Download PDF
ads:
The Village Labourer: 1760-1832: A Study in the Government of
England before the Reform Bill
John Lawrence Hammond & Barbara Hammond
PREFACE
This edition differs from previous editions of The Village Labourer in two respects. The original
Chapter One has been omitted: this chapter described the concentration of power in the hands of a
small class, which was the leading feature of our political development in the eighteenth century.
Secondly, the Appendices have been reduced, but the student who wishes to pursue the subject of
enclosure further will find, at the end of this volume, full details of four important and representative
enclosures.
In their preface to the edition published in 1913 the authors discussed some of the controversies
that had arisen on the topic of the enclosures. It seems worth while to reproduce here the substance
of that preface. Two main criticisms have been passed on the treatment of enclosures in these
pages: the first, that the writers have drawn an unjust picture, because they deliberately excluded
the importance of enclosure in increasing the food supplies of the nation; the second, that the
hardships of the poor have been exaggerated, and that, though the system of enclosure lent itself to
abuses, there was no evidence that wrong was done in the mass of enclosures.
The writers submit the following considerations: (1) It has been the accepted view of all modern
critics, with the single exception of dr Hasbach, that the enclosures of this period, or at any rate the
enclosures that took place after 1795, made the soil of England immediately more productive. That
this is the usual view was stated in the text; its correctness was not discussed or questioned. The
subject of this volume is the fate of the Village Labourer, and so far as he is concerned, the facts
which they are accused of neglecting suggest two reflections: (a) the feeding of Manchester and
Leeds did not make life cheaper to him; and (b) if agriculture suddenly became a great industry,
multiplying as some say England's resources twenty-fold, an equitable readjustment must have
increased the prosperity of all classes engaged in that industry. The greater the stress laid on the
progress of agriculture, the greater appear the perversity and injustice of the arrangements of a
society under which the labourer became impoverished. If it is argued that the misery of the labourer
was the price the nation had to pay for that advance, it is worth while to point out that that was not
the view of Young, or Davies, or Eden, or Sinclair, or Cobbett, and that the actual revolution that was
accomplished was not the only alternative to the old unreformed common field system. (2) The
authors desire to point out how little they have relied on solitary instances for their general
statements. Complaint has been made of the publishing of the story of the attempted enclosure of
Sedgmoor, but those who read that account carefully will see that the passage from Selwyn's letters
are important as disclosing the state of mind of a chairman of an Enclosure Committee; they will
note also that his letters show that it was a common practice for Members of Parliament to arrange
meetings in order to manipulate Committees in the interest of private persons. Selwyn's view of the
responsibilities of a chairman of one of these Committees has therefore a special significance. The
main question for the historian is this: Were the poor sacrificed or not in the enclosures as they were
carried out? The writers have given their reasons for thinking that they were sacrificed, and
needlessly sacrificed, and no evidence has come under their notice in the criticisms published to
shake that view. They have set out the actual methods of procedure that were adopted for
converting England from the old to the new system, and they think it is clear that those methods
were such that the poor were bound to suffer unless Parliament expressly intervened for their
protection. This was apparent, or became apparent, to observers at the time, and proposals that
would have helped the poor were made by Arthur Young, by Eden, by Davies, by Suffield, and by
the Board of Agriculture. Those proposals were disregarded, not necessarily from wickedness or
rapacity, but because the atmosphere of the ruling class was unfavourable. Young referred to his
own proposal six years later in a passage which is worth quoting:
'I have been reading over my Inquiry into the Propriety of applying Wastes to the better Maintenance
of the Poor. I had almost forgotten it, but of all the essays and papers I have produced, none I think
so pardonable as this, so convincing by facts, and so satisfactory to any candid reader. Thank God I
wrote it, for though it never had the smallest effect except in exciting opposition and ridicule, it will, I
trust, remain a proof of what ought to have been done; and had it been executed, would have
ads:
Livros Grátis
http://www.livrosgratis.com.br
Milhares de livros grátis para download.
diffused more comfort among the poor than any proposition that ever was made' (Autobiography,
July 14, 1806).
One further fact of interest and importance in this connection may be mentioned. Michael Sadler,
the Factory Reformer, was, unhappily for England, thrown out of Parliament after the passing of the
Reform Bill. He was in the House of Commons for only three years. One of the most important
speeches that he made in his brief career there, was a long speech reviewing the disastrous change
that had come over the agricultural labourers in recent times. The chief cause he found in the
disappearance of the small farmer, the pulling down of cottages, and the enclosures. He said that
the enclosures had inflicted on the poor as a class 'the most irreparable injuries.' Like Thelwall, with
whom he would have been slow to recognise any affinity, he argued that enclosure might have
benefited the poor, but that in practice it had ruined them. 'Inclosures might indeed have been so
conducted as to have benefited all parties; but now, coupled with other features of the system, they
form a part of what Blackstone denominates a "fatal rural policy"; one which has completed the
degradation and ruin of your agricultural poor.'
Two subjects are discussed fully in this volume for the first time. One is the actual method and
procedure of Parliamentary Enclosure; the other the labourers' rising of 1830. More than one
important book has been written on enclosures during the last few years, but nowhere can the
student find a full analysis of the procedure and stages by which the old village was destroyed. The
rising of 1830 has only been mentioned incidentally in general histories: it has nowhere been treated
as a definite demand for better conditions, and its course, scope, significance and punishment have
received little attention. The writers of this book have treated it fully, using for that purpose the Home
Office Papers accessible to students in the Record Office. They wish to express their gratitude to Mr
Hubert Hall for his help and guidance in this part of their work.
The obligations of the writers to the important books published in recent years on eighteenth-century
local government in the text, but the are manifest, and they are acknowledged writers desire to
mention specially their great debt to Mr Hobson's Industrial System, a work that seems to them to
throw a new and most illuminating light on the economic significance of the history of the early years
of the last century.
Mr and Mrs Arthur Ponsonby and Miss M. K. Bradby have done the writers the great service of
reading the entire book and suggesting many important improvements. Mr and Mrs C. R. Buxton, Mr
A. Clutton Brock, Professor L. T. Hobhouse, and Mr H. W. Massingham have given them valuable
help and advice on various parts of the work.
HEMEL HEMPSTED, April 1920.
CHAPTER ONE
The Village Before Enclosure
To elucidate these chapters, and to supply further information for those who are interested in the
subject, we publish an Appendix containing the history, and tolerably full particulars, of four separate
enclosures at Croydon, Haute Huntre, Stanwell and Wakefield.
At the time of the great Whig Revolution, England was in the main a country of commons and of
common fields;(1*) at the time of the Reform Bill, England was in the main a country of individualist
agriculture and of large enclosed farms. There has probably been no change in Europe in the last
two centuries comparable to this in importance of which so little is known to-day, or of which so little
is to be learnt from the general histories of the time. The accepted view is that this change marks a
great national advance, and that the hardships which incidentally followed could not have been
avoided: that it meant a vast increase in the food resources of England in comparison with which the
sufferings of individuals counted for little: and that the great estates which then came into existence
were rather the gift of economic forces than the deliberate acquisitions of powerful men. We are not
concerned to corroborate or to dispute the contention that enclosure made England more
productive,(2*) or to discuss the merits of enclosure itself as a public policy or a means to
agricultural progress in the eighteenth century. Our business is with the changes that the enclosures
caused in the social structure of England, from the manner in which they were in practice carried
out. We propose, therefore, to describe the actual operations by which society passed through this
revolution, the old village vanished, and rural life assumed its modern form and character.
It is difficult for us, who think of a common as a wild sweep of heather and beauty and freedom,
saved for the enjoyment of the world in the midst of guarded parks and forbidden meadows, to
realise that the commons that disappeared from so many an English village in the eighteenth
ads:
century belonged to a very elaborate, complex, and ancient economy. The antiquity of that elaborate
economy has been the subject of fierce contention, and the controversies that rage round the
nursery of the English village recall the controversies that raged round the nursery of Homer. The
main subject of contention has been this. Was the manor or the township, or whatever name we like
to give to the primitive unit of agricultural life, an organisation imposed by a despotic landowner on
his dependents, or was it created by the co-operation of a group of free tribesmen, afterwards
dominated by a military overlord? Did it owe more to Roman tradition or to Teutonic tendencies?
Professor Vinogradoff, the latest historian, inclines to a compromise between these conflicting
theories. He thinks that it is impossible to trace the open-field system of cultivation to any exclusive
right of ownership or to the power of coercion, and that the communal organisation of the peasantry,
a village community of shareholders who cultivated the land on the open-field system and treated
the other requisites of rural life as appendant to it, is more ancient than the manorial order. It
derives, in his view, from the old English society. The manor itself, an institution which partakes at
once of the character of an estate and of a unit of local government, was produced by the needs of
government and the development of individualist husbandry, side by side with this communal
village. These conditions lead to the creation of lordships, and after the Conquest they take form in
the manor. The manorial element, in fact, is superimposed on the communal, and is not the
foundation of it: the medieval village is a free village gradually feudalised. Fortunately it is not
incumbent on us to do more than touch on this fascinating study, as it is enough for our purposes to
note that the greater part of England in cultivation at the beginning of the eighteenth century was
cultivated on a system which, with certain local variations, belonged to a common type, representing
this common ancestry.
The term 'common' was used of three kinds of land in the eighteenth-century village, and the three
were intimately connected with each other. There were (1) the gable fields, (2) the common
meadowland, and (3) the common or waste. The arable fields were divided into strips, with different
owners, some of whom owned few strips, and some many. The various strips that belonged to a
particular owner were scattered among the fields. Strips were divided from each other, sometimes
by a grass band called a balk, sometimes by a furrow. They were cultivated on a uniform system by
agreement, and after harvest they were thrown open to pasturage. The common meadow land was
divided up by lot, pegged out, and distributed among the owners of the strips; after the hay was
carried, these meadows, like the arable fields, were used for pasture. The common or waste, which
was used as a common pasture at all times of the year, consisted sometimes of woodland,
sometimes of roadside strips, and sometimes of commons in the modern sense.(3*)
Such, roughly, was the map of the old English village. What were the classes that lived in it, and
what were their several rights? In a normal village there would be (1) a Lord of the Manor, (2)
Freeholders, some of whom might be large proprietors, and many small, both classes going by the
general name of Yeomanry, (3) Copyholders, (4) Tenant Farmers, holding by various sorts of
tenure, from tenants at will to farmers with leases for three lives, (5) Cottagers, (6) Squatters, and
(7) Farm Servants, living in their employers' houses. The proportions of these classes varied greatly,
no doubt, in different villages, but we have an estimate of the total agricultural population in the table
prepared by Gregory King in 1688, from which it appears that in addition to the Esquires and
Gentlemen, there were 40,000 families of freeholders of the better sort, 140,000 families of
freeholders of the lesser sort, and 150,000 farmers. Adam Smith, it will be remembered, writing
nearly a century later, said that the large number of yeomen was at once the strength and the
distinction of English agriculture.
Let us now describe rather more fully the different people represented in these different categories,
and the different rights that they enjoyed. We have seen in the first chapter that the manorial courts
had lost many of their powers by this time, and that part of the jurisdiction that the Lord of the Manor
had originally exercised had passed to the Justice of the Peace. No such change had taken place in
his relation to the economic life of the village. He might or he might not still own a demesne land. So
far as the common arable or common meadow was concerned, he was in the same position as any
other proprietor: he might own many strips or few strips or no strips at all. His position with regard to
the waste was different, the difference being expressed by Blackstone 'in those waste grounds,
which are usually called commons, the property of the soil is generally in the Lord of the Manor, as
in the common fields it is in the particular tenant.' The feudal lawyers had developed a doctrine that
the soil of the waste was vested in the Lord of the Manor, and that originally it had all belonged to
him. But feudal law acknowledged certain definite limitations to his rights over the waste. The
Statute of Merton, 1235, allowed him to make enclosures on the waste, but only on certain terms; he
was obliged to leave enough of the waste for the needs of his tenants. Moreover, his powers were
limited, not only by the concurrent rights of freeholders and copyholders thus recognised by this
ancient law, but also by certain common rights of pasture and turbary enjoyed by persons who were
neither freeholders nor copyholders, namely cottagers. These rights were explained by the lawyers
of the time as being concessions made by the Lord of the Manor in remote antiquity. The Lord of the
Manor was regarded as the owner of the waste, subject to these common rights: that is, he was
regarded as owning the minerals and the surface rights (sand and gravel) as well as sporting rights.
Every grade of property and status was represented in the ranks of the freeholders, the copyholders
and the tenant farmers, from the man who employed others to work for him to the man who was
sometimes employed in working for others. No distinct line, in fact, can be drawn between the small
farmer, whether freeholder, copyholder or tenant, and the cottager, for the cottager might either own
or rent a few strips; the best dividing-line can be drawn between those who made their living mainly
as farmers, and those who made their living mainly as labourers.
It is important to remember that no farmer, however large his holdings or property, or however
important his social position, was at liberty to cultivate his strips as he pleased. The system of
cultivation would be settled for him by the Jury of the Manor Court, a court that had different names
in different places. By the eighteenth century the various courts of the manorial jurisdiction had been
merged in a single court, called indifferently the View of Frankpledge, the Court Leet, the Court
Baron, the Great Court or the Little Court, which transacted so much of the business hitherto
confided to various courts as had not been assigned to the Justices of the Peace.(4*) Most of the
men of the village, freeholders, copyholders, leaseholders, Or cottagers, attended the court, but the
constitution of the Jury or Homage seems to have varied in different manors. Sometimes the
tenants of the manor were taken haphazard in rotation: sometimes the steward controlled the
choice, sometimes a nominee of the steward or a nominee of the tenants selected the Jury:
sometimes the steward took no part in the selection at all. The chief part of the business of these
courts in the eighteenth century was the management of the common fields and common pastures,
and the appointment of the village officers. These courts decided which seed should be sown in the
different fields, and the dates at which they were to be opened and closed to common pasture.
Under the most primitive system of rotation the arable land was divided into three fields, of which
one was sown with wheat, another with spring corn, and the third lay fallow: but by the end of the
eighteenth century there was a great variety of cultivation, and we find a nine years' course at Great
Tew in Oxfordshire, a six years' course in Berkshire, while the Battersea common fields were sown
with one uniform round of grain without intermission, and consequently without fallowing.(5*)
By Sir Richard Sutton's Act(6*) for the cultivation of common fields, passed in 1773, a majority of
three-fourths in number and value of the occupiers, with the consent of the owner and titheholder,
was empowered to decide on the course of husbandry, to regulate stinted commons, and, with the
consent of the Lord of the Manor, to let off a twelfth of the common, applying the rent to draining or
improving the rest of it.(7*) Before this Act, a universal consent to any change of system was
necessary.(8*) The cultivation of strips in the arable fields carried with it rights of common over the
waste and also over the common fields when they were thrown open. These rights were known as
'common appendant' and they are thus defined by Blackstone: 'Common appendant is a right
belonging to the owners or occupiers of arable land to put commonable beasts upon the Lord's
waste and upon the lands of other persons within the same manor.'
The classes making their living mainly as labourers were the cottagers, farm servants, and
squatters. The cottagers either owned or occupied cottages and had rights of common on the waste,
and in some cases over the common fields. These rights were of various kinds: they generally
included the right to pasture certain animals, to cut turf and to get fuel. The cottagers, as we have
already said, often owned or rented land. This is spoken of as a common practice by Addington,
who knew the Midland counties well; Arthur Young gives instances from Lincolnshire and
Oxfordshire, and Eden from Leicestershire and Surrey. The squatters or borderers were, by origin, a
separate class, though in time they merged into the cottagers. They were settlers who built
themselves huts and cleared a piece of land in the commons or woods, at some distance from the
village. These encroachments were generally sanctioned. A common rule in one part of the country
was that the right was established if the settler could build his cottage in the night and send out
smoke from his chimney in the morning.(9*) The squatters also often went out as day labourers. The
farm servants were usually the children of the small farmers or cottagers; they lived in their masters'
houses until they had saved enough money to marry and take a cottage of their own.
Were there any day labourers without either land or common rights in the old village? It is difficult to
suppose that there were many.(10*) Blackstone said of common appurtenant that it was not a
general right 'but can only be claimed by special grant or by prescription, which the law esteems
sufficient proof of a special grant or agreement for this purpose.' Prescription covers a multitude of
encroachments. Indeed, it was only by the ingenuity of the feudal lawyers that these rights did not
attach to the inhabitants of the village at large. These lawyers had decided in Gateward's case,
1603, that 'inhabitants' were too vague a body to enjoy a right, and on this ground they had deprived
the inhabitants of the village of Stixswold in Lincolnshire of their customary right of turning out cattle
on the waste.(11*) From that time a charter of incorporation was necessary to enable the inhabitants
at large to prove a legal claim to common rights. But rights that were enjoyed by the occupiers of
small holdings or of cottages by long prescription, or by encroachments tacitly sanctioned, must
have been very widely scattered.
Such were the classes inhabiting the eighteenth-century village. As the holdings in the common
fields could be sold, the property might change hands, though it remained subject to common rights
and to the general regulations of the manor court. Consequently the villages exhibited great
varieties of character. In one village it might happen that strip after strip had been bought up by the
Lord of the Manor or some proprietor, until the greater part of the arable fields had come into the
possession of a single owner. In such eases, however, the land so purchased was still let out as a
rule to a number of small men, for the engrossing of farms as a practice comes into fashion after
enclosure. Sometimes such purchase was a preliminary to enclosure. The Bedfordshire reporter
gives an example in the village of Bolnhurst, in that county. Three land speculators bought up as
much of the land as they could with a view to enclosing the common fields and then selling at a
large profit. But the land turned out to be much less valuable than they had supposed, and they
could not get it off their hands: all improvements were at a standstill, for the speculators only let from
year to year, hoping still to find a market.(12*) In other villages, land might have changed hands in
just the opposite direction. The Lord of the Manor might sell his property in the common fields, and
sell it not to some capitalist or merchant, but to a number of small farmers. We learn from the
evidence of the Committee of 1844 on enclosures that sometimes the Lord of the Manor sold his
property in the waste to the commoners. Thus there were villages with few owners, as there were
villages with many owners. The writer of the Report on Middlesex, which was published in 1798
says, 'I have known thirty landlords in a field of 200 acres, and the property of each so divided as to
lie in ten or twenty places, containing from an acre or two downwards to fifteen perches; and in a
field of 300 acres I have met with patches of arable land, containing eight perches each. In this
instance the average size of all the pieces in the field was under an acre. In all cases they lie in
long, narrow, winding or worm-like slips.'(13*)
The same writer states that at the time his book was written (1798) 20,000 out of the 23,000 arable
acres in Middlesex were cultivated on the common-field system.(14*) Perhaps the parish of
Stanwell, of which we describe the enclosure in detail elsewhere, may be taken as a fair example of
an eighteenth-century village. In this parish there were, according to the enclosure award, four large
proprietors, twenty-four moderate proprietors, twenty-four small proprietors, and sixty-six cottagers
with common rights.
The most important social fact about this system is that it provided opportunities for the humblest
and poorest labourer to rise in the village. Population seems to have moved slowly, and thus there
was no feverish competition for land. The farm servant could save up his wages and begin his
married life by hiring a cottage which carried rights of common, and gradually buy or hire strips of
land. Every village, as Hasbach has put it, had its ladder, and nobody was doomed to stay on the
lowest rung. This is the distinguishing mark of the old village. It would be easy, looking only at this
feature, to idealise the society that we have described, and to paint this age as an age of gold. But
no reader of Fielding or of Richardson would fall into this mistake, or persuade himself that this
community was a society of free and equal men, in which tyranny was impossible. The old village
was under the shadow of the squire and the parson, and there were many ways in which these
powers controlled and hampered its pleasures and habits: there were quarrels, too, between
farmers and cottagers, and there are many complaints that the farmers tried to take the lion's share
of the commons: but, whatever the pressure outside and whatever the bickerings within, it remains
true that the common-field system formed a world in which the villagers lived their own lives and
cultivated the soil on a basis of independence.
It was this community that now passed under the unqualified rule of the oligarchy. Under that rule it
was to disappear. Enclosure was no new menace to the poor. English literature before the
eighteenth century echoes the dismay and lamentations of preachers and prophets who witnessed
the havoc that it spread. Stubbes had written in 1553 his bitter protest against the enclosures which
enabled rich men to eat up poor men, and twenty years later a writer had given a sombre landscape
of the new farming: 'We may see many of their houses built alone like ravens' nests, no birds
building near them.' The Midlands had been the chief scene of these changes, and there the
conversion of arable land into pasture had swallowed up great tracts of common agriculture,
provoking in some cases an armed resistance. The enclosures of this century were the second and
the greater of two waves.(15*) In one respect enclosure was in form more difficult now than in earlier
periods, for it was generally understood at this time that an Act of Parliament was necessary. In
reality there was less check on the process. For hitherto the enclosing class had had to reckon with
the occasional panic or ill-temper of the Crown. No English king, it is true, had intervened in the
interests of the poor so dramatically as did the earlier and unspoilt Louis XIV, who restored to the
French village assemblies the public lands they had alienated within a certain period. But the Crown
had not altogether overlooked the interests of the classes who were ruined by enclosure, and in
different ways it had tried to modify the worst consequences of this policy. From 1490 to 1601 there
were various Acts and proclamations designed for this purpose. Charles I had actually annulled the
enclosures of two years in certain midland counties, several Commissions had been issued, and the
Star Chamber had instituted proceedings against enclosures on the ground that depopulation was
an offence against the Common Law. Mr. Firth holds that Cromwell's influence in the eastern
counties was due to his championship of the commoners in the fens. Throughout this time, however
ineffectual the intervention of the Crown, the interests of the classes to whom enclosures brought
wealth and power were not allowed to obliterate all other considerations.
From the beginning of the eighteenth century the reins are thrown to the enclosure movement, and
the policy of enclosure is emancipated from all these checks and afterthoughts. One interest is
supreme throughout England, supreme in Parliament, supreme in the country; the Crown follows,
the nation obeys.
The agricultural community which was taken to pieces in the eighteenth century and reconstructed
in the manner in which a dictator reconstructs a free government, was threatened from many points.
It was not killed by avarice alone. Cobbett used to attribute the enclosure movement entirely to the
greed of the landowners, but, if greed was a sufficient motive, greed was in this case clothed and
almost enveloped in public spirit. Let us remember what this community looked like to men with the
mind of the landlord class. The English landowners have always believed that order would be
resolved into its original chaos, if they ceased to control the lives and destinies of their neighbours.
'A great responsibility rests on us landlords; if we go, the whole thing goes.' So says the landlord in
Mr. Galsworthy's novel, and so said the landlords in the eighteenth century. The English aristocracy
always thinking of this class as the pillars of society, as the Atlas that bears the burden of the world,
very naturally concluded that this old peasant community, with its troublesome rights, was a public
encumbrance. This view received a special impetus from all the circumstances of the age. The
landlord class was constantly being recruited from the ranks of the manufacturers, and the new
landlords, bringing into this charmed circle an energy of their own, caught at once its taste for
power, for direction, for authority, for imposing its will. Readers of Shirley will remember that when
Robert Moore pictures to himself a future of usefulness and success, he says that he will obtain an
Act for enclosing Nunnely Common, that his brother will be put on the bench, and that between
them they will dominate the parish. The book ends in this dream of triumph. Signorial position owes
its special lustre for English minds to the association of social distinction with power over the life and
ways of groups of men and women. When Bagehot sneered at the sudden millionaires of his day,
who hoped to disguise their social defects by buying old places and hiding among aristocratic
furniture, he was remarking on a feature of English life that was very far from being peculiar to his
time. Did not Adam Smith observe that merchants were very commonly ambitious of becoming
country gentlemen? This kind of ambition was the form that public spirit often took in successful
Englishmen, and it was a very powerful menace to the old village and its traditions of collective life.
Now this passion received at this time a special momentum from the condition of agriculture. A
dictatorship lends itself more readily than any other form of government to the quick introduction of
revolutionary ideas, and new ideas were in the air. Thus, in addition to the desire for social power,
there was behind the enclosure movement a zeal for economic progress seconding and almost
concealing the direct inspiration of self-interest. Many an enclosing landlord thought only of the
satisfaction of doubling or trebling his rent: that is unquestionable. If we are to trust so warm a
champion of enclosure as William Marshall, this was the state of mind of the great majority. But
there were many whose eyes glistened as they thought of the prosperity they were to bring to
English agriculture, applying to a wider and wider domain the lessons that were to be learnt from the
processes of scientific farming. A man who had caught the large ideas of a Coke, or mastered the
discoveries of a Bakewell, chafed under the restraints that the system of common agriculture placed
on improvement and experiment. It was maddening to have to set your pace by the slow bucolic
temperament of small farmers, nursed in a simple and old-fashioned routine, who looked with
suspicion on any proposal that was strange to them. In this tiresome partnership the swift were put
between the shafts with the slow, and the temptation to think that what was wanted was to get rid of
the partnership altogether, was almost irresistible. From such a state the mind passed rapidly and
naturally to the conclusion that the wider the sphere brought into the absolute possession of the
enlightened class, the greater would be the public gain. The spirit in which the Board of Agriculture
approached the subject found appropriate expression in Sir John Sinclair's high-sounding language.
'The idea of having lands in common, it has been justly remarked, is to be derived from that
barbarous state of society, when men were strangers to any higher occupation than those of hunters
or shepherds, or had only just tasted the advantages to be reaped from the cultivation of the
earth.'(16*) Arthur Young(17*) compared the with its inconveniences 'which the barbarity of their
ancestors had neither knowledge to discover nor government to remedy' to the Tartar policy of the
shepherd state.
It is not surprising that men under the influence of these set ideas could find no virtue at all in the old
system, and that they soon began to persuade themselves that that system was at the bottom of all
the evils of society. It was harmful to the morals and useless to the pockets of the poor. 'The
benefit,' wrote Arbuthnot,(18*) 'which they are supposed to reap from commons, in their present
state, I know to be merely nominal; nay, indeed, what is worse, I know, that, in many instances, it is
an essential injury to them, by being made a plea for their idleness; for, some few excepted, if you
offer them work, they will tell you, that they must go to look up their sheep, cut furzes, get their cow
out of the pound, or, perhaps, say they must take their horse to be shod, that he may carry them to a
horse-race or cricket-match.' Lord Sheffield, in the course of one of the debates in Parliament,
described the commoners as a 'nuisance,' and most people of his class thought of them as
something worse. Mr. John Billingsley, who wrote the Report on Somerset for the Board of
Agriculture in 1795, describes in some detail the enervating atmosphere of the commoners' life.
'Besides, moral effects of an injurious tendency accrue to the cottager, from a reliance on the
imaginary benefits of stocking a common. The possession of a cow or two, with a hog, and a few
geese, naturally exalts the peasant, in his own conception, above his brethren in the same rank of
society. It inspires some degree of confidence in a property, inadequate to his support. In sauntering
after his cattle, he acquires a habit of indolence. Quarter, half, and occasionally whole days are
imperceptibly lost. Day labour becomes disgusting; the aversion increases by indulgence; and at
length the sale of a half-fed calf, or hog, furnishes the means of adding intemperance to
idleness.'(19*) Mr. Bishton, who wrote the Report on Shropshire in 1794, gives a still more
interesting glimpse into the mind of the enclosing class: 'The use of common land by labourers
operates upon the mind as a sort of independence.' When the commons are enclosed 'the labourers
will work every day in the year, their children will be put out to labour early,' and 'that subordination
of the lower ranks of society which in the present times is so much wanted, would be thereby
considerably secured.'
A similar view was taken of the moral effects of commons by Middleton, the writer of the Report on
Middlesex.(20*) 'On the other hand, they are, in many instances, of real injury to the public; by
holding out a lure to the poor man -- I mean of materials wherewith to build his cottage, and ground
to erect it upon: together with firing and the run of his poultry and pigs for nothing. This is of course
temptation sufficient to induce a great number of poor persons to settle upon the borders of such
commons. But the mischief does not end here: for having gained these trifling advantages, through
the neglect or connivance of the lord of the manor, it unfortunately gives their minds an improper
bias, and inculcates a desire to live, from that time forward, without labour, or at least with as little as
possible.'
One of the witnesses before the Select Committee on Commons Inclosure in 1844 was Mr. Carus
Wilson, who is interesting as the original of the character of Mr. Brocklehurst in Jane Eyre. We know
how that zealous Christian would regard the commoners from the speech in which he reproved Miss
Temple for giving the pupils at Lowood a lunch of bread and cheese on one occasion when their
meagre breakfast had been uneatable. 'Oh, madam, when you put bread and cheese, instead of
burnt porridge, into these children's mouths, you may indeed feed their vile bodies, but you little
think how you starve their immortal souls!' We are not surprised to learn that Mr. Carus Wilson
found the commoners 'hardened and unpromising,' and that he was obliged to inform the committee
that. the misconduct which the system encouraged 'hardens the heart, and causes a good deal of
mischief, and at the same time puts the person in an unfavourable position for the approach of what
might be serviceable to him in a moral and religious point of view.'(21*)
It is interesting, after reading all these confident generalisations about the influence of this kind of
life upon the character of the poor, to learn what the commoners themselves thought of its moral
atmosphere. This we can do from such a petition as that sent by the small proprietors and persons
entitled to rights of common at Raunds, in Northamptonshire. These unfortunate people lost their
rights by an Enclosure Act in 1797, and during the progress of the Bill they petitioned Parliament
against it, in these terms: 'That the Petitioners beg Leave to represent to the House that, under
Pretence of improving Lands in the said Parish, the Cottagers and other Persons entitled to Right of
Common on the Lands intended to be inclosed, will be deprived of an inestimable Privilege, which
they now enjoy, of turning a certain Number of their Cows, Calves, and Sheep, on and over the said
Lands; a Privilege that enables them not only to maintain themselves and their Families in the depth
of Winter, when they cannot, even for their Money, obtain from the Occupiers of other Lands the
smallest Portion of Milk or Whey for such necessary Purpose, but, in addition to this, they can now
supply the Grazier with young or lean Stock at a reasonable Price, to fatten and bring to Market at a
more moderate Rate for general Consumption, which they conceive to be the most rational and
effectual Way of establishing Public Plenty and Cheapness of Provision; and they further conceive,
that a more ruinous Effect of this Inclosure will be the almost total depopulation of their Town, now
filled with bold and hardy Husbandmen, from among whom, and the Inhabitants of other open
Parishes, the Nation has hitherto derived its greatest Strength and Glory, in the Supply of its Fleets
and Aries, and driving them, from Necessity and Want of Employ, in vast Crowds, into
manufacturing Towns, where the very Nature of their Employment, over the Loom or the Forge,
soon may waste their Strength, and consequently debilitate their Posterity, and by imperceptible
degrees obliterate that great Principle of Obedience to the Laws of God and their Country, which
forms the Character of the simple and artless Villagers, more equally distributed through the Open
Countries, and on which so much depends the good Order and Government of the State: These are
some of the Injuries to themselves as Individuals, and of the ill Consequences to the Public, which
the Petitioners conceive will follow from this, as they have already done from many Inclosures, but
which they did not think they were entitled to lay before the House (the Constitutional Patron and
Protector of the Poor) until it unhappily came to their own Lot to be exposed to them through the Bill
now pending.'(22*)
When we remember that the enterprise of the age was under the spell of the most seductive
economic teaching of the time, and that the old peasant society, wearing as it did the look of
confusion and weakness, had to fear not only the simplifying appetites of the landlords, but the
simplifying philosophy, in England of an Adam Smith, in France of the Physiocrats, we can realise
that a ruling class has seldom found so plausible an atmosphere for the free play of its interests and
ideas. Des crimes sont flattés d'être présidés par une vertu. Bentham himself thought the spectacle
of an enclosure one of the most reassuring of all the evidences of improvement and happiness.
Indeed, all the elements seemed to have conspired against the peasant, for aesthetic taste, which
might at other times have restrained, in the eighteenth century encouraged the destruction of the
commons and their rough beauty. The rage for order and symmetry and neat cultivation was
universal. It found expression in Burnet, who said of the Alps and Appenines that they had neither
form nor beauty, neither shape nor order, any more than the clouds of the air: in Johnson, who said
of the Highlands that 'the uniformity of barrenness can afford very little amusement to the traveller;'
and in Cobbett, who said of the Cotswolds, 'this is a sort of country having less to please the eye
than any other that I have ever seen, always save and except the heaths like those of Bagshot and
Hindhead.' The enjoyment of wild nature was a lost sense, to be rediscovered one day by the
Romanticists and the Revolution, but too late to help the English village. In France, owing to various
causes, part economic, part political, on which we shall touch later, the peasant persisted in his
ancient and ridiculous tenure, and survived to become the envy of English observer: it was only in
England that he lost his footing, and that his ancient patrimony slipped away from him.
We are not concerned at this juncture to inquire into the truth of the view that the sweeping policy of
enclosure increased the productivity and resources of the State: we are concerned only to inquire
into the Way in which the aristocracy gave shape and effect to it. This movement, assumed by the
enlightened opinion of the day to be beneficent and progressive, was none the less a gigantic
disturbance; it broke up the old Village life; it transferred a great body of property; it touched a vast
mass of interests at a hundred points. A governing class that cared for its reputation for justice
would clearly regard it as of sovereign importance that this delicate network of rights and claims
should not be roughly disentangled by the sheer power of the stronger: a governing class that
recognised its responsibility for the happiness and order of the State would clearly regard it as of
sovereign importance that this ancient community should not be dissolved in such a manner as to
plunge great number of contented men into permanent poverty and despair. To decide how far the
aristocracy that presided over these changes displayed insight or foresight, sympathy or
imagination, and how far it acted with a controlling sense of integrity and public spirit, we must
analyse the methods and procedure of Parliamentary enclosure.
Before entering on a discussion of the methods by which Parliamentary enclosure was effected, it is
necessary to realise the extent of its operations. Precise statistics, of course, are not to be had, but
there are various estimates based on careful study of such evidence as we possess. Mr. Levy says
that between 1702 and 1760 there were only 246 Acts, affecting about 400,000 acres, and that in
the next fifty years the Acts had reached a total of 2438, affecting almost five million acres.(23*) Mr.
Johnson gives the following table for the years 1700-1844, founded on Dr. Slater's detailed estimate
(24*) --
Common Field and Waste only
some waste
Years Acts Acreage Acts Acreage
1750-1760 152 237,845 56 74,518
1761-1801 1,479 2,428,721 521 752,150
1802-1844 1,075 1,610,302 808 939,043
Total 2,706 4,276,868 1,385 1,765,711
This roughly corresponds with the estimate given before the Select Committee on Enclosures in
1844, that there were some one thousand seven hundred private Acts before 1800, and some two
thousand between 1800 and 1844. The General Report of the Board of Agriculture on Enclosures
gives the acreage enclosed from the time of Queen Anne down to 1805 as 4,187,056. Mr.
Johnson's conclusion is that nearly 20 per cent of the total acreage of England has been enclosed.
During the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries, though Mr. Prothero puts the percentage still
higher. But we should miss the significance of these proportions if we were to look at England at the
beginning of the eighteenth century as a map of which a large block was already shaded, and of
which another block, say a fifth or a sixth part, was to be shaded by the enclosure of this period. The
truth is that the life of the common-field system was still the normal village life of England, and that
the land which was already enclosed consisted largely of old enclosures or the lord's demesne land
lying side by side with the open fields. This was put quite clearly by the Bishop of St. Davids in the
House of Lords in 1781. 'Parishes of any considerable extent consisted partly of old inclosures and
partly of common fields.'(25*) If a village living on the common-field system contained old
enclosures, effected some time or other without Act of Parliament, it suffered just as violent a
catastrophe when the common fields or the waste were enclosed, as if there had been no previous
enclosure in the parish. The number of Acts passed in this period varies of course with the different
counties,(26*) but speaking generally, we may say that the events described in the next two
chapters are not confined to any one part of the country, and that they mark a national revolution,
making sweeping and profound changes in the form and the character of agricultural society
throughout England.(27*)
NOTES:
1. Gregory King and Davenant estimated that the whole of the cultivated land in England in 1685 did
not amount to much more than half the total area, and of this cultivated portion three-fifths was still
farmed on the old common field system.
2. For a full discussion, in which the ordinary view is vigorously combated in an interesting analysis,
see Hasbach, History of the Agricultural Labourer; on the other side, Levy, Large and Small
Holdings.
3. This was the general structure of the village that was dissolved in the eighteenth century. It is
distinguished from the Keltic type of communal agriculture, know as run-rig, in two important
respects. In the run-rig village the soil is periodically redivided, and the tenant's holding is compact.
Dr. Slater (Geographical Journal</i>, Jan. 1907) has shown that in those parts of England where the
Keltic type predominated, e.g., in Devon and Cornwall, enclosure took place early, and he argues
with good reason that it was easier to enclose by voluntary agreement where the holdings were
compact than it was where they were scattered in strips. But gradual enclosure by voluntary
agreement had a different effect from the cataclysm-like enclosure of the eighteenth century, as is
evident from the large number of small farmers in Devonshire.
4. See Webb, Manor and Borough, vol. i, p. 66 seq.
5. Slater, The English Peasantry and the Enclosure of Common Fields, p. 77.
6. 13 George III, c. 81.
7. This was done at Barnes Common; see for whole subject, Annals of Agriculture, vol. xvii. p. 516.
8. For cases where changes in the system of cultivation of common fields had been made, see
Annals of Agriculture, vol. xvi. p. 606; 'To Peterborough, crossing an open field, but sown by
agreement with turnips.' Cf. Report on Bedfordshire: 'Clover is sown in some of the open clay-fields
by common consent (p. 339), and 'Turnips are sometimes cultivated, both on the sands and gravels,
by mutual consent.' (p. 340).
9. Slater, p. 119.
10. Dr. Slater's conclusion is that 'in the open field village the entirely landless labourer was scarcely
to be found.' p. 130.
11. See Commons, Forests, and Footpaths, by Lord Eversley, p. 11.
12. Bedforshire Report, 1808, p. 223, quoting from Arthur Young.
13. p. 114.
14. p. 138.
15. See on this point, Levy, Large and Small Holdings, p. 1.
16. Report of Select Committee on Waste Lands, 1795, p. 15, Appendix B.
17. Annals of Agriculture, vol. i. p. 72.
18. An Inquiry into the Connection between the present Price of Provisions and the Size of Farms,
1773, p. 81.
19. Report on Somerset, reprinted 1797, p. 52; compare Report on Commons in Brecknock, Annals
of Agriculture, vol. xxii, p. 632, where commons are denounced as 'hurtful to society by holding forth
a temptation to idleness, that fell parent to vice and immorality' also compare Ibid., vol. xx, p. 145,
where they are said to encourage the commoners to be 'hedge, breakers, pilferers, nightly
trespassers... poultry and rabbit stealers, or such like.'
20. p. 103.
21. Committee on Inclosures, 1844, p. 135.
22. House of Commons Journal, June 19, 1797.
23. Large and Small Holdings, p. 24.
24. Disappearance of Small Landowner, p. 90; Slater's English Peasantry and the Enclosure of
Common Fields, Appendix B.
25. Parliamentary Register, March 30, 1781.
26. See Dr. Slater's detailed estimate.
27. There were probably many enclosures that hand not the authority either of a special Act or of the
Act of 1756, particularly in the more distant counties. The evidence of Mr Carus Wilson upon the
committee of 1844 shows that the stronger classes interpreted their rights and powers in a liberal
spirit. Mr Carus Wilson had arranged with the other large proprietors to let out the only common
which remained open in the thirteen parishes in which his father was interested as a large
landowner, and to pay the rent into the poor rates. Some members of the committee asked whether
the minority who dissented from the arrangement could be excluded, and Mr Wilson explained that
he and his confederates believed that the minority were bound by their action, and that by this
simple plan they could shut out all cattle from the common, except the cattle of their joint tenants. --
Committee on Inclosures, 1844, p. 127.
Chapter Two
Enclosure (1)
An enclosure, like most Parliamentary operations, began with a petition from a local person or
persons, setting forth the inconveniencies of the present system and the advantages of such a
measure. Parliament, having received the petition, would give leave for a Bill to be introduced. The
Bill would be read a first and a second time, and would then be referred to a Committee, which, after
considering such petitions against the enclosure as the House of Commons referred to it, would
present its report. The Bill would then be passed, sent to the Lords, and receive the Royal Assent.
Finally, the Commissioners named in the Bill would descend on the district and distribute the land.
That is, in brief, the history of a successful enclosure agitation. We will now proceed to explore its
different stages in detail.
The original petition was often the act of a big landowner, whose solitary signature was enough to
set an enclosure process in train.(1*) Before 1774 it was not even incumbent on this single
individual to let his neighbours know that he was asking Parliament for leave to redistribute their
property. In that year the House of Commons made a Standing Order prodding that notice of any
such petition should be affixed to the church door in each of the parishes affected, for three
Sundays in the month of August or the month of September. This provision was laid down, as we
learn from the Report of the Committee that considered the Standing Orders in 1775, because it had
often happened that those whose land was to be enclosed knew nothing whatever of transactions in
which they were rather intimately concerned, until they were virtually completed.(2*)
But the publicity that was secured by this Standing Order, though it prevented the process of
enclosure from being completed in the dark, did not in practice give the village any kind of voice in
its own destiny. The promoters laid all their plans before they took their neighbours into the secret.
When their arrangements were mature, they gave notice to the parish in accordance with the
requirements of the Standing Order, or they first took their petition to the various proprietors for
signature, or in some cases they called a public meeting. The facts set out in the petition against the
Enclosure Bill for Haute Huntre, show that the promoters did not think that they were bound to
accept the opinion of a meeting. In that case 'the great majority' were hostile, but the promoters
proceeded with their petition notwithstanding.(3*) Whatever the precise method, unless some large
proprietor stood out against the scheme, the promoters were masters of the situation. This we know
from the evidence of witnesses favourable to enclosure. 'The proprietors of large estates,' said
Arthur Young, 'generally agree upon the measure, adjust the principal points among themselves,
and fix upon their attorney before they appoint any general meeting of the proprietors.'(4*)
Addington, in his Inquiry into the Reasons for and against Inclosing, quoting another writer, says,
'the whole plan is generally settled between the solicitor and two or three principal proprietors
without ever letting the rest of them into the secret till they are called upon to sign the petition.'(5*)
What stand could the small proprietor hope to make against such forces? The matter was a chose
jugée, and his assent a mere formality. If he tried to resist, he could be warned that the success of
the enclosure petition was certain, and that those who obstructed it would suffer, as those who
assisted it would gain, in the final award. His only prospect of successful opposition to the lord of the
manor, the magistrate, the impropriator of the tithes, the powers that enveloped his life, the powers
that appointed the commissioner who was to make the ultimate award, lay in his ability to move a
dim and distant Parliament of great landlords to come to his rescue. It needs no very penetrating
imagination to picture what would have happened in a village in which a landowner of the type of
Richardson's hero in Pamela was bent on an enclosure, and the inhabitants, being men like
Goodman Andrews, knew that enclosure meant their ruin. What, in point of fact, could the poor do to
declare their opposition? They could tear down the notices from the church doors:(6*) they could
break up a public meeting, if one were held: but the only way in which they could protest was by
violent and disorderly proceedings, which made no impression at all upon Parliament, and which the
forces of law and order could, if necessary, be summoned to quell.
The scene now shifts to Parliament, the High Court of Justice, the stronghold of the liberties of
Englishmen. Parliament hears the petition, and, almost as a matter of course, grants it, giving leave
for the introduction of a Bill, and instructing the member who presents the petition to prepare it. This
is not a very long business, for the promoters have generally taken the trouble to prepare their Bill in
advance. The Bill is submitted, read a first and second time, and then referred to a Committee. Now
a modern Parliamentary Private Bill Committee is regarded as a tribunal whose integrity and
impartiality are beyond question, and justly, for the most elaborate precautions are taken to secure
that it shall deserve this character. The eighteenth-century Parliament treated its Committee with
just as much respect, but took no precautions at all to obtain a disinterested court. Indeed, the
committee that considered an enclosure was chosen on the very contrary principle. This we know,
not from the evidence of unkind and prejudiced outsiders, but from the Report of the Committee of
the House of Commons, which inquired in 1825 into the constitution of Committees on Private Bills.
'Under the present system each Bill is committed to the Member who is charged with its
management and such other Members as he may choose to name in the House, and the Members
serving for a particular County (usually the County immediately connected with the object of the Bill)
and the adjoining Counties, and consequently it has been practically found that the Members to
whom Bills have been committed have been generally those who have been most interested in the
result.'
During the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries there developed the practice of opening the
committees. This was the system of applying to Private Bills the procedure followed in the case of
Public Bills, and proposing a resolution in the House of Commons that 'all who attend shall have
voices,' i.e., that any member of the House who cared to attend the committee should be able to
vote. We can see how this arrangement acted. It might happen that some of the county members
were hostile to a particular enclosure scheme; in that case the promoters could call for an open
committee and mass their friends upon it. It might happen, on the other hand, that the committee
was solid in supporting an enclosure, and that some powerful person in the House considered that
his interests, or the interests of his friend, had not been duly consulted in the division of the spoil. In
such a case he would call for all to 'have voices' and so compel the promoters to satisfy his claims.
This system then secured some sort of rough justice as between the powerful interests represented
in Parliament, but it left the small proprietors and the cottagers, who were unrepresented in this
mêlée, absolutely at the mercy of these conflicting forces.
It is difficult, for example, to imagine that a committee in which the small men were represented
would have sanctioned the amazing clause in the Ashelworth Act(7*) which provided 'that all fields
or inclosures containing the Property of Two or more Persons within one fence, and also all
inclosures containing the property of one Person only, if the same be held by or under different
Tenures or Interests, shall be considered as commonable land and be divided and allotted
accordingly.' This clause, taken with the clause that follows, simply meant that some big landowner
had his eye on some particular piece of enclosed property, which in the ordinary way would not
have gone into the melting-pot at all. The arrangements of the Wakefield Act would hardly have
saved the scrutiny of a committee on which the Duke of Leeds' class was not paramount. Under that
Act(8*) the duke was to have full power to work mines and get minerals, and those proprietors
whose premises suffered in consequence were to have reasonable satisfaction, not from the duke
who was enriched by the disturbing cause, but from all the allottees, including presumably those
whose property was damaged. Further, to save himself inconvenience, the duke could forbid
allottees on Westgate Moor to build a house for sixty years. A different kind of House of Commons
would have looked closely at the Act at Moreton Corbet which gave the Lord of the manor all
enclosures and encroachments more than twenty years old, and also at the not uncommon
provision which exempted the tithe-owner from paying for his own fencing.
The Report of the 1825 Committee describes the system as 'inviting all the interested parties in the
Souse to take part in the business of the committee, which necessarily terminates in the prevalence
of the strongest part, for they who have no interest of their own to serve will not be prevailed upon to
take part in a struggle in which their unbiassed judgment can have no effect.' The chairman of the
committee was generally the member who had moved to introduce the Bill. The unreformed
Parliament of landowners that passed the excellent Act of 1782, forbidding Members of Parliament
to have an interest in Government contracts, never thought until the eve of the Reform Bill that there
was anything remarkable in this habit of referring Enclosure Bills to the judgment of the very
landowners who were to profit by them. And in 1825 it was not the EncLosure Bills, in which. the rich
took and the poor suffered, but the Railway Bills, in which rich men were pitted against rich men,
that drew the attention of the House of Commons to the disadvantages and risks of this procedure.
The committee so composed sets to work on the Bill, and meanwhile, perhaps, some of the persons
affected by the enclosure send petitions against it to the Souse of Commons. Difficulties of time and
space would as a rule deter all but the rich dissentients, unless the enclosure was near London.
These petitions are differently treated according to their origin. If they emanate from a lord of the
manor, or from a tithe-owner, who for some reason or other is dissatisfied with the contemplated
arrangements, they receive some attention. In such a case the petitioner probably has some friend
in Parliament, and his point of view is understood. He can, if necessary, get this friend to attend the
committee and introduce amendments. He is therefore a force to be reckoned with; the Bill is
perhaps altered to suit him; the petition is at any rate referred to the committee. On the other hand, if
the petition comes from cottagers or small proprietors, it is safe, as a rule, to neglect it.
The enclosure histories set out in the Appendix supply some good examples of this differential
treatment. Lord Strafford sends a petition against the Bill for enclosing Wakefield with the result that
he is allowed to appoint a commissioner, and also that his dispute with the duke of Leeds is
exempted from the jurisdiction of the Enclosure Commissioners. On the other hand, the unfortunate
persons who petition against the monstrous provision that forbade them to erect any building for
twenty, forty or sixty years, get no kind of redress. In the case of Croydon, James Trecothick, Esq.,
who is dissatisfied with the Bill, is strong enough to demand special consideration. Accordingly a
special provision is made that the commissioners are obliged to sell Mr. Trecothick, by private
contract, part of Addington Hills, if he so wishes. But when the various freeholders, copyholders,
leaseholders and inhabitant householders of Croydon, who complain that the promoters of the Bill
have named commissioners without consulting the persons interested, ask leave to nominate a third
commissioner, only four members of the House of Commons support Lord William Russell's
proposal to consider this petition, and fifty-one vote the other way. Another example of the spirit in
which Parliament received petitions from unimportant persons is furnished by the case of the
enclosure of Holy Island. In 1791 (Feb. 23)(9*) a petition was presented to Parliament for the
enclosure of Holy Island, asking for the division of a stinted pasture, and the extinction of the rights
of common or 'eatage' over certain infield lands. Leave was given, and the Bill was prepared and
read a first time on 28th February. The same day Parliament received a petition from freeholders
and stallingers, who ask to be heard by themselves or by counsel against the Bill. From Eden(10*)
we learn that there were 26 freeholders and 31 stallingers, and that the latter were in the strict sense
of the term as much freeholders as the former. Whilst, however, a freeholder had the right to put 30
sheep, 4 black cattle and 3 horses on the stinted common, a stallinger had a right of common for
one horse and one cow only. The House ordered that this petition should lie on the table till the
second reading, and that the petitioners should then be heard. The second reading, which had been
fixed for 2nd April, was deferred till 20th April, a change which probably put the petitioners to
considerable expense. On 20th April the Bill was read a second time, and the House was informed
that Counsel attended, and a motion was made that Counsel be now called in. But the motion was
opposed, and on a division was defeated by 47 votes to 12. The Bill passed the House of Commons
on 10th May, and received the Royal Assent on 9th June.(11*) In this case the House of Commons
broke faith with the petitioners, and refused the hearing it had promised. Such experience was not
likely to encourage dissentients to waste their money on an appeal to Parliament against a Bill that
was promoted by powerful politicians. It will be observed that in many cases the petitioners did not
think that it was worth the trouble and expense to be heard on Second Reading.
The Report of the Committee followed a stereotyped formula: 'That the Standing Orders had been
complied with: and that the Committee had examined the Allegations of the Bill and found the same
to be true; and that the Parties concerned had given their Consent to the Bill, to the Satisfaction of
the Committee, except...'
Now what did this mean? What consents were necessary to satisfy the committee? The
Parliamentary Committee that reported on the cost of enclosures in 1800(12*) said that there was
no fixed rule, that in some cases the consent of three-fourths was required, in others the consent of
four-fifths. This proportion has a look of fairness until we discover that we are dealing in terms, not
of persons, but of property, and that the suffrages were not counted but weighed. The method by
which the proportions were reckoned varied, as a glance at the cases described in the Appendix will
show. Value is calculated sometimes in acres, sometimes in annual value, sometimes in
assessment to the land tax, sometimes in assessment to the poor rate. It is important to remember
that it was the property interested that counted, and that in a case where there was common or
waste to be divided as well as open fields, one large proprietor, who owned a considerable property
in old enclosures, could swamp the entire community of smaller proprietors and cottagers. If Squire
Western owned an enclosed estate with parks, gardens and farms of 800 acres, and the rest of the
parish consisted of a common or waste of 1000 acres and open fields of 200 acres, and the village
population consisted of 100 cottagers and small farmers, each with a strip of land in the common
fields, and a right of common on the waste, Squire Western would have a four-fifths majority in
determining whether the open fields and the waste should be enclosed or not, and the whole matter
would be in his hands. This is an extreme example of the way in which the system worked. The
case of Ashelworth shows that a common might be cut up, on the votes of persons holding enclosed
property, against the wishes of the great majority of the commoners. At Laleham the petitioners
against the Bill claimed that they were 'a great majority of the real Owners and Proprietors of or
Persons interested in, the Lands and Grounds intended to be enclosed.' At Simpson, where
common fields were to be enclosed, the Major Part of the Owners and Proprietors petitioned against
the Bill, stating that they were 'very well satisfied with the Situation and Convenience of their
respective Lands and Properties in their present uninclosed State.'(13*)
Even a majority of three-fourths in value was not always required; for example, the Report of the
Committee on the enclosure of Cartmel in Lancashire in 1796 gave particulars showing that the
whole property belonging to persons interested in the enclosure was assessed at £150, and that the
property of those actually consenting to the enclosure was just under £110.(14*) Yet the enclosure
was recommended and carried. Another illustration is supplied by the Report of the Committee on
the enclosure of Histon and Impington in 1801, where the parties concerned are reported to have
consented except the proprietors of 1020 acres, out of a total acreage of 3680.(15*) In this case the
Bill was recommitted, and on its next appearance the committee gave the consents in terms of
assessment to the Land Tax instead, putting the total figure at £304, and the assessment of the
consenting parties at £188. This seems to have satisfied the House of Commons.(16*) Further, the
particulars given in the case of the enclosure of Bishopstone in Wilts (enclosed in 1809) show that
the votes of copyholders were heavily discounted. In this case the copyholders who dissented held
1079 acres, the copyholders who were neuter 81 acres, and the total area to be divided was 2602
acres. But by some ingenious actuarial calculation of the reversionary interest of the lord of the
manor and the interest of the tithe-owner, the 1079 acres held by copyholders are written down to
474 acres.(17*) In the cases of Simpson and Louth, as readers who consult the proceedings will
see, the committees were satisfied with majorities just above three-fifths in value. At Raunds, where
4963 acres were 'interested,' the owners of 570 are stated to be against, and of 721 neuter.(18*) An
interesting illustration of the lax practice of the committees is provided in the history of an attempted
enclosure at Quainton (1801).(19*) In any case the signatures were a doubtful evidence of consent.
'It is easy,' wrote an acute observer, 'for the large proprietors to overcome opposition. Coaxing,
bribing, threatening, together with many other acts which superiors will make use, often induce the
inferiors to consent to things which they think will be to their future disadvantage.(20*) We hear
echoes of such proceedings in the petition from various owners and proprietors at Armley, who 'at
the instance of several other owners of land,' signed a petition for enclosure and wish to be heard
against it, and also in the unavailing petition of some of the proprietors and freeholders of Winfrith
Newburgh in Dorsetshire, in 1768,(21*) who declared that if the Bill passed into law, their 'Estates
must be totally ruined thereby, and that some of the Petitioners by Threats and Menaces were
prevailed upon to sign the Petition for the said Bill: but upon Recollection, and considering the
impending Ruin,' they prayed to 'have Liberty to retract from their seeming Acquiescence.' From the
same case we learn that it was the practice sometimes to grant copyholds on the condition that the
tenant would undertake not to oppose enclosure. Sometimes, as in the case of the Sedgmoor
Enclosure, which we shall discuss later, actual fraud was employed. But even if the promoters
employed no unfair methods they had one argument powerful enough to be a deterrent in many
minds. For an opposed Enclosure Bill was much more expensive than an unopposed Bill, and as
the small men felt the burden of the costs much more than the large proprietors, they would
naturally be shy of adding to the very heavy expenses unless they stood a very good chance of
defeating the scheme.
It is of capital importance to remember in this connection that the enumeration of 'consents' took
account only of proprietors. It ignored entirely two large classes to whom enclosure meant, not a
greater or less degree of wealth, but actual ruin. These were such cottagers as enjoyed their rights
of common in virtue of renting cottages to which such rights were attached, and those cottagers and
squatters who either had no strict legal right, or whose rights were difficult of proof. Neither of these
classes was treated even outwardly and formally as having any claim to be consulted before an
enclosure was sanctioned.
It is clear, then, that it was only the pressure of the powerful interests that decided whether a
committee should approve or disapprove of an Enclosure Bill. It was the same pressure that
determined the form in which a Bill became law. For a procedure that enabled rich men to fight out
their rival claims at Westminster left the classes that could not send counsel to Parliament without a
weapon or a voice. And if there was no lawyer there to put his case, what prospect was there that
the obscure cottager, who was to be turned adrift with his family by an Enclosure Bill promoted by a
Member or group of Members, would ever trouble the conscience of a committee of landowners?
We have seen already how this class was regarded by the landowners and the champions of
enclosure. No cottagers had votes or the means of influencing a single vote at a single election. To
Parliament, if they had any existence at all, they were merely dim shadows in the very background
of the enclosure scheme. It would require a considerable effort of the imagination to suppose that
the Parliamentary Committee spent very much time or energy on the attempt to give body and form
to this hazy and remote society, and to treat these shadows as living men and women, about to be
tossed by this revolution from their ancestral homes. As it happens, we need not put ourselves to
the trouble of such speculation, for we have the evidence of a witness who will not be suspected of
injustice to his class. 'This I know,' said Lord Lincoln(22*) introducing the General Enclosure Bill of
1845, 'that in nineteen cases out of twenty, Committees of this House sitting on private Bills
neglected the rights of the poor. I do not say that they wilfully neglected those rights -- far from it: but
this I affirm, that they were neglected in consequence of the Committees being permitted to remain
in ignorance of the claims of the poor man, because by reason of his very poverty he is unable to
come up to London for counsel, to produce witnesses, and to urge his claims before a Committee of
this House.' Another Member(23*) had described a year earlier the character of this private Bill
procedure. 'Inclosure Bills had been introduced heretofore and passed without discussion, and no
one could tell how many persons had suffered in their interests and rights by the interference of
these Bills. Certainly these Bills had been referred to Committees upstairs, but everyone knew how
these Committees were generally conducted. They were attended only by honourable Members
who were interested in them, being Lords of Manor, and the rights of the poor, though they might be
talked about, had frequently been taken away under that system.'
These statements were made by politicians who remembered well the system they were describing.
There is another witness whose authority is even greater. In 1781 Lord Thurlow, then at the
beginning of his long life of office as Lord Chancellor,(24*) spoke for an hour and three quarters in
favour of recommitting the Bill for enclosing Ilmington in Warwickshire. If the speech had been fully
reported it would be a contribution of infinite value to students of the social history of eighteenth-
century England, for we are told that he proceeded to examine, paragraph by paragraph, every
provision of the Bill, animadverting and pointing out some acts of injustice, partiality, obscurity or
cause of confusion in each.'(25*) Unfortunately this part of his speech was omitted in the report as
being 'irrelative to the debate,' which was concerned with the question of the propriety of commuting
tithes. But the report, incomplete as it is, contains an illuminating passage on the conduct of Private
Bill Committees. 'His Lordship... next turned his attention to the mode in which private bills were
permitted to make their way through both Houses, and that in matters in which property was
concerned, to the great injury of many, if not the total ruin of some private families: many proofs of
this evil had come to his knowledge as a member of the other House, not a few in his professional
character, before he had the honour of a seat in that House, nor had he been a total stranger to
such evils since he was called upon to preside in another place.' Going on to speak of the
committees of the House of Commons and 'the rapidity with which private Bills were hurried
through,' he declared that 'it was not unfrequent to decide upon the merits of a Bill which would
affect the property and interests of persons inhabiting a district of several miles in extent, in less
time than it took him to determine upon the propriety of issuing an order for a few pounds, by which
no man's property could be injured.' He concluded by telling the House of Lords a story of how Sir
George Savile once noticed a man 'rather meanly habited' watching the proceedings of a committee
with anxious interest. When the committee had agreed on its report, the agitated spectator was
seen to be in great distress. Sir George Savile asked him what was the matter, and he found that
the man would be ruined by a clause that had been passed by the committee, and that, having
heard that the Bill was to be introduced, he had made his way to London on foot, too poor to come
in any other way or to fee counsel. Savile then made inquiries and learnt that these statements were
correct, whereupon he secured the amendment of the Bill, 'by which means an innocent, indigent
man and his family were rescued from destruction.' It would not have been very easy for a 'meanly
habited man' to make the journey to London from Wakefield or Knaresborough or Haute Huntre,
even if he knew when a Bill was coming on, and to stay in London until it went into committee; and if
he did, he would not always be so lucky as to find a Sir George Savile on the committee -- the public
man who was regarded by his contemporaries, to whatever party they belonged, as the Bayard of
politics.(26*)
We get very few glimpses into the underworld of the common and obscure people, whose homes
and fortunes trembled on the chance that a quarrel over tithes and the conflicting claims of squire
and parson might disturb the unanimity of a score of gentlemen sitting round a table. London was
far away, and the Olympian peace of Parliament was rarely broken by the protests of its victims. But
we get one such glimpse in a passage in the Annual Register for 1767.
'On Tuesday evening a great number of farmers were observed going along Pall Mall with cockades
in their hats. On enquiring the reason, it appeared they all lived in or near the parish of Stanwell in
the county of Middlesex, and they were returning to their wives and families to carry them the
agreeable news of a Bill being rejected for inclosing the said common, which if carried into
execution, might have been the ruin of a great number of families.'(27*)
When the Committee on the Enclosure Bill had reported to the House of Commons, the rest of the
proceedings were generally formal. The Bill was read a third time, engrossed, sent up to the Lords,
where petitions might be presented as in the Commons, and received the Royal Assent.
A study of the pages of Hansard and Debrett tells us little about transactions that fill the Journals of
the Houses of Parliament. Three debates in the House of Lords are fully reported,(28*) and they
illustrate the play of forces at Westminster. The Bishop of St. Davids(29*) moved to recommit an
Enclosure Bill in 1781 on the ground that, like many other Enclosure Bills, it provided for the
commutation of tithes -- an arrangement which he thought open to many objections. Here was an
issue that was vital, for it concerned the interests of the classes represented in Parliament. Did the
Church stand to gain or to lose by taking land instead of tithe? Was it a bad thing or a good thing
that the parson should be put into the position of a farmer, that he should be under the temptation to
enter into an arrangement with the landlord which might prejudice his successor, that he should be
relieved from a system which often caused bad blood between him and his parishioners? Would it
'make him neglect the sacred functions of his ministry' as the Bishop of St. Davids feared, or would
it improve his usefulness by rescuing him from a situation in which 'the pastor was totally sunk in the
tithe collector' as the Bishop of Peterborough(30*) hoped, and was a man a better parson on the
Sunday for being a farmer the rest of the week as Lord Coventry believed? The bishops and the
peers had in this discussion a subject that touched very nearly the lives and interests of themselves
and their friends, and there was a considerable and animated debate,(31*) at the end of which the
House of Lords approved the principle of commuting tithes in Enclosure Bills. This debate was
followed by another on 6th April, when Lord Bathurst (President of the Council) as a counterblast to
his colleague on the Woolsack, moved, but afterwards withdrew, a series of resolutions on the same
subject. In the course of this debate Thurlow, who thought perhaps that his zeal for the Church had
surprised and irritated his fellowpeers, among whom he was not conspicuous in life as a practising
Christian, explained that though he was zealous for the Church, 'his zeal was not partial or confined
to the Church, further than it was connected with the other great national establishments, of which it
formed a part, and no inconsiderable one.' The Bishop of St. Davids returned to the subject on the
14th June, moving to recommit the Bill for enclosing Kington in Worcestershire. He read a string of
resolutions which he wished to see applied to all future Enclosure Bills, in order to defend the
interests of the clergy from 'the oppressions of the Lord of the Manor, landowners, etc.' Thurlow
spoke for him, but he was defeated by 24 votes to 4, his only other supporters being Lord Galloway
and the Bishop of Lincoln.
Thurlow's story of Sir George Savile's 'meanly habited man' did not disturb the confidence of the
House of Lords in the justice of the existing procedure towards the poor: the enclosure debates
revolve solely round the question of the relative claims of the lord of the manor and the tithe-owner.
The House of Commons was equally free from scruple or misgiving. One petitioner in 1800
commented on the extraordinary haste with which a New Forest Bill was pushed through
Parliament, and suggested that if it, were passed into law in this rapid manner at the end of a
session, some injustice might unconsciously be done. The Speaker replied with a grave and
dignified rebuke: 'The House was always competent to give every subject the consideration due to
its importance, and could not therefore be truly said to be incapable at any time of discussing any
question gravely, dispassionately, and with strict regard to justice.'(32*) He recommended that the
petition should be passed over as if it had never been presented. The member who had presented
the petition pleaded that he had not read it. Such were the plausibilities and decorum in which the
House of Commons mapped up its abuses. We can imagine that some of the members must have
smiled to each other like the Roman augurs, when they exchanged these solemn hypocrisies.
We have a sidelight on the vigilance of the House of Commons, when an Enclosure Bill came down
from a committee, in a speech of Windham's in defence of bull-baiting. Windham attacked the
politicians who had introduced the Bill to abolish bull-baiting, for raising such a question at a time of
national crisis when Parliament ought to be thinking of other things. He then went on to compare the
subject to local subjects that 'contained nothing of public or general interest. To procure the
discussion of such subjects it was necessary to resort to canvass and intrigue. Members whose
attendance was induced by local considerations in most cases of this description, were present: the
discussion, if any took place, was managed by the friends of the measure: and the decision of the
House was ultimately, perhaps, a matter of mere chance.' From Sheridan's speech in answer, we
learn that this is a description of the passing of Enclosure Bills. 'Another honourable gentleman who
had opposed this Bill with peculiar vehemence, considered it as one of those light and trivial
subjects, which was not worthy to occupy the deliberations of Parliament: and he compared it to
certain other subjects of Bills: that is to say, bills of a local nature, respecting inclosures and other
disposal of property, which merely passed by chance, as Members could not be got to attend their
progress by dint of canvassing,'(33*) Doubtless most Members of the House of Commons shared
the sentiments of Lord Sandwich, who told the House of Lords that he was so satisfied 'that the
more inclosures the better, that as far as his poor abilities would enable him, he would support every
inclosure bill that should be brought into the House.'(34*)
For the last act of an enclosure drama the scene shifts back to the parish. The commissioners
arrive, receive and determine claims, and publish an award, mapping out the new village. The life
and business of the village are now in suspense, and the commissioners are often authorised to
prescribe the course of husbandry during the transition.(35*) The Act which they administer provides
that a certain proportion of the land is to be assigned to the lord of the manor, in virtue of his rights,
and a certain proportion to the owner of the tithes. An occasional Act provides that some small
allotment shall be made to the poor: otherwise the commissioners have a free hand: their powers
are virtually absolute. This is the impression left by all contemporary writers. Arthur Young, for
example, writes emphatically in this sense. 'Thus is the property of proprietors, and especially of the
poor ones, entirely at their mercy: every passion of resentment and prejudice may be gratified
without control, for they are vested with a despotic power known in no other branch of business in
this free country.'(36*) Similar testimony is found in the Report of the Select Committee (1800) on
the Expense and Mode of Obtaining Bills of Enclosure: 'the expediency of despatch, without the
additional expense of multiplied litigation, has suggested the necessity of investing them with a
summary, and in most cases uncontrollable jurisdiction.'(37*) In the General Report of the Board of
Agriculture on Enclosures, published in 1808, though any more careful procedure is deprecated as
likely to cause delay, it is stated that the adjusting of property worth £50,000 was left to the
arbitration of a majority of five, 'often persons of mean education.' The author of An Inquiry into the
Advantages and disadvantages resulting from Bills of Inclosure, published in 1781, writes as if it was
the practice to allow an appeal to Quarter Sessions; such an appeal he characterised as useless to
a poor man, and we can well believe that most of the squires who sat on such a tribunal to punish
vagrants or poachers had had a hand in an enclosure in the past or had their eyes on an enclosure
in the future. Thurlow considered such an appeal quite inadequate, giving the more polite reason
that Quarter Sessions had not the necessary time.(38*) The Act of 1801 is silent on the subject, but
Sinclair's draft of a General Inclosure Bill, published in the Annals of Agriculture in 1796,(39*)
provided for an appeal to Quarter Sessions. In the case of five enclosures mentioned in these
chapters (Haute Huntre, Simpson, Stanwell, Wakefield and Winfrith Newburgh), the decision of the
commissioners on claims was final, except that at Wakefield an objector might oblige the
commissioners to take the opinion of a counsel chosen by themselves. In five cases (Ashelworth,
Croydon, Cheshunt, Laleham and Louth), a disappointed claimant might bring a suit on a feigned
issue against a proprietor. At Armley and Knaresborough the final decision was left to arbitrators,
but whereas at Armley the arbitrator was to be chosen by a neutral authority, the Recorder of Leeds,
the arbitrators at Knaresborough were named in the Act, and were presumably as much the
nominees of the promoters as the commissioners themselves.
The statements of contemporaries already quoted go to show that none of these arrangements were
regarded as seriously fettering the power of the commissioners, and it is easy to understand that a
lawsuit, which might of course overwhelm him, was not a remedy for the use of a small proprietor or
a cottager, though it might be of some advantage to a large proprietor who had not been fortunate
enough to secure adequate representation of his interests on the Board of Commissioners. But the
decision as to claims was only part of the business. A man's claim might be allowed, and yet gross
injustice might be done him in the redistribution. He might be given inferior land, or land in an
inconvenient position. In most of the cases cited in this chapter the award of the commissioners is
stated to be final, and there is no appeal from it. Two exceptions are Knaresborough and Armley.
The Knaresborough Act is silent on the point, and the Armley Act allows an appeal to the Recorder
of Leeds. So far therefore as the claims and allotments of the poor were concerned, the
commissioners were in no danger of being overruled. Their freedom in other ways was restricted by
the Standing Orders of 1774, which obliged them to give an account of their expenses.
It would seem to be obvious that any society which had an elementary notion of the meaning and
importance of justice would have taken the utmost pains to see that the men appointed to this
extraordinary office had no motive for showing partiality. This might not reasonably have been
expected of the society about which Pitt declared in the House of Commons, that it was the boast of
the law of England that it afforded equal security and protection to the high and low, the rich and
poor.(40*) How were these commissioners appointed at the time that Pitt was Prime Minister? They
were appointed in each case before the Bill was presented to Parliament, and generally, as Young
tells us, they were appointed by the promoters of the enclosure before the petition was submitted for
local signatures, so that in fact they were nominated by the persons of influence who agreed on the
measure. In one case (Moreton Corbet in Shropshire; 1950 acres enclosed in 1797) the Act
appointed one commissioner only, and he was to name his successor. Sometimes, as in the case of
Otmoor,(41*) it might happen that the commissioners were changed while the Bill was passing
through Committee, if some powerful persons were able to secure better representation of their own
interests. In the case of Wakefield again, the House of Commons Committee placated Lord
Strafford by giving him a commissioner.
Now, who was supposed to have a voice in the appointment of the commissioners? There is to be
found in the Annals of Agriculture(42*) an extremely interesting paper by Sir John Sinclair,
preliminary to a memorandum of the General Enclosure Bill which he promoted in 1796. Sinclair
explains that he had had eighteen hundred Enclosure Acts (taken indiscriminately) examined in
order to ascertain what was the usual procedure and what stipulations were made with regard to
particular interests; this with the intention of incorporating the recognised practice in his General Bill.
In the course of these remarks he says, 'the probable result will be the appointment of one
Commissioner by the Lord of the Manor, of another by the tithe-owner, and of a third by the major
part in value of the proprietors.'(43*) It will be observed that the third commissioner is not appointed
by a majority of the commoners, nor even by the majority of the proprietors, but by the votes of
those who own the greater part of the village. This enables us to assess the value of what might
have seemed a safeguard to the poor -- the provision that the names of the commissioners should
appear in the Bill presented to Parliament. The lord of the manor, the impropriator of tithes, and the
majority in value of the owners are a small minority of the persons affected by an enclosure, and all
that they have to do is to meet round a table and name the commissioners who are to represent
them.(44*) Thus we find that the powerful persons who carried an enclosure against the will of the
poor nominated the tribunal before which the poor had to make good their several claims. This was
the way in which the constitution that Pitt was defending afforded equal security and protection to
the rich and to the poor.
It will be noticed further that two interests are chosen out for special representation. They are the
lord of the manor and the impropriator of tithes: in other words, the very persons who are formally
assigned a certain minimum in the distribution by the Act of Parliament. Every Act after 1774
declares that the lord of the manor is to have a certain proportion, and the tithe-owner a certain
proportion of the land divided: scarcely any Act stipulates that any share at all is to go to the cottager
or the small proprietor. Yet in the appointment of commissioners the interests that are protected by
the Act have a preponderating voice, and the interests that are left to the caprice of the
commissioners have no voice at all. Thurlow, speaking in the House of Lords in 1781,(45*) said that
it was grossly unjust to the parson that his property should be at the disposal of these
commissioners, of whom he only nominated one. 'He thanked God that the property of an
Englishman depended not on so loose a tribunal in any other instance whatever.' What, then, was
the position of the poor and the small farmers who were not represented at all among the
commissioners? In the paper already quoted, Sinclair mentions that in.some cases the
commissioners were peers, gentlemen and clergymen, residing in the neighbourhood, who acted
without fees or emolument. He spoke of this as undertaking a useful duty, and it does not seem to
have occurred to him that there was any objection to such a practice. 'To lay down the principle that
men are to serve for nothing,' said Cobbett, in criticising the system of unpaid magistrates, 'puts me
in mind of the servant who went on hire, who being asked what wages he demanded, said he
wanted no wages: for that he always found about the house little things to pick up.'
There is a curious passage in the General Report of the Board of Agriculture(46*) on the subject of
the appointment of commissioners. The writer, after dwelling on the unexampled powers that the
commissioners enjoy, remarks that they are not likely to be abused, because a commissioner's
prospect of future employment in this profitable capacity depends on his character for integrity and
justice. This is a reassuring reJection for the classes that promoted enclosures and appointed
commissioners, but it rings with a very different sound in other ears. It would dearly have been much
better for the poor if the commissioners had not had any prospect of future employment at all. We
can obtain some idea of the kind of men whom the landowners considered to be competent and
satisfactory commissioners from the Standing Orders of 1801, which forbade the employment in this
capacity of the bailiff of the lord of the manor. It would be interesting to know how much of England
was appropriated on the initiative of the lord of the manor, by his bailiff, acting under the authority
given to him by the High Court of Parliament. It is significant, too, that down to 1801 a commissioner
was only debarred from buying land in a parish in which he had acted in this capacity, until his
award was made, The Act of 1801 debarred him from buying land under such circumstances for the
following five years.
The share of the small man in these transactions from first to last can be estimated from the
language of Arthur Young in 1770. 'The small proprietor whose property in the township is perhaps
his all, has little or no weight in regulating the clauses of the Act of Parliament, has seldom, if ever,
an opportunity of putting a single one in the Bill favourable to his rights, and has as little influence in
the choice of Commissioners.'(47*) But even this description does less than justice to his
helplessness. There remains to be considered the procedure before the commissioners themselves.
Most Enclosure Acts specified a date before which all claims had to be presented. It is obvious that
there must have been very many small proprietors who had neither the courage nor the knowledge
necessary to put and defend their case, and that vast numbers of claims must have been
disregarded because they were not presented, or because they were presented too late, or because
they were irregUlar in form. The Croydon Act, for example, prescribes that claimants must send in
their claims 'in Writing under their Hands, or the Hands of their Agents, distinguishing in such
Claims the Tenure of the Estates in respect whereof such Claims are made, and stating therein
such further Particulars as shall be necessary to describe such Claims with Precision.' And if this
was a difficult fence for the small proprietor, unaccustomed to legal forms and documents, or to
forms and documents of any kind, what was the plight of the cottager? Let us imagine the cottager,
unable to read or write, enjoying certain customary rights of common without any idea of their origin
or history or legal basis: knowing only that as long as he can remember he has kept a cow, driven
geese across the waste, pulled his fuel out of the neighbouring brushwood, and cut turf from the
common, and that his father did all these things before him. The cottager learns that before a certain
day he has to present to his landlord's bailiff, or to the parson, or to one of the magistrates into
whose hands perhaps he has fallen before now over a little matter of a hare or a partridge, or to
some solicitor from the country town, a clear and correct statement of his rights and his claim to a
share in the award. Let us remember at the same time all that we know from Fielding and Smollett
of the reputation of lawyers for cruelty to the poor. Is a cottager to be trusted to face the ordeal, or to
be in time with his statement, or to have that statement in proper legal form? The commissioners
can reject his claim on the ground of any technical irregularity, as we learn from a petition presented
to Parliament in 1774 by several persons interested in the enclosure of Knaresborough Forest,
whose claims had been disallowed by the commissioners because of certain 'mistakes made in the
description of such tenements... notwithstanding the said errors were merely from inadvertency 'and
in no way altered the merits of the petitioners' claims.' A Bill was before Parliament to amend the
previous Act for enclosing Knaresborough Forest, in respect of the method of payment of expenses,
and hence these petitioners had an opportunity of making their treatment public.(48*) It is easy to
guess what was the fate of many a small proprietor or cottager, who had to describe his tenement or
common right to an unsympathetic tribunal. We are not surprised that one of the witnesses told the
Enclosure Committee of 1844 that the poor often did not know what their claims were, or how to
present them. It is significant that in the case of Sedgmoor, out of 4063 claims sent in, only 1798
were allowed.(49*)
We have now given an account of the procedure by which Parliamentary enclosures were carried
out. We give elsewhere a detailed analysis, disentangled from the Journals of Parliament and other
sources, of particular enclosures. We propose to give here two frustrations of the temper of the
Parliamentary Committees. One illustration is provided by a speech made by Sir William Meredith,
one of the Rockingham Whigs, in 1772, a speech that needs no comment. 'Sir William Meredith
moved, That it might be a general order, that no Bill, or clause in a Bill, making any offence capital,
should be agreed to but in a Committee of the whole House. He observed, that at present the facility
of passing such clauses was shameful: that he once passing a Committee-room, when only one
Member was holding a Committee, with a clerk's boy, he happened to hear something of hanging;
he immediately had the curiosity to ask what was going forward in that small Committee that could
merit such a punishment? He was answered, that it was an Inclosing Bill, in which a great many
poor people were concerned, who opposed the Bill; that they feared those people would obstruct the
execution of the Act, and therefore this clause was to make it capital felony in anyone who did so.
This resolution was unanimously agreed to.'(50*)
The other illustration is provided by the history of an attempted enclosure in which we can watch the
minds of the chief actors without screen or disguise of any kind: in this case we have very
fortunately a vivid revelation of the spirit and manner in which Committees conducted their business,
from the pen of the chairman himself. George Selwyn gives us in his letters, published in the
Carlisle Papers, a view of the proceedings from the inside. It is worth while to set out in some detail
the passages from these letters published in the Carlisle Papers, by way of supplementing and
explaining the official records of the House of Commons.
We learn from the Journals of the House of Commons that, on 10th November, 1775, a petition was
presented to the House of Commons for the enclosure of King's Sedgmoor, in the County of
Somerset, the petitioners urging that this land was of very little value in its present state, and that it
was capable of great improvement by enclosure and drainage. Leave was given to bring in a Bill, to
be prepared by Mr. St. John and Mr. Coxe. Mr. St. John was brother of Lord Bolingbroke. On 13th
November, the Bill was presented and read a first time. Four days later it received a second reading,
and was sent to a Committee of Mr. St. John and others. At this point, those who objected to the
enclosure began to take action. First of all there is a petition from William Waller, Esq., who says
that under a grant of Charles I he is entitled to the soil of the moor: it is agreed that he shall be
heard by counsel before the Committee. The next day there arrives a petition from owners and
occupiers in thirty-five 'parishes, hamlets and places,' who state that all these parishes have enjoyed
rights of common without discrimination over the 18,000 acres of pasture on Sedgmoor: that these
rights of pasture and cutting turf and rushes and sedges have existed from time immemorial, and
that no Enclosure Act is wanted for the draining of Sedgmoor, because an Act of the reign of
William III had conferred all the necessary powers for this purpose on the Justices of the Peace.
The petitioners prayed to be heard by themselves and counsel against the application for enclosure
on Committee and on Report. The House of Commons ordered that the petition should lie on the
Table, and that the petitioners should be heard when the Report had been received from
Committee. Five days later three lords of manors (Sir Charles Kemys Tynte, Baronet, Copleston
Warre Bampfylde, Esq., and William Hawker, Esq.) petition against the Bill and complain of the
haste with which the promoters are pushing the Bill through Parliament. This petition is taken more
seriously: a motion is made and defeated to defer the Bill for two months, but the House orders that
the petitioners shall be heard before the Committee. Two of these three lords of manor present a
further petition early in December, stating that they and their tenants are more than a majority in
number and value of the persons interested, and a second petition is also presented by the thirty-
seven parishes and hamlets already mentioned, in which it is contended that, in spite of the
difficulties of collecting signatures in a scattered district in a very short time, 749 persons interested
had already signed the petition against the Bill, that the effect of the Bill had been misrepresented to
many of the tenants, that the facts as to the different interests affected had been misrepresented to
the Committee, that the number and rights of the persons supporting the Bill had been exaggerated
(only 213 having signed their names as consenting), and that if justice was to be done to the various
parties concerned, it was essential that time should be given for the hearing of complaints and the
circulation of the Bill in the district. This petition was presented on 11th December, and the House of
Commons ordered that the petitioners should be heard when the Report was received. Next day Mr.
Selwyn, as Chairman of the Committee, presented a Report in favour of the Bill, mentioning among
other things that the number of tenements concerned was 1269, and that 303 refused to sign; but
attention was drawn to the fact that there were several variations between the Bill as it was
presented to the House, and the Bill as it was presented to the parties concerned for their consent,
and on this ground the Bill was defeated by 59 to 35 votes.
This is the cold impersonal account of the proceedings given in the official journals, but the letters of
Selwyn take us behind the scenes and supply a far livelier picture.(51*) His account begins with a
letter to Lord Carlisle in November:
<ex>
'Bully has a scheme of enclosure, which, if it succeeds, I am told will free him from all his difficulties.
It is to come into our House immediately. If I had this from a better judgment than that of our
sanguine counsellors, I should have more hopes from it. I am ready to allow that he has been very
faulty, but I cannot help wishing to see him once more on his legs....'
</ex>
(Bully, of course, is Bolingbroke, brother of St. John, called the counsellor, author of the Bill.) We
learn from this letter that there are other motives than a passion to drain Sedgmoor in the promotion
of this great improvement scheme. We learn from the next letter that it is not only Bully's friends and
creditors who have some reason for wishing it well:
<ex>
'Stavordale is returning to Redlinch; I believe that he sets out to-morrow. He is also deeply engaged
in this Sedgmoor Bill, and it is supposed that he or Lord Ilchester, which you please, will get 2000 l.
a year by it. He will get more, or save more at least, by going away and leaving the Moor in my
hands, for he told me himself the other night that this last trip to town had cost him 4000 l.'
</ex>
Another letter warns Lord Carlisle that the only way to get his creditors to pay their debts to him,
when they come into their money through the enclosure, is to press for payment, and goes on to
describe the unexpected opposition the Bill had encountered. Selwyn had been made chairman of
the Committee.
<ex>
'... My dear Lord, if your delicacy is such that you will not be pressing with him about it, you may be
assured that you will never receive a farthing. I have spoke to Hare about it, who [was] kept in it till
half an hour after 4; as I was also to-day, and shall be to-morrow. I thought that it was a matter of
form only, but had no sooner begun to read the preamble to the Bill, but I found myself in a nest of
hornets. The room was full, and an opposition made to it, and disputes upon every word, which kept
me in the Chair, as I have told you. I have gained it seems great reputation, and am at this minute
reputed one of the best Chairmen upon this stand. Bully and Harry came home and dined with
me....'
</ex>
The next letter, written on 9th December, shows that Selwyn is afraid that Stavordale may not get
his money out of his father, and also that he is becoming still more anxious about the fate of the
Enclosure Bill, on which of course the whole pack of cards depends:
<ex>
'... I have taken the liberty to talk a good deal to Lord Stavordale, partly for his own sake and partly
for Yours, and pressed him much to get out of town as soon as possible, and not quit Lord I.
[Ilchester] any more. His attention there cannot be of long duration, and his absence may be fatal to
us all. I painted it in very strong colours, and he has promised me to go, as soon as this Sedgmoor
Bill is reported. I moved to have Tuesday fixed for it. We had a debate and division upon my motion,
and this Bill will at last not go down so glibly as Bully hoped that it would. It will meet with more
opposition in the H. of Lords, and Lord North being adverse to it, does us no good. Lord Ilchester
gets, it is said, £5000 a year by it, and amongst others Sir C. Tynte something, who, for what reason
I cannot yet comprehend, opposes it....'
</ex>
The next letter describes the final catastrophe:
<ex>
'December 12. Tuesday night... Bully has lost his Bill. I reported it to-day, and the Question was to
withdraw it. There were 59 against us, and we were 35. It was worse managed by the agents,
supposing no treachery, than ever business was. Lord North, Robinson, and Keene divided against.
Charles(52*) said all that could be said on our side. But as the business was managed, it was the
worst Question that I ever voted for. We were a Committee absolutely of Almack's,(53*) so if the Bill
is not resumed, and better conducted and supported, this phantom of 30,000 l. clear in Bully's
pocket to pay off his annuities vanishes.
'It is surprising what a fatality attends some people's proceedings. I begged last night as for alms,
that they would meet me to settle the Votes. I have, since I have been in Parliament, been of twenty
at least of these meetings, and always brought numbers down by those means. But my advice was
slighted, and twenty people were walking about the streets who could have carried this point.
'The cause was not bad, but the Question was totally indigestible. The most conscientious man in
the House in Questions of this nature, Sir F. Drake, a very old acquaintance of mine, told me that
nothing could be so right as the enclosure. But they sent one Bill into the country for the assent of
the people interested, and brought me another, differing in twenty particulars, to carry through the
Committee, without once mentioning to me that the two Bills differed. This they thought was
cunning, and I believe a happy composition of Bully's cunning and John's idea of his own par.ts. I
had no idea, or could have, of this difference. The adverse party said nothing of it, comme de raison,
reserving the objection till the Report, and it was insurmountable. If one of the Clerks only had
hinted it to me, inexperienced as I am in these sort of Bills, I would have stopped it, and by that
means have given them a better chance by a new Bill than they can have now, that people will have
a pretence for not altering their opinion....'
</ex>
These letters compensate for the silence of Hansard, so real and instructive a picture do they
present of the methods and motives of enclosure. 'Bully has a scheme of enclosure which, if it
succeeds, I am told will free him from all his difficulties.' The journals may talk of the undrained
fertility of Sedgmoor, but we have in this sentence the aspect of the enclosure that interests Selwyn,
the Chairman of the Committee, and from beginning to end of the proceedings no other aspect ever
enters his head. And it interests a great many other people besides Selwyn, for Bully owes money;
so too does Stavordale, another prospective beneficiary: he owes money to Fox, and Fox owes
money to Carlisle. Now Bully and Stavordale are not the only eighteenth-century aristocrats who are
in difficulties; the waiters at Brooks's and at White's know that well enough, as Selwyn felt when, on
hearing that one of them had been attested for felony, he exclaimed, 'What an idea of us he will give
in Newgate.' Nor is Bully the only aristocrat in difficulties whose thoughts turn to enclosure; Selwyn's
letters alone, with their reference to previous successes, would make that clear. It is here that we
begin to appreciate the effect of our system of family settlements in keeping the aristocracy
together. These young men, whose fortunes come and go in the hurricanes of the faro table, would
soon have dissipated their estates if they had been free to do it; as they were restrained by
settlements, they could only mortgage them. But there is a limit to this process, and after a time their
debts begin to overwhelm them; perhaps also too many of their fellow gamblers are their creditors to
make Brooks's or White's quite as comfortable a place as it used to be, for we may doubt whether
all of these creditors were troubled with Lord Carlisle's morbid delicacy of feeling. Happily there is
an escape from this painful situation: a scheme of enclosure which will put him 'once more on his
legs.' The other parties concerned are generally poor men, and there is not much danger of failure.
Thus if we trace the adventures of the gaming table to their bitter end, we begin to understand that
these wild revellers are gambling not with their own estates but with the estates of their neighbours.
This is the only property they can realise. Quidquid delirant reges plectuntur Achivi.
The particular obstacle on which the scheme split was a fraudulent irregularity the Bill submitted for
signature to the inhabitants differing seriously (in twenty particulars) from the Bill presented to
Parliament. Selwyn clearly attached no importance at all to the Petitions that were received against
the Bill, or to the evidence of its local unpopularity. It is clear too, that it was very rare for a scheme
like this to miscarry, for, speaking of his becoming Chairman of the Committee, he adds, 'I thought it
was a matter of form only.' Further with a little care this project would have weathered the discovery
of the fraud of which the author were guilty. 'I begged last night as for alms that they would meet us
to settle the Votes. I have, since I have been in Parliament, been of twenty at least of these
meetings, and always brought number down by these means. But my advice was slighted, and
twenty people were walking about the streets who could have carried this point.' In other words, the
Bill would have been carried, all its iniquities notwithstanding, if only Bully's friends had taken
Selwyn's advice and put themselves out to go down to Westminster. So little impression did this
piece of trickery make on the mind of the Chairman of the Committee, that he intended to the last,
by collecting his friends, to carry the Bill, for the fairness and good order of which he was
responsible, through the House of Commons. This glimpse into the operations of the Committee
enables us to picture the groups of comrades who sauntered down from Almack's of an afternoon to
carve up a manor in Committee of the House of Commons. We can see Bully's friends meeting
round the table in their solemn character of judges and legislator, to give a score of villages to Bully,
and a dozen to Stavordale, much as Artaxerxes gave Magnesia to Themistocles for his bread, Myus
for his meat and Lampsacus for his wine. And if those friends happened to be Bully's creditor as
well, it would perhaps not be unjust to suppose that their action was not altogether free from the kind
of gratitude that inspired the bounty of the great king.(54*)
NOTES:
1. E.g., Laxton enclosed on petition on Lord Carbery in 1772. Total area 1200 acres. Enclosure
proceedings completed in the Commons in nineteen days. Also Ashbury, Berks, enclosed on
petition of Lord Craven in 1770. There were contrary petitions. Also Nylands, enclosed in 1790 on
petition of the lady of the manor. Also Tilsworth, Beds, enclosed on petition of Charles Chester,
Esq., 1767, and Westcote, Bucks, on petition of the most noble George, Duke of Marlborough,
January 24, 1765. Sometimes the lord of the manor associated the vicar with his petition; thus
Waltham, Croxton and Braunston, covering 5600 acres, in Leicestershire, were all enclosed in 1766
by the Duke of Rutland and the local rector or vicar. The relations of Church and State are very
happily illustrated by the language of the petitions, 'A petition of the most noble John, Duke of
Rutland, and the humble petition' of the Rev. ----- Brown or Rastall or Martin.
2. This Standing Order does not seem to have been applied universally, for Mr Braggs on December
1, 1800, made a motion that it should be extended to the countries where it had not hitherto
obtained. See Senator, vol. xxvii, December 1, 1800.
3. See particulars in Appendix.
4. A Six Months' Tour through the North of England, 1771, vol. i, p. 122.
5. Pp. 21 f.
6. Cf. Otmoor in next chapter.
7. See Appendix.
8. See Appendix.
9. See House of Commons Journal.
10. Eden, The State of the Poor, vol. ii, p. 157.
11. Eden, writing a few years later, remarks that since the enclosure 'the property in Holy Island has
gotten into fewer hands,' vol. ii, p. 149.
12. Report of Select Committee on Most Effectual Means of Facilitating Enclosure, 1800.
13. Cf. also Wraisbury in Bucks, House of Commons Journal, June 17, 1799, where the petitioners
against the Bill claimed that they spoke on behalf of 'by much the greatest Part of the Proprietors of
the said Lands of Grounds.' yet in the enumeration of consents the committee state that the owners
of property assessed at £6, 18s. are hostile out of a total value of £295, 14s.
14. House of Commons Journal, March 21, 1796.
15. House of Commons Journal, June 10, 1801; cf. also case of Laleham. See Appendix.
16. Ibid., June 15, 1801.
17. Ibid., May 3, 1809.
18. Ibid., June 15, 1801.
19. See Appendix A (13).
20. A Political Enquiry into the Consequences of enclosing Waste Lands, 1785, p. 108.
21. See Appendix A (12).
22. House of Commons, May 1, 1845.
23. Aglionby, House of Commons, June 5, 1844.
24. Thurlow was Chancellor from 1778 to 1783 (when Fox contrived to get rid of him) and from 1783
to 1792.
25. Parliamentary Register, House of Lords, March 30, 1781.
26. Sir George Savile (1726-1784), M.P. for Yorkshire, 1759-1783; carried the Catholic Relief Bill,
which provoked the Gordon Riots, and presented the great Yorkshire Petition for Economical
Reform.
27. Annual Register, 1867, p. 68. For a detailed history of the Stanwell Enclosure, see Appendix A
(10). Unhappily the farmers were only reprieved; Stanwell was enclosed at the second attempt.
28. See Parliamentary Register, House of Lords, March 30, 1781; April 6, 1781; June 14, 1781.
29. John Warren (1730-1800).
30. Hohn Hinchcliffe (1731-1794), at one time Master of Trinity College, Cambridge.
31. Parliamentary Register, March 30, 1781.
32. Senator, vol. xxvi, July 2, 1800.
33. For both speeches see Parliamentary Register, May 24, 1802.
34. Ibid., June 14, 1781.
35. See Chesnut, Louth, Simpson and Stanwell in Appendix.
36. Six Months' Tour through the North of England, 1771, vol. i, p. 122.
37. See Annual Register, 1800, Appendix to Chronicle, p. 87.
38. Parliamentary Register, June 14, 1781.
39. Annals of Agriculture, vol. xxvi, p. 111.
40. February 1, 1793.
41. See Chapter iv.
42. Vol. xxvi, p. 70.
43. Sinclair's language shows that this was the general arrangement. Of course there are
exceptions. See e.g., Haute Huntre and other cases in Appendix.
44. Cf. Billingsley's Report on Somerset, p. 59, where the arrangements are described as 'a little
system of patronage. The lord of the soil, the rector, and a few of the principal commoners,
monopolize and distribute the appointments.'
45. Parliamentary Register, June 14, 1781.
46. General Report on Enclosures, 1808.
47. Six Months' Tour through the North of England, vol. i, p. 122.
48. See Appendix A (6).
49. Report on Somerset, p. 192.
50. Parliamentary Register, January 21, 1772.
51. Carlisle MSS.; Historical MSS. Commission, pp. 301ff.
52. Charles James Fox.
53. The earlier name of Brooks's Club.
54. For the subsequent history of King's Sedgmoor, see Appendix A (14).
Chapter 3
Enclosure (2)
In the year 1774, Lord North's Government, which had already received a bad bruise or two in the
course of its quarrels with printer and author, got very much the worst of it in an encounter that a
little prudence would have sufficed to avert altogether. The affair has become famous on account of
the actor, and because it was the turing point in a very important career. The cause of the quarrel
has passed into the background, but students of the enclosure movement will find more to interest
them in its beginning than in its circumstances and development.
Mr. De Grey, Member for Norfolk, and Lord of the Manor of Tollington in that county, had a dispute
of long standing with Mr. William Tooke of Purley, a landowner in Tollington, who had resisted Mr.
De Grey's encroachments on the common. An action on this subject was impending, but Mr. De
Grey, who held, as Sir George Trevelyan puts it, 'that the law's delay was not intended for Member
of Parliament' got another Member of Parliament to introduce a petition for a Bill for the enclosure of
Tollington. As it happened, Mr. Tooke was a friend of one of the clerks in the House of Commons,
and this friend told him on 6th January that a petition from De Grey was about to be presented. A
fortnight later Mr. Tooke received from this clerk a copy of Mr. De Grey's petition, in which the Lord
Chief Justice, brother of Mr. De Grey was included. Mr. Tooke hurried to London and prepared a
counter petition, and Sir Edward Astley, the member for the constituency, undertook to present that
petition together with the petition from Mr. De Grey. There were some further negotiations, with the
result that both sides revised their respective petitions, and it was arranged that they should be
presented on 4th February. On that day the Speaker said the House was not full enough, and the
petitions must be presented on the 7th. Accordingly Sir Edward Astley brought up both petitions on
the 7th, but the Speaker said it was very extraordinary to present two contrary petitions at the same
time. 'Bring the first petition first.' When members began to say 'Hear, hear,' the Speaker remarked,
'It is only a common petition for a common enclosure,' and the Members fell into general
conversation, paying no heed to the proceedings at the Table. In the midst of this the petition was
read, and the Speaker asked for 'Ayes and Noes,' and declared that the Ayes had it. The petition
asking for the Bill had thus been surreptitiously carried without the House being made aware that
there was a contrary petition to be presented, the contrary petition asking for delay. The second
petition was then read and ordered to lie on the Table.
In ordinary circumstances nothing more would have been heard of the opposition to Mr. De Grey's
Bill. Hundreds of petitions may have been so stifled without the world being any the wiser. But Mr.
Tooke, who would never have known of Mr. De Grey's intention if he had not had a friend among
the clerk of the House of Commons, happened to have another friend who was able to help him in a
very different way in his predicament. This was Horne, who was now living in a cottage at Purley,
reading law, on the desperate chance that a man, who was a clergyman against his will, would be
admitted to the bar. Rushed rather than spent by his public quarrel with Wilkes, which was just dying
down, Horne saw in Mr. Tooke's wrongs an admirable opportunity for a champion of freedom,
whose earlier exploits had been a little tarnished by his subsequent feuds with his comrades.
Accordingly he responded very promptly, and published in the Public Advertiser of 11th February,
an anonymous indictment of the Speaker, Sir Retcher Norton, based on his unjust treatment of
these petitions. This letter scandalised the House of Commons and drew the unwary Government
into a quarrel from which Horne emerged triumphant; for the Government, having been led on to
proceed against Horne, was unable to prove his authorship of the letter. The incident had
consequences of great importance for many persons. It was the making of Horne, for he became
Horne Tooke, with £8000 from his friend and a reputation as an intrepid and vigilant champion of
popular liberty that he retained to the day of his death. It was also the making of Fox, for it was this
youth of twenty-five who had led the Government into its scrape, and the king could not forgive him.
His temerity on this occasion provoked the famous letter from North. 'Sir, His Majesty has thought
proper to order a new Commission of the Treasury to be made out, in which I do not see your
name.' Fox left the court party to lend his impetuous courage henceforth to very different causes.
But for social students the incident is chiefly interesting because it was the cause of the introduction
of Standing Orders on Enclosure Bills. It had shown what might happen to rich men under the
existing system. Accordingly the House of Commons set to work to construct a series of Standing
Orders to regulate the proceedings on Enclosure Bills.
Most of these Standing Orders have ready been mentioned in the previous chapter, but we propose
to recapitulate their main provisions in order to show that the gross fairness of the procedure,
described in the last chapter, as between the rich and the poor, made no impression at all upon
Parliament. The first Standing Orders dealing with Enclosure Bills were passed in 1774, and they
were revised in 1775, 1781, 1799, 1800 and 1801. These Standing Orders prevented a secret
application to Parliament by obliging promoters to publish a notice on the church door; they
introduced some control over the extortions of commissioners, and laid down that the Bill presented
to Parliament should contain the names of the commissioners and a description of the
compensation to be given to the lord of the manor and the impropriator of tithes. But they contained
no safeguard at all against robbery of the small proprietors or the commoners. Until 1801 there was
no restriction on the choice of a commissioner, and it was only in that year that Parliament adopted
the Standing Order providing that no lord of the manor, or steward, or bailiff of any lord or lady or
proprietor should be allowed to act as commissioner in an enclosure in which he was an interested
party.(1*) In one respect Parliament deliberately withdrew a rule introduced to give greater regUlarity
and publicity to the proceedings of committees. Under the Standing Orders of 1774, the Chairman
of a Committee had to report not only whether the Standing Orders had been complied with, but
also what evidence had been submitted to show that all, the necessary formalities had been
observed; but in the following year the House of Commons struck out this second provision. A
Committee of the House of Commons suggested in 1799 that no petition should be admitted for a
Parliamentary Bill unless a fourth part of the proprietors in number and value signed the application,
but this suggestion was rejected.
The poor then found no kind of shelter in the Standing Orders. The legislation of this period, from
first to last, shows just as great an indifference to the injustice to which they were exposed. The first
public Act of the time deals not with enclosures for growing corn, but with enclosures for growing
wood. The Act of 1756 states in its preamble that the Acts of Henry VIII, Charles II and William III for
encouraging the growth of timber had been obstructed by the resistance of the commoners, and
Parliament therefore found it necessary to enact that any owner of waste could enclose for the
purpose of growing timber with the approval of the majority in number and value of those who had
common rights, and any majority of those who had common rights could enclose with the approval
of the owner of the waste. Any person or persons who thought themselves aggrieved could appeal
to Quarter Sessions, within six months after the agreement had been registered. We hear very little
of this Act, and the enclosures that concern us are enclosures of a different kind. In the final years of
the century there was a succession of General Enclosure Bills introduced and debated in
Parliament, under the stimulus of the fear of famine. These Bills were promoted by the Board of
Agriculture, established in 1793 with Sir John Sinclair as President, and Arthur Young as secretary.
This Board of Agriculture was not a State department in the modern sense, but a kind of Royal
Society receiving, not too regularly, a subsidy from Parliament.(2*) As a result of its efforts two
Parliamentary Committees were appointed to report on the enclosure of waste lands, and the
Reports of these Committees, which agreed in recommending a General Enclosure Bill, were
presented in 1795 and 1799. Bills were introduced in 1795, 1796, 1797 and 1800, but it was not until
1801 that any Act was passed.
The first Bills presented to Parliament were General Enclosure Bills, that is to say, they were Bills for
prescribing conditions on which enclosure could be carried out without application to Parliament.
The Board of Agriculture was set on this policy partly, as we have seen, in the interest of agricultural
expansion, partly as the only way of guaranteeing a supply of food during the French war. But these
were not the only considerations in the mind of Parliament, and we are able in this case to see what
happened to a disinterested propOsal when it had to pass through the sieve of a Parliament of
owners of land and tithes. For we have in the Annals of Agriculture(3*) the form of the General
Enclosure Bill of 1796 as it was presented to the Government by that expert body, the Board of
Agriculture, and we have among the Parliamentary Bills in the British Museum (1) the form in which
this Bill left a Select Committee, and (2) the form in which it left a second Select Committee of
Eights of the Shire and Gentlemen of the Long Robe. We are thus able to see in what spirit the lords
of the manor who sat in Parliament regarded, in a moment of great national urgency, the policy put
before it by the Board of Agriculture. We come at once upon a fact of great importance. In the first
version it is recognised that Parliament has to consider the future as well as the present, that it is
dealing not only with the claims of a certain number of living cottagers, whose rights and property
may be valued by the commissioners at a five pound note, but with the necessities of generations
still to be born, and that the most liberal recognition of the right to pasture a cow, in the form of a
cash payment to an individual, cannot compensate for the calamities that a society suffers in the
permanent alienation of all its soil. The Bill as drafted in the Board of Agriculture enacted that in
view of the probable increase of population, a portion of the waste should be set aside, and vested
in a corporate body (composed of the lord of the manor, the rector, the vicar, the churchwardens
and the overseers), for allotments for ever. Any labourer over twenty-one, with a settlement in the
parish, could claim a portion and hold it for fifty years, rent free, on condition of building a cottage
and fencing it. When the fifty years were over, the cottages, with their parcels of land, were to be let
on leases of twenty-one years and over at reasonable rents, half the rent to go to the owner of the
soil, and half to the poor rates. The land was never to be alienated from the cottage. All these far-
sighted clauses vanish absolutely under the sifting statesmanship of the Parliament, of which Burke
said in all sincerity, in his Reflections on the Revolution in France, that 'our representation has been
found perfectly adequate to all the purposes for which a representation of the people can be desired
or devised.'
There was another respect in which the Board of Agriculture was considered to be too generous to
the poor by the lords of the manor, who made the laws of England. In version 1 of the Bill, not only
those entitled to such right but, also those who have enjoyed or exercised the right of getting fuel
are to have special and inalienable fuel allotments made to them: in version 2 only those who are
entitled to such rights are to have a fuel allotment, and in version 3, this compensation is restricted
to those who have possessed fuel rights for ten years. Again in version 1, the cost of enclosing and
fencing small allotments, where the owners are unable to pay, is to be borne by the other owners: in
version 2, the small owners are to be allowed to mortgage their allotments in order to cover the cost.
The importance of the proposal thus rejected by the Parliamentary Committee will appear when we
come to consider the practical effects of Enclosure Acts. The only people who got their fencing done
for them under most Acts were the tithe-owners, a class neither so poor nor so powerless in
Parliament.
However this Bill shared the fate of all other General Enclosure Bills at this time. There were many
obstacles to a General Enclosure Bill. Certain Members of Parliament resisted them on the ground
that if it were made legal for a majority to coerce a minority into enclosure without coming to
Parliament, such protection as the smaller commoners derived from the possibility of Parliamentary
discussion would disappear. Powis quarrelled with the Bill of 1796 on this ground, and he was
supported by Fox and Grey, but his objections were overruled. However a more formidable
opposition came from other quarters. Enclosure Acts furnished Parliamentary officials with a harvest
of fees,(4*) and the Church thought it dangerous that enclosure, affecting tithe-owners, should be
carried through without the bishops being given an opportunity of interfering. These and other forces
were powerful enough to destroy this and all General Enclosure Bills, intended to make application
to Parliament unnecessary.
The Board of Agriculture accordingly changed its plans. In 1800 the Board abandoned its design of
a General Enclosure Bill, and presented instead a consolidating Bill, which was to cheapen
procedure. Hitherto there had been great diversities of form and every Bill was an expensive little
work of art of its own. The Act of 1801 was designed to save promoters of enclosure some of this
trouble and expense. It took some forty clauses that were commonly found in Enclosure Bills and
provided that they could be incorporated by reference in private Bills, thus cheapening legal
procedure. Further, it allowed affidavits to be accepted as evidence, thus relieving the promoters
from the obligation of bringing witnesses before the Committee to swear to every signature. All the
recognition that was given to the difficulties and the claims of the poor was comprised in sections 12
and 13, which allow small allotments to be laid together and depastured in common, and instruct the
commissioners to have particular regard to the convenience of the owners or proprietors of the
smallest estates. In 1813, the idea of a General Bill was revived once more, and a Bill passed the
House of Commons which gave a majority of three-fifths in value the right to petition quarter
Sessions for an enclosure. The Bill was rejected in the Lords. In 1836 a General Enclosure Bill was
passed, permitting enclosure when two-thirds in number and value desired it, and in 1845
Parliament appointed central Commissioners with a view to preventing local injustice.
It is fortunate that the Parliamentary Reports of the debates on General Enclosure Bills in the
unreformed Parliament are almost as meagre as the debates on particular Enclosure Bills. We can
gather from various indications that the rights of the clergy received a good deal of notice, and Lord
Grenville made an indignant speech to vindicate his zeal in the cause of the Church, which had
been questioned by opponents. The cause of the poor does not often ruffle the surface of
discussion. This we can collect not only from negative evidence but also from a statement by Mr.
Lechmere, Member for Worcester. Lechmere, whose loss of his seat in 1790 deprived the poor of
one of their very few champions in Parliament, drew attention more than once during the
discussions on scarcity and the high price of corn to the lamentable consequences of the
disappearances of the small farms, and recommended drastic steps to arrest the process. Philip
Francis gave him some support. The general temper of Parliament can be divined from his
complaint that when these subjects were under discussion it was very difficult to make a House.
It must not be supposed that the apathy of the aristocracy was part of a universal blindness or
anaesthesia, and that the method and procedure of enclosure were accepted as just and inevitable,
without challenge or protest from any quarter. The poor were of course bitterly hostile. This appears
not only from the petitions presented to Parliament, but from the echoes that have reached us of
actual violence. It was naturally easier for the threatened commoners to riot in places where a single
enclosure scheme affected a wide district, and most of the records of popular disturbances that
have come down to us are connected with attempts to enclose moors that were common to several
parishes. An interesting example is afforded by the history of the enclosure of Haute Huntre Fen in
Lincolnshire. This enclosure, which affected eleven parishes, was sanctioned by Parliament in 1767,
but three years later the Enclosure Commissioners had to come to Parliament to explain that the
posts and rails that they had set up had been destroyed 'by malicious persons, in order to hinder the
execution of the said Act,' and to ask for permission to make ditches instead of fences.(5*) An
example of disturbances in a single village is given by the Bedfordshire reporter for the Board of
Agriculture, who says that when Maulden was enclosed it was found necessary to send for troops
from Coventry to quell the riots:(6*) and another in the Annual Register for 1799(7*) describing the
resistance of the commoners at Wilbarston in Northamptonshire, and the employment of two troops
of yeomanry to coerce them. The general hatred of the poor for enclosures is evident from the
language of Eden, and from statements of contributors to the Annals of Agriculture. Eden had
included a question about commons and enclosures in the questions he put to his correspondents,
and he says in his preface that he had been disappointed that so few of his correspondents had
given an answer to this question. He then proceeds to give this explanation: 'This question, like
most others, that can now be touched upon, has its popular and its unpopular sides: and where no
immediate self-interest, or other partial leaning, interferes to bias the judgment, a good-natured man
cannot but wish to think with the multitudes; stunned as his ears must daily be, with the oft-repeated
assertion, that, to condemn commons, is to determine on depopulating the country'(8*) The writer of
the Bedfordshire Report in 1808 says that 'it appears that the poor have invariably been inimical to
enclosures, as they certainly remain to the present day.'(9*) Dr. Wilkinson, writing in the Annals of
Agriculture(10*) in favour of a General Enclosure Bill says, 'the grand objection to the inclosure of
commons arises from the unpopularity which gentlemen who are active in the cause expose
themselves to in their own neighbourhood, from the discontent of the poor when any such question
is agitated.' Arthur Young makes a similar statement.(11*) 'A general inclosure has been long ago
proposed to administration, but particular ones have been so unpopular in some cases that
government were afraid of the measure.'
The popular feeling, though quite unrepresented in Parliament, was not unrepresented in
contemporary literature. During the last years of the eighteenth century there was a sharp war of
pamphlets on the merits of enclosure, and it is noticeable that both supporters and opponents
denounced the methods on which the governing class acted. There is, among others, a very
interesting anonymous pamphlet, published in 1781 under the title of An Inquiry into the Advantages
and disadvantages resulting from Bills of Inclosure, in which the existing practice is renewed and
some excellent suggestions are made for reform. The writer proposed that the preliminary to a Bill
should be not the fixing of a notice to the church door, but the holding of a public meeting, that there
should be six commissioners, that they should be elected by the commoners by ballot, that no
decision should be valid that was not unanimous, and that an appeal from that decision should lie
not to Quarter Sessions, but to Judges of Assize. The same writer proposed that no enclosure
should be sanctioned which did not allot one acre to each cottage.
These proposals came from an opponent of enclosure, but the most distinguished supporters of
enclosure were also discontented with the procedure. Who are the writers on eighteenth-century
agriculture whose names and publications are known and remembered? They are, first of all, Arthur
Young (l741-1820), who, though he failed as a merchant and failed as a farmer, and never ceased
to regret his father's mistake in neglecting to put him into the soft lap of a living in the Church, made
for himself, by the simple process of observing and recording, a European reputation as an expert
adviser in the art which he had practised with so little success. A scarcely less important authority
was William Marshall (1745-1818), who began by trading in the West Indies, afterwards farmed in
Surrey, and then became agent in Norfolk to Sir Harbord Harbord. It was Marshall who suggested
the creation of a Board of Rural Affairs, and the preparation of Surveys and Minutes. Though he
never held an official position, it was from his own choice, for he preferred to publish his own
Minutes and Surveys rather than to write them for the Board. He was interested in philology as well
as in agriculture; he published a vocabulary of the Yorkshire dialect and he was a friend of Johnson,
whom he rather scandalised by condoning Sunday labour in agriculture under special
circumstances. Nathaniel Kent (1737-1810) studied husbandry in the Austrian Netherlands, where
he had been secretary to an ambassador, and on his return to England in 1766 he was employed as
an estate agent and land valuer. He wrote a well-known book Hints to Gentlemen of Landed
Property, and he had considerable influence in improving the management of various estates.
He was, for a short time, bailiff of George III's farm at Windsor. All of these writers, though they are
very far from taking the view which found expression in the riots in the Lincolnshire fens, or in the
anonymous pamphlet already mentioned, addressed some very important criticisms and
recommendations to the class that was inclosing the English commons. Both Marshall and Young
complained of the injustice of the method of choosing commissioners. Marshall, ardent champion of
enclosure as he was, and no sentimentalist on the subject of the commoners, wrote a most bitter
account of the motives of the enclosers. 'At this juncture, it is true, the owners of manors and tithes,
whether clergy or laity, men of ministry or men of opposition, are equally on the alert: not however
pressing forward with offerings and sacrifices to relieve the present distresses of the country, but
searching for vantage ground to aid them in the scramble.'(12*) Holding this view, he was not
unnaturally ill-content with the plan of letting the big landlords nominate the commissioners, and
proposed that the lord of the soil and the owner or owners of tithes should choose one
commissioner each, that the owner or owners of pasturage should choose two, and that the four
should choose a fifth. Arthur Young proposed that the small proprietors should have a share in the
nomination of commissioners either by a union of votes or otherwise, as might be determined.
The general engrossing of farms was arraigned by Thomas Stone, the author of an important
pamphlet, Suggestions for rendering the inclosure of common fields and waste lands a source of
population and of riches, 1787, who proposed that in future enclosures farms should be let out in
different sites from £40 to £200 a year. He thought further that Parliament should consider the
advisability of forbidding the alienation of cottagers' property, in order to stop the frittering away of
cottagers' estates which was general under enclosure. Kent, a passionate enthusiast for enclosing,
was not less critical of the practice of throwing farms together, a practice which had raised the price
of provisions to the labourer, and he appealed to landlords to aid the distressed poor by reducing
the site of their farms, as well as by raising wages. Arbuthnot, the author of a pamphlet on An
Inquiry into the Connection between the present Price of Provisions and the Size of Farms, by a
Farmer, 1773, who had defended the large-farm system against Dr. Price, wrote, 'My plan is to allot
to each cottage three or four acres which should be annexed to it without power or alienation and
without rent while under the covenant of being kept in grass.'
So much for writers on agriculture. But the eighteenth century produced two authoritative writers on
social conditions. Any student of social history who wishes to understand this period would first turn
to the three great volumes of Eden's State of the Poor, published in 1797, as a storehouse of cold
facts. Davies, who wrote The Case of Labourers in Husbandry, published in 1795, is less famous
than he deserves to be, if we are to judge from the fact that the Dictionary of National Biography
only knows about him that he was Rector of Barkham in Berkshire, and a graduate of Jesus
College, Oxford, that he received a D.D. degree in 1800, that he is the author of this book, and that
he died, perhaps, in the year 1809. But Davies' book, which contains the result of most careful and
patient investigation, made a profound impression on contemporary observers. Howlett called it
'incomparable,' and it is impossible for the modern reader to resist its atmosphere of reality and
truth. This country parson gives us a simple, faithful and sincere picture of the facts, seen without
illusion or prejudice, and free from all the conventional affectations of the time: a priceless legacy to
those who are impatient of the generalisations with which the rich dismiss the poor. Now both of
these writers warned their contemporaries of the danger of the uncontrolled tendencies of the age.
Eden proposed that in every enclosure a certain quantity of land should be reserved for cottagers
and labourers, to be vested in the whole district. He spoke in favour of the crofters in Scotland, and
declared that provision of this kind was made for the labouring classes in the first settled townships
of New England. Davies was still more emphatic in calling upon England to settle cottagers and to
arrest the process of engrossing farms.(13*)
Thus of all the remembered writers of the period who had any practical knowledge of agriculture or
of the poor, there is not one who did not try to teach the governing class the need for reform, and the
dangers of the state into which they were allowing rural society to drift. Parliament was assailed on
all sides with criticisms and recommendations, and its refusal to alter its ways was deliberate.
Of the protests of the time the most important and significant came from Arthur Young. No man had
been so impatient of objections to enclosure: no man had taken so severe and disciplinary a view of
the labourer: no man had dismissed so lightly the appeals for the preservation of the fragmentary
possessions of the poor. He had taught a very simple philosophy, that the more the landowner
pressed the farmer, and the more the farmer pressed the labourer, the better it was for agriculture.
He had believed as implicitly as Sinclair himself, and with apparently as little effort to master the
facts, that the cottagers were certain to benefit by enclosure. All this gives pathos, as well as force,
to his remarkable paper, published under the title An Inquiry into the Propriety of applying Wastes to
the better Maintenance and Support of the Poor.
The origin of this document is interesting. It was written in 1801, a few years after the
Speenhamland system had begun to fix itself on the villages. The growth of the poor rates was
troubling the minds of the upper and middle classes. Arthur Young, in the course of his travels at
this time, stumbled on the discovery that in those parishes where the cottagers had been able to
keep together a tiny patch of property, they had shown a Spartan determination to refuse the refuge
of the Poor Law. When once he had observed this, he made further investigations which only
confirmed his first impressions. This opened his eyes to the consequences of enclosure as it had
been carried out, and he began to examine the history of these operations in a new spirit. He then
found that enclosure had destroyed with the property of the poor one of the great incentives to
industry and self-respect, and that his view that the benefit of the commons to the poor was
'perfectly contemptible,' and 'when it tempts them to become owners of cattle or sheep usually
ruinous,'(14*) was fundamentally wrong. Before the enclosures, the despised commons had
enabled the cottager to keep a cow, and this, so far from bringing ruin, had meant in very many
cases all the difference between independence and pauperism. His scrutiny of the Acts convinced
him that in respect of this they had been unjust. 'By nineteen out of twenty Inclosure Bills the poor
are injured, and some grossly injured.... Mr. Forster of Norwich, after giving me an account of twenty
inclosures in which he had acted as Commissioner, stated his opinion on their general effect on the
poor, and lamented that he had been accessory to the injuring of 2000 poor people, at the rate of
twenty families per parish.... The poor in these parishes may say, and with truth, "Parliament may be
tender of property: all I know is that I had a cow and an Act of Parliament has taken it from me."'
This paper appeared on the eve of the Enclosure Act of 1801, the Act to facilitate and cheapen
procedure, which Young and Sinclair had worked hard to secure. It was therefore an opportune
moment for trying to temper enclosure to the difficulties of the poor. Arthur Young made a
passionate appeal to the upper classes to remember these difficulties. 'To pass Acts beneficial to
every other class in the State and hurtful to the lowest class only, when the smallest alteration would
prevent it, is a conduct against which reason, justice and humanity equally plead.' He then
proceeded to outline a constructive scheme. He proposed that twenty millions should be spent in
setting up half a million families with allotments and cottages: the fee-simple of the cottage and land
to be vested in the parish, and possession granted under an Act of Parliament, on condition that if
the father or his family became chargeable to the rates, the cottage and land should revert to the
parish. The parishes were to carry out the scheme, borrowing the necessary money on the security
of the rates.(15*) 'A man,' he told the landlords, in a passage touched perhaps with remorse as well
as with compassion, 'will love his country the better even for a pig.' 'At a moment,' so he concludes,
'when a General Inclosure of Wastes is before Parliament, to allow such a measure to be carried
into execution in conformity with the practice hitherto, without entering one voice, however feeble, in
defence of the interests of the poor, would have been a wound to the feelings of any man not lost to
humanity who had viewed the scenes which I have visited.'
The appeal broke against a dense mass of class prejudice, and so far as any effect on the
Consolidating Act of 1801 is concerned, Arthur Young might never have written a line. This is
perhaps not surprising, for we know from Young's autobiography (p. 350) that he did not even carry
the Board of Agriculture with him, and that Lord Carrington, who was then President, only allowed
him to print his appeal on the understanding that it was not published as an official document, and
that the Board was in no way identified with it. Sinclair, who shared Young's conversion, had ceased
to be President in 1798. The compunction he tried to awaken did affect an Act here and there. A
witness before the Allotments Committee of 1843 described the arrangements he contrived to
introduce into an Enclosure Act. The witness was Mr. Demainbray, an admirable and most public-
spirited parson, Rector of Broad Somerford in Wiltshire. Mr. Demainbray explained that when the
Enclosure Act for his parish was prepared in 1806, he had been pressed to accept land in lieu of
tithes, and that he took the opportunity to stipulate for some provision for the poor. As a
consequence of his efforts, half an acre was attached to each cottage on the waste, the land being
vested in the rector, churchwardens and overseers for the time being, and eight acres were
reserved for the villagers for allotment and reallotment every Easter. This arrangement, which had
excellent results, 'every man looking forward to becoming a man of property,' was copied in several
of the neighbouring parishes. Dr. Slater has collected some other examples. One Act, passed in
1824 for Pottern in Wiltshire, vested the ownership of the enclosed common in the Bishop of
Salisbury, who was lord of the manor, the vicar, and the churchwardens, in trust for the parish. The
trustees were required to lease it in small holdings to poor, honest and industrious persons, who had
not, except in cases of accident or sickness, availed themselves of Poor Law Relief.(16*) Thomas
Stone's proposal for making inalienable allotments to cottagers was adopted in two or three Acts in
the eastern counties, but the Acts that made some provision for the poor do not amount, in Dr.
Slater's opinion, to more than one per cent of the Enclosure Acts passed before 1845,(17*) and this
view is corroborated by the great stress laid in the Reports of the Society for Bettering the Condition
of the Poor, upon a few cases where the poor were considered, and by a statement made by Mr.
Demainbray in a pamphlet published in 1831.(18*) In this pamphlet Mr. Demainbray quotes what
Davies had said nearly forty years earlier about the effect of enclosures in robbing the poor, and
then adds: 'Since that time many hundred enclosures have taken place, but in how few of them has
any reserve been made for the privileges which the poor man and his ancestors had for centuries
enjoyed?'
Some interesting provisions are contained in certain of the Acts of the period. At Stanwell the
commissioners were to set aside such parcel as they thought proper not exceeding thirty acres, to
be let out and the rents and profits were to be given for the benefit of such occupiers and inhabitants
as did not receive parochial relief or occupy lands and tenements of more than £5 a year, and had
not received any allotment under the Act. Middleton, the writer of the Report on Middlesex, says that
the land produced £30 a year,(19*) and he remark that this is a much better way of helping the poor
than leaving them land for their use. We may doubt whether the arrangement seemed equally
attractive to the poor. It could not have been much compensation to John Carter, who owned a
cottage, to receive three roods, twenty-six perches in lieu of his rights of common, which is his
allotment in the award, for three-quarters of an acre is obviously insufficient for the pasture of a cow,
but it was perhaps still less satisfactory for James Carter to know that one acre and seven perches
were allotted to the 'lawful owner or owners' of the cottage and land which he occupied, and that his
own compensation for the loss of his cow or sheep or geese was the cold hope that if he kept off the
rates, Sir William Gibbons, the vicar, and the parish officers might give him a dole. The Laleham
Commissioners were evidently men of a rather grim humour, for, in setting aside thirteen acres for
the poor, they authorised the churchwardens and overseers to encourage the poor, if they were so
minded, by letting this plot for sixty years and using the money so received to build a workhouse. A
much more liberal provision was made at Cheshunt, where the poor were allowed 100 acres. At
Knaresborough and Louth, the poor got nothing at all.
Before we proceed to describe the results of enclosure on village life, we may remark one curious
fact. In 1795 and 1796 there was some discussion in the House of Commons of the condition of the
agricultural labourers, arising out of the proposal of Whitbread's to enable the magistrates to fix a
minium wage. Pitt made a long speech in reply, and promised to introduce a scheme of his own for
correcting evils that were too conspiCuous to be ignored. This promise he kept next year in the ill-
fated Poor Law Bill, which died, almost at its birth, of general hostility. That Bill will be considered
elsewhere. All that we are concerned to notice here is that neither speech nor Bill, though they cover
a wide range of topics, and though Pitt said that they represented the results of long and careful
inquiry, hint at this cause of social disturbance, or at the importance of safe-guarding the interests of
the poor in future enclosure schemes: this in spite of the fact that, as we have seen, there was
scarcely any contemporary writer or observer who had not pointed out that the way in which the
governing class was conducting these revolutions was not only unjust to the poor but perilous to the
State.
It is interesting, in the light of the failure to grasp and retrieve an error in national policy which mark
the progress of these transactions, to glance at the contemporary history of France. The Legislative
Assembly, under the influence of the ideas of the economists, decreed the division of the land of the
communes in 1792. The following year this decree was modified. Certain provincial assemblies had
asked for division, but many of the villages were inexorably hostile. The new decree of June 1793
tried to do justice to these conflicting wishes by making division optional. At the same time it insisted
on an equitable division in cases where partition took place. But this policy of division was found to
have done such damage to the interests of the poor that there was strenuous opposition, with the
result that in 1796 the process was suspended, and in the following year it was forbidden.(20*) Can
any one suppose that if the English legislature had had as swift and ready a sense for things going
wrong, the policy of enclosure would have been pursued after 1801 with the same reckless
disregard for its social consequences?
We have given in the last chapter the history of an enclosure project for the light it throws on the
play of motive in the enclosing class. We propose now to give in some detail the history of an
enclosure project that succeeded for the light it throws on the attention which Parliament paid to
local opinion and on the generally received views as to the rights of the small commoners. Our
readers will observe that this enclosure took place after the criticisms and appeals which we have
described had all been published.
Otmoor is described in Dunkin's History of Oxfordshire,(21*) as a 'dreary and extensive common.'
Tradition said that the tract of land was the gift of some mysterious lady 'who gave as much ground
as she could ride round while an oat-sheaf was burning, to the inhabitants of its vicinity for a public
common,' and hence came its name of Oatmoor, corrupted into Otmoor. Whatever the real origin of
the name, which more prosaic persons connected with 'Oc,' a Celtic word for 'water,' this tract of
land had been used as a 'public common without stint... from remote antiquity.' Lord Abingdon,
indeed, as Lord of the Manor of Beckley, claimed and exercised the right of appointing a moor-
driver, who at certain seasons drove all the cattle into Beckley, where those which were unidentified
became Lord Abingdon's property. Lord Abingdon also claimed rights of soil and of sport: these, like
his other claim, were founded on prescription only, as there was no trace of any grant from the
Crown.
The use to which Otmoor, in its original state, was put, is thus described by Dunkin. 'Whilst this
extensive piece of land remained unenclosed, the farmers of the several adjoining townships
estimated the profits of a summer's pasturage at 20s. per head, subject to the occasional loss of a
beast by a peculiar distemper called the moor-evil. But the greatest benefit was reaped by the
cottagers, many of whom turned out large numbers of geese, to which the coarse aquatic sward
was well suited, and thereby brought up their families in comparative plenty.(22*)
'Of late years, however, this dreary waste was surveyed with longing eyes by the surrounding
landowners, most of whom wished to annex a portion of it to their estates, and in consequence
spared no pains to recommend the enclosure as a measure beneficial to the country.'
The promoters of the enclosure credited themselves with far loftier motives: prominent among them
being a desire to improve the morals of the poor. An advocate of the enclosure afterwards described
the pitiable state of the poor in pre-enclosure days in these words: 'In looking after a brood of
goslings, a few rotten sheep, a skeleton of a cow or a mangy horse, they lost more than they might
have gained by their day's work, and acquired habits of idleness and dissipation and a dislike to
honest labour, which has rendered them the riotous and lawless set of men which they have now
shown themselves to be.' A pious wish to second the intention of Providence was also a strong
incentive: 'God did not create the earth to lie waste for feeding a few geese, but to be cultivated by
man, in the sweat of his brow.'(23*)
The first proposal for enclosure came to Parliament from George, Duke of Marlborough, and others
on 11th March, 1801. The duke petitioned for the drainage and the allotment of the 4000 acres of
Otmoor among the parishes concerned, namely Beckley (with Horton and Studley), Noke,
Oddington, and Charlton (with Fencott and Moorcott). This petition was referred to a Committee, to
consider amongst other things, whether the Standing Orders with reference to drainage Bills had
been duly complied with. The Committee reported in favour of allowing the introduction of the Bill,
but made this remarkable admission, that though the Standing Orders with respect to the affixing of
notices on church doors had been complied with on Sunday, 3rd August, 'it appeared to the
Committee that on the following Sunday, the 10th of August, the Person employed to affix the like
Notices was prevented from so doing at Beckley, Oddington and Charlton, by a Mob at each Place,
but that he read the Notices to the Persons assembled, and afterwards threw them amongst them
into the Church Yards of those Parishes.' Notice was duly affixed that Sunday at Noke. The next
Sunday matters were even worse, for no notices were allowed to be fixed in any parish.
The Bill that was introduced in spite of this local protest, was shipwrecked during its Committee
stage by a petition from Alexander Croke, LL.D., Lord of the Manor of Studley with Whitecross
Green, and from John Mackaness, Esq., who stated that as proprietors in the parish of Beckley,
their interests had not been sufficiently considered.
The next application to Parliament was not made till 1814. In the interval various plans were
propounded, and Arthur Young, in his Survey of Oxfordshire for the Board of Agriculture, published
in 1809 (a work which Dunkin describes as supported by the farmers and their landlords and as
having caught their strain), lamented the wretched state of the land. 'I made various inquiries into
the present value of it by rights of commonage; but could ascertain no more than the general fact, of
its being to a very beggarly amount.... Upon the whole, the present produce must be quite
contemptible, when compared with the benefit which would result from enclosing it. And I cannot but
remark, that such a tract of waste land in summer, and covered the winter through with water, to
remain in such a state, within five miles of Oxford and the Thames, in a kingdom that regularly
imports to the amount of a million sterling in corn, and is almost periodically visited with
apprehensions of want -- is a scandal to the national policy.... If drained and enclosed, it is said that
no difficulty would occur in letting it at 30s. per acre, and some assert even 40s.' (p. 228).
When the new application was made in November 1814, it was again referred to a Committee, who
again had to report turbulent behaviour in the district concerned. Notices had been fixed on all the
church doors on 7th August, and on three doors on 14th August, 'but it was found impracticable to
affix the Notices on the Church doors of the other two Parishes on that day, owing to large Mobs,
armed with every description of offensive weapons, having assembled for the prose of obstructing
the persons who went to affix the Notices, and who were prevented by violence, and threats of
immediate death, from approaching the Churches.'(24*) From the same cause no notices could be
affixed on these two church doors on 21st or 28th August.
These local disturbances were not allowed to check the career of the Bill. It was read a first time on
21st February, and a second time on 7th March. But meanwhile some serious flaws had been
discovered. The Duke of Marlborough and the Earl of Abingdon both petitioned against it. The
Committee, however, were able to introduce amendments that satisfied both these powerful
personages, and on 1st May Mr. Fane reported from the Committee that no persons had appeared
for the said petitions, and that the parties concerned had consented to the satisfaction of the
Committee, and had also consented 'to the changing the Commissioners therein named.' Before the
Report had been passed, however, a petition was received on behalf of Alexander Croke,(25*) Esq.,
who was now in Nova Scotia, which made further amendments necessary, and the Committee was
empowered to send for persons, papers and records. Meanwhile the humbler individuals whose
future was imperilled were also bestirring themselves. They applied to the Keeper of the Records in
the Augmentation Office for a report on the history of Otmoor. This Report, which is published at
length by Dunkin,(26*) states that in spite of laborious research no mention of Otmoor could be
found in any single record from the time of William the Conqueror to the present day. Even
Doomsday Book contained no reference to it. Nowhere did it appear in what manor Otmoor was
comprehended, nor was there any record that any of the lords of neighbouring manors had ever
been made capable of enjoying any rights of common upon it. The custom of usage without stint, in
fact, pointed to some grant before the memory of man, and made it unlikely that any lord of the
manor had ever had absolute right of soil. Armed, no doubt, with this learned report, some
'Freeholders, Landholders, Cottagers and Persons' residing in four parishes sent up a petition
asking to be heard against the Bill. But they were too late: their petition was ordered to lie on the
Table, and the Bill passed the Commons the same day (26th June) and received the Royal Assent
on 12th July.
The Act directed that one-sixteenth of the whole (which was stated to be over 4000 acres) should be
given to the Lord of the Manor of Beckley, Lord Abingdon, in compensation of his rights of soil, and
one-eighth as composition for all tithes. Thus Lord Abingdon received, to start with, about 750 acres.
The residue was to be allotted among the various parishes, townships and hamlets, each allotment
to be held as a common pasture for the township. So far, beyond the fact that Lord Abingdon had
taken off more than a sixth part of their common pasture, and that the pasture was now divided up
into different parts, it did not seem that the ordinary inhabitants were much affected. The sting lay in
the arrangements for the future of these divided common pastures. 'And if at any future time the
major part in value of the several persons interested in such plot or parcels of land, should require a
separate division of the said land, he (the commissioner) is directed to divide and allot the same
among the several proprietors, in proportion to their individual rights and interests therein.'(27*)
We have, fortunately, a very clear statement of the way in which the 'rights and interests' of the
poorer inhabitants of the Otmoor towns were regarded in the enclosure. These inhabitants, it must
be remembered, had enjoyed rights of common without any stint from time immemorial, simply by
virtue of living in the district. In a letter from 'An Otmoor Proprietor' to the Oxford papers in 1830, the
writer (Sir Alexander Croke himself?), who was evidently a man of some local importance, explains
that by the general rule of law a commoner is not entitled to turn on to the common more cattle than
are sufficient to manure and stock the land to which the right of common is annexed. Accordingly,
houses without land attached to them cannot, strictly speaking, claim a right of common. How then
explain the state of affairs at Otmoor, where all the inhabitants, landed or landless, enjoyed the
same rights? By prescription, he answers, mere houses do in point of fact sometimes acquire a right
of common, but this right, though it may be said to be without stint, is in reality always liable to be
stinted by law. Hence, when a common like Otmoor is enclosed, the allotments are made as
elsewhere in proportion to the amount of land possessed by each commoner, whist a
'proportionable share' is thrown in to those who own mere houses. But even this share, he points
out, does not necessarily belong to the person who has been exercising the right of common, unless
he happens to own his own house. It belongs to his landlord, who alone is entitled to compensation.
A superficial observer might perhaps think this a hardship, but in point of fact it is quite just. The
tenants, occupying the houses, must have been paying a higher rent in consideration of the right
attached to the houses, and they have always been liable to be turned out by the landlord at will.
'They had no permanent interest, and it has been decided by the law that no man can have any right
in any common, as belonging to a house, wherein he has no interest but only habitation: so that the
poor, as such, had no right to the common whatever.'(28*)
The results of the Act, framed and administered on these lines, were described by Dunkin,(29*)
writing in 1823, as follows: 'It now only remains to notice the effect of the operation of this act. On
the division of the land allotted to the respective townships, a certain portion was assigned to each
cottager in lieu of his accustomed commonage, but the delivery of the allotment did not take place,
unless the party to whom it was assigned paid his share of the expenses incurred in draining and
dividing the waste: and he was also further directed to enclose the same with a fence. The poverty
of the cottager in general prevented his compliance with these conditions, and he was necessitated
to sell his share for any paltry sum that was offered. In the spring of 1819, several persons at
Charlton and elsewhere made profitable speculations by purchasing these commons for £5 each,
and afterwards prevailing on the commissioners to throw them into one lot; thus forming a valuable
estate. In this way was Otmoor lost to the poor man, and awarded to the rich, under the specious
idea of benefitting the public.' The expenses of the Act, it may be mentioned, came to something
between £20,000 and £30,000, or more than the fee-simple of the soil.(30*)
'Enclosed Otmoor did not fulfil Arthur Young's hopes:... instead of the expected improvement in the
quality of the soil, it has been rendered almost totally worthless; a great proportion being at this
moment over-rated at 5s. an acre yearly rent, few crops yielding any more than barely sufficient to
pay for labour and seed.'(31*) This excess of expenses over profits was adduced by the 'Otmoor
proprietor,' to whom we have already referred, as an frustration of the public-spirited self-sacrifice of
the enclosers, who were paying out of their own pockets for a national benefit, and by making some,
at any rate, of the land capable of cultivation, were enabling the poor to have 'an honest
employment, instead of losing their time in idleness and waste.'(32*) But fifteen years of this 'honest
employment' failed to reconcile the poor to their new position, and in 1830 they were able to express
their feelings in a striking manner.(33*)
In the course of his drainage operations, the commissioner had made a new channel for the river
Ray, at a higher level, with the disastrous result that the Ray overflowed into a valuable tract of low
land above Otmoor. For two years the farmers of this tract suffered severe losses (one farmer was
said to have lost £400 in that time), then they took the law into their own hands, and in June 1829
cut the embankments, so that the waters of the Ray again flowed over Otmoor and left their valuable
land unharmed. Twenty-two farmers were indicted for felony for this act, but they were acquitted at
the Assizes, under the direction of Mr. Justice Parke, on the grounds that the farmers had a right to
abate the nuisance, and that the commissioner had exceeded his powers in making this new
channel and embankment.
This judgment produced a profound impression on the Otmoor farmers and cottagers. They misread
it to mean that all proceedings under the Enclosure Act were illegal and therefore null and void, and
they determined to regain their lost privileges. Disturbances began at the end of August (28th
August). For about a week, straggling parties of enthusiasts paraded the moor, cutting down fences
here and there. A son of Sir Alexander Croke came out to one of these parties and ordered them to
desist. He had a loaded pistol with him, and the moor-men, thinking, rightly or wrongly, that he was
going to fire, wrested it from him and gave him a severe thrashing. Matters began to look serious:
local sympathy with the rioters was so strong that special constables refused to be sworn in; the
High Sheriff accordingly summoned the Oxfordshire Militia, and Lord Churchill's troop of Yeomanry
Cavalry was sent to Islip. But the inhabitants were not overawed. They determined to perambulate
the bounds of Otmoor in full force, in accordance with the old custom. On Monday, 6th September,
five hundred men, women and children assembled from the Otmoor towns, and they were joined by
five hundred more from elsewhere. Armed with reap-hook, hatchets, bill-hooks and duckets, they
marched in order round the seven-mile-long boundary of Otmoor, destroying all the fences on their
way. By noon their work of destruction was finished. 'A farmer in the neighbourhood who witnessed
the scene gives a ludicrous description of the zeal and perseverance of the women and children as
well as the men, and the ease and composure with which they waded through depths of mud and
water and overcame every obstacle in their march. He adds that he did not hear any threatening
expressions against any person or his property, and he does not believe any individuals present
entertained any feeling or wish beyond the assertion of what they conceived (whether correctly or
erroneously) to be their prescriptive and inalienable right, and of which they speak precisely as the
freemen of Oxford would describe their right to Port Meadow.'(34*)
By the time the destruction of fences was complete, Lord Churchill's troop of yeomanry came up to
the destroying band: the Riot Act was read, but the moormen refused to disperse. Sixty or seventy
of them were thereupon seized and examined, with the result that forty-four were sent off to Oxford
Gaol in wagons, under an escort of yeomanry. Now it happened to be the day of St. Giles' Fair, and
the street of St. Giles, along which the yeomanry brought their prisoners, was crowded with
countryfolk and townsfolk, most of whom held strong views on the Otmoor question. The men in the
wagons raised the cry 'Otmoor for ever,' the crowd took it up, and attacked the yeomen with great
violence, hurling brickbats, stones and stick at them from every side. The yeomen managed to get
their prisoners as far as the turning down Beaumont Street, but there they were overpowered, and
all forty-four prisoners escaped. At Otmoor itself peace now reigned. Through the broken fences
cattle were turned in to graze on all the enclosures, and the villagers even appointed a herdsman to
look after them. The inhabitants of the seven Otmoor towns formed an association called 'the
Otmoor Association,' which boldly declared that 'the Right of Common on Otmoor was always in the
inhabitants, and that a non-resident proprietor had no Right of Common thereon,' and determined to
raise subscriptions for legal expenses in defence of their right, calling upon 'the pecuniary aid of a
liberal and benevolent public... to assist them in attempting to restore Otmoor once more to its
original state.'(35*)
Meanwhile the authorities who had lost their prisoners once, sent down a stronger force to take
them next time, and although at the Oxford City Sessions a bill of indictment against William Price
and others for riot in St. Giles and rescue of the prisoners was thrown out, at the County Sessions
the Grand Jury found a true Bill against the same William Price and others for the same offence,
and also against Cooper and others for riot at Otmoor. The prisoners were tried at the Oxford
Assizes next month, before Mr. Justice Bosanquet and Sir John Patteson. The jury returned a
verdict which shows the strength of public opinion. 'We find the defendants guilty of having been
present at an unlawful assembly on the 6th September at Otmoor, but it is the unanimous wish of
the Jury to recommend all the parties to the merciful consideration of the Court.' The judges
responded to this appeal and the longest sentence inflicted was for months' imprisonment.(36*)
The original enclosure was now fifteen years old, but Otmoor was still in rebellion, and the Home
Office Papers of the next two years contain frequent applications for troops from Lord Macclesfield,
Lord-Lieutenant, Sir Alexander Croke and other magistrates. Whenever there was a full moon, the
patriots of the moor turned out and pulled down the fences. How strong was the local resentment of
the overriding of all the rights and traditions of the commoners may be seen not only from the
language of one magistrate writing to Lord Melbourne in January 1832: 'all the towns in the
neighborhood of Otmoor are more or less infected with the feelings of the most violent, and cannot
at all be depended on:' but also from a resolution passed by the magistrates at Oxford in February
of that year, declaring that no constabulary force that the magistrates could raise would be equal to
suppressing the Otmoor outrages, and asking for soldiers. The appeal ended with this significant
warning: 'Any force which Government may send down should not remain for a length of time
together, but that to avoid the possibility of an undue connexion between the people and the Military,
a succession of troops should be observed.' So long and so bitter was the civil war roused by an
enclosure which Parliament had sanctioned in absolute disregard of the opinions or the traditions or
the circumstances of the mass of the people it affected.
NOTES:
1. Most private Enclosure Acts provided that if a commissioner died his successor was to be
somebody not interested in the property.
2. Sir John Sinclair complained in 1796, that the Board had not even the privilege of franking its
letters. -- Annals of Agriculture, vol. xxvi, pp. 506.
3. Vol. xxvi, p. 85.
4. From the Select Committee on the Means of Facilitating Enclosures in 1800, reprinted in Annual
Register, 1800, Appendix to Chronicle, p. 85 ff., we learn that the fees received alone in the House
of Commons (Bill fees, small fees, committee fees, housekeepers' and messengers' fees, and
engrossing fees) for 707 Bills during the fourteen years from 1786 to 1799 inclusive amounted to no
less that £59,867, 6s. 4d. As the scale of fees in the House of Lords was about the same (Bill fees,
yeoman, usher, door-keepers' fees, order of committee, and committee fees) during these years
about £120,000 must have gone into the pockets of Parliamentary officials.
5. See Appendix A (5).
6. Bedford Report, 1808, p. 235.
7. Annual Register, 1799, Chron. p. 27.
8. Eden, I, Preface, p. xviii.
9. Bedford Report, p. 249. Cf. writer in Appendix of Report on Middlesex, pp. 507-15, 'a gentleman
of the least sensibility would rather suffer his residence to continue surrounded by marshes and
bogs, than take the lead in what may be deemed an obnoxious measure.' This same writer urges,
that the unpopularity of enclosures would be overcome were care taken 'to place the inferior orders
of mankind -- the cottager and industrious poor -- in such a situation, with regard to inclosures, that
they should certainly have some share secured to them, and he treated with a gentle hand. Keep all
in temper -- let no rights be now disputed... It is far more easy to prevent a clamour than to stop it
when once it is raised. Those who are acquainted with the business of inclosure must know that
there are more than four-fifths of the inhabitants in most neighbourhoods who are generally left out
of the bill for want for property, and therefore cannot possibly claim any part thereof.'
10. Vol. xx, p. 456.
11. Vol. xxiv, p. 543.
12. The Appropriation and Enclosure of Commonable and Intermixed Lands, 1801.
13. 'Allow to the cottager a little land about his dwelling for keeping a cow, for planting potatoes, for
raising flax or hemp. 2ndly. Convert the waste lands of the kingdom into small arable farms, a
certain quantity every year, to be let on favourble terms to industrious families. 3rdly, Restrain the
engrossment and over-enlargement of farms. The propriety of those measures cannot, I think, he
questioned.' -- The Case of Labourers in Husbandry, p. 103.
14. Annals of Agriculture, vol. i, p. 52.
15. This scheme marks a great advance on an earlier scheme which Young published in the first
volume of the Annals of Agriculture. He then proposed that public money should be spent in settling
cottagers or soldiers on the waste, giving them their holding free of rent and tithes for three lives, at
the end of which time the land they had redeemed was to revert to its original owners.
16. Slater, pp. 126-7.
17. Ibid., p. 128.
18. The Poor Man's Best Friend, or Land to cultivate for his own Benefit. Letter to the Marquis of
Salisbury, by the Rev. S. Demainbary, B.D., 1831.
19. p. 126.
20. See for this subject Cambridge Modern History, vol. viii, chap. 24, and P. Sagnac, La Législation
Civils de la Révolution Française.
21. Vol. i, p. 119 ff.
22. Jackson's Oxford Journal, September 11, 1830, said that a single cottager sometimes cleared
as much as £20 a year by geese.
23. Oxford University and City Herald, September 25, 1830.
24. House of Commons Journal, February 17, 1815.
25. Alexander Croke (1758-1842), knighted in 1816, was from 1801-1815 judge in the Vice-
Admiralty Court, Nova Scotia. As a lawyer, he could defend his own interest.
26. Dunkin's Oxfordshire, vol. i, pp. 122-3.
27. Ibid., p. 123.
28. Jackson's Oxford Journal, September 18, 1830.
29. Vol. i, p. 124.
30. Jackson's Oxford Journal, September 11, 1830.
31. Ibid.,
32. Ibid., September 18.
33. See Jackson's Oxford Journal, and Oxford University and City Herald, for September 11, 1830,
and also Annual Register, 1830, Chron. p. 142, and Home Office Papers, for what follows.
34. Oxford University and City Herald, September 11, 1830.
35. Ibid.
36. Jackson's Oxford Journal, March 5, 1831.
Chapter Four
The Village After Enclosure
The governing class continued its policy of extinguishing the old village life and all the relationships
and interests attached to it, with unsparing and unhesitating hand; and as its policy progressed there
were displayed all the consequences predicted by its critics. Agriculture was revolutionised: rents
leapt up: England seemed to be triumphing over the difficulties of a war with half the world. But it
had one great permanent result which the rulers of England ignored. The anchorage of the poor was
gone.
For enclosure was fatal to three classes: the small farmer, the cottager, and the squatter. To all of
these classes their common rights were worth more than anything they received in return. Their
position was just the opposite of that of the lord of the manor. The lord of the manor was given a
certain quantity of land (the conventional proportion was one-sixteenth(1*)) in lieu of his surface
rights, and that compact allotment was infinitely more valuable than the rights so compensated.
Similarly the tithe-owner stood to gain with the increased rent. The large farmer's interests were also
in enclosure, which gave him a wider field for his capital and enterprise. The other classes stood to
lose.
For even if the small farmer received strict justice in the division of the common fields, his share in
the legal costs and the additional expense of fencing his own allotments often overwhelmed him,
and he was obliged to sell his property.(2*) The expenses were always very heavy, and in some
cases amounted to £5 an acre.(3*) The lord of the manor and the tithe-owner could afford to bear
their share, because they were enriched by enclosure: the classes that were impoverished by
enclosure were ruined when they had to pay for the very proceeding that had made them the poorer.
The promoter of the General Enclosure Bill of 1796, it will be remembered, had proposed to exempt
the poor from the expense of fencing, but the Select Committee disapproved, and the only persons
exempted in the eases we have examined were the lords of the manor or tithe-owners.
If these expenses still left the small farmer on his feet, he found himself deprived of the use of the
fallow and stubble pasture, which had been almost as indispensable to him as the land he
cultivated. 'Strip the small farms of the benefit of the commons,' said one observer, 'and they are all
at one stroke levelled to the ground.'(4*) It was a common clause in Enclosure Acts that no sheep
were to be depastured on allotments for seven years.(5*) The small farmer either emigrated to
America or to an industrial town, or became a day labourer. His fate in the last resort may perhaps
be frustrated by the account given by the historian of Oxfordshire of the enclosure of Merton. 'About
the middle of last century a very considerable alteration was produced in the relative situation of
different classes in the village. The Act of Parliament for the inclosure of the fields having annulled
all leases, and the inclosure itself facilitated the plan of throwing several small farms into a few large
bargains,(6*) the holders of the farms who had heretofore lived in comparative plenty, became
suddenly reduced to the situation of labourers, and in a few years were necessitated to throw
themselves and their families upon the parish. The overgrown farmers who had fattened upon this
alteration, feeling the pressure of the new burden, determined if possible to free themselves: they
accordingly decided upon reducing the allowance of these poor to the lowest ratio,(7*) and resolved
to have no more servants so that their parishioners might experience no further increase from that
source. In a few years the numbers of the poor rapidly declined: the more aged sank into their
graves, and the youth, warned by their parents' sufferings, sought a settlement elsewhere. The
farmers, rejoicing in the success of their scheme, procured the demolition of the cottages, and thus
endeavoured to secure themselves and their successors from the future expenses of supporting an
increased population, so that in 1821 the parish numbered only thirty houses inhabited by thirty-four
families.'(8*) Another writer gave an account of the results of a Norfolk enclosure. 'In passing
through a village near Swaffham, in the County of Norfolk a few years ago, to my great mortification
I beheld the houses tumbling into ruins, and the common fields all enclosed; upon enquiring into the
cause of this melancholy alteration, I was informed that a gentleman of Lynn had bought that
township and the next adjoining to it: that he had thrown the one into three, and the other into four
farms; which before the enclosure were in about twenty farms: and upon my further enquiring what
was becoming of the farmers who were turned out, the answer was that some of them were dead
and the rest were become labourers.'(9*)
The effect on the cottager can best be described by saying that before enclosure the cottager was a
labourer with land, after enclosure he was a labourer without land. The economic basis of his
independence was destroyed. in the first place, he lost a great many rights for which he received no
compensation. There were, for instance, the cases mentioned by Mr. Henry Homer (1719-1791),
Rector of Birdingbury and Chaplain to Lord Leigh, in the pamphlet he published in 1769,(10*) where
the cottagers lost the privileges of cutting furze and turf on the common land, the proprietor
contending that they had no right to these privileges, but only enjoyed them by his indulgence. In
every other case, Mr. Homer urged, uninterrupted, immemorial usage gives a legal sanction even to
encroachments. 'Why should the poor, as poor, be excluded from the benefit of this general
indulgence; or why should any set of proprietors avail themselves of the inability of the poor to
contend with them, to get possession of more than they enjoyed?'(11*)
Another right that was often lost was the prescriptive right of keeping a cow. The General Report on
Enclosures (p. 12) records the results of a careful inquiry made in a journey of 1600 miles, which
showed that before enclosure cottagers often kept cows without a legal right, and that nothing was
given them for the practice. Other cottagers kept cows by right of hiring their cottages and common
rights, and on enclosure the land was thrown into a farm, and the cottager had to sell his cow. Two
examples taken from the Bedfordshire Report illustrate the consequences of enclosure to the small
man. One is from Maulden:(12*) 'The common was very extensive. I conversed with a farmer, and
several cottagers. One of them said, enclosing would ruin England; it was worse than ten wars.
Why, my friend, what have you lost by it? I kept four cows before the parish was enclosed, and now
I don't keep so much as a goose; and you ask me what I lose by it!'(13*) The other is from Sandy;
(14*) 'This parish was very peculiarly circumstanced; it abounds with gardeners, many cultivating
their little freeholds, so that on the enclosure, there were found to be sixty-three proprietors, though
nine-tenths, perhaps, of the whole belonged to Sir P. Monoux and Mr. Pym. These men kept cows
on the boggy common, and cut fern for litter on the warren, by which means they were enabled to
raise manure for their gardens, besides fuel in plenty; the small allotment of an acre and a half,
however good the land, has been no compensation for what they were deprived of. They complain
heavily, and know not how they will now manage to raise manure. This was no reason to preserve
the deserts in their old state, but an ample one for giving a full compensation.'
Lord Winchilsea stated in his letter to the Board of Agriculture in 1796: 'Whoever travels through the
Midland Counties and will take the trouble of inquiring, will generally receive for answer that formerly
there were a great many cottagers who kept cows, but that the land is now thrown to the farmers,
and if he inquires still further, he will find that in those parishes the Poor Rates have increased in an
amazing degree more than according to the average rise throughout England.'
These cottagers often received nothing at all for the right they had lost, the compensation going to
the owner of the cottage only. But even those cottagers who owned their cottage received in
return.for their common right something infinitely less valuable. For a tiny allotment was worth much
less than a common right, especially if the allotment was at a distance from their cottage, and
though the Haute Huntre Act binds the commissioners to give Lord FitzWilliam an allotment near his
gardens, there was nothing in any Act that we have seen to oblige the commissioners to give the
cottager an allotment at his door. And the cottagers had to fence their allotments or forfeit them.
Anybody who glances at an award will understand what this meant. it is easy, for example, to
imagine what happened under this provision to the following cottagers at Stanwell: Edmund Jordan
(1 1/2 acres) J. and F. Ride (each 1 1/4 acres) T. L. Rogers (1 1/4 acres) Brooker Derby (1 1/4)
Mary Gulliver (1 1/4 acres) Anne Higgs (1 1/4) H. Isherwood (1 1/4) William Kent (1 1/4) Elizabeth
Carr (1 acre) Thomas Nash (1 acre) R. Ride (just under 1 acre) William Robinson (just under 1 acre)
William Cox (3/4 acre) John Carter (3/4 acre) William Porter (3/4 acre) Thomas King (1/2 acre) John
Hetherington (under 1/2 an acre) J. Trout (1/4 acre and 4 perches) and Charles Burkhead (12
perches). It would be interesting to know how many of these small parcels of land found their way
into the hands of Sir william Gibbons and Mr. Edmund Hill.
The Louth award is still more interesting from this point of view. J. Trout and Charles Burkhead
passing rich, the one on 1/4 acre and 4 perches, the other on 12 perches, had only to pay their
share of the expenses of the enclosure, and for their own fencing. Sir William Gibbons was too
magnanimous a man to ask them to fence his 500 acres as well. But at Louth the tithe-owners, who
took more than a third of the whole, were excused their share of the costs, and also had their
fencing done for them by the other proprietors. The prebendary and the vicar charged the expenses
of fencing their 600 acres on persons like Elizabeth Bryan who went off with 39 perches, Ann dunn
(35 perches), Naomi Hodgson, widow (35 perches), John Betts (34 perches), Elizabeth Atkins (32
perches), Will Boswell (31 perches), Elizabeth Eycon (28 perches), Ann Hubbard, widow (15
perches), and Ann Metcalf, whose share of the spoil was 14 perches. The award shows that there
were 67 persons who received an acre or less. Cottagers who received such allotments and had to
fence them had no alternative but to sell, and little to do with the money but to drink it. This is the
testimony of the General Report on Enclosures.(15*)
The squatters, though they are often spoken of as cottagers, must be distinguished from the
cottager in regard to their legal and historical position. They were in a sense outside the original
village economy. The cottager was, so to speak, an aboriginal poor man: the squatter a poor alien.
He settled on a waste, built a cottage, and got together a few geese or sheep, perhaps even a horse
or a cow, and proceeded to cultivate the ground.
The treatment of encroachments seems to have varied very greatly, as the cases analysed in the
Appendix show, and there was no settled rule. Squatters of less than twenty years' standing seldom
received any consideration beyond the privilege of buying their encroachment. Squatters of more
than twenty or forty years' standing, as the case might be, were often allowed to keep their
encroachments, and in some cases were treated like cottagers, with a claim to an allotment. But, of
course, like the cottagers, they lost their common rights.
Lastly, enclosure swept away the bureaucracy of the old village: the viewers of fields and letters of
the cattle, who had general supervision of the arrangements for pasturing sheep or cows in the
common meadow, the common shepherd, the chimney peepers who saw that the chimneys were
kept properly, the hayward, or pinder, who looked after the pound. Most of these little officials of the
village court had been paid either in land or by fees. When it was proposed to abolish Parliamentary
Enclosure, and to substitute a General Enclosure Bill, the Parliamentary officials, who made large
sums out of fees from Enclosure Bills, were to receive compensation; but there was no talk of
compensation for the stolen livelihood of a pinder or a chimney peeper, as there had been for the
lost pickings of the officials of Parliament, or as there was whenever an unhappy aristocrat was
made to surrender one of his sinecures. George Selwyn, who had been Paymaster of the Works for
twenty-seven years at the time that Burke's Act of 1782 deprived him of that profitable title, was not
allowed to languish very long on the two sinecures that were left to him. In 1784 Pitt consoled him
with the lucrative name of Surveyor-General of Crown Lands. The pinder and the viewer received a
different kind of justice. For the rich there is compensation, as the weaver said in Disraeli's Sybil, but
'sympathy is the solace of the poor.' In this case, if the truth be told, even this solace was not
administered with too liberal a hand.
All these classes and interests were scattered by enclosure, but it was not one generation alone that
was struck down by the blow. For the commons were the patrimony of the poor. The commoner's
child, however needy, was born with a spoon in his mouth. He came into a world in which he had a
share and a place. The civilisation which was now submerged had spelt a sort of independence for
the obscure lineage of the village. It had represented, too, the importance of the interest of the
community in its soil, and in this aspect also the robbery of the present was less important than the
robbery of the future. For one act of confiscation blotted out a principle of permanent value to the
State.
The immediate consequences of this policy were only partially visible to the governing or the
cultivated classes. The rulers of England took it for granted that the losses of individuals were the
gains of the State, and that the distresses of the poor were the condition of permanent advance.
Modern apologists have adopted the same view; and the popular resistance to enclosure is often
compared to the wild and passionate fury that broke against the spinning and weaving machines,
the symbols and engines of the Industrial Revolution. History has drawn a curtain over those days of
exile and suffering, when cottages were pulled down as if by an invader's hand, and families that
had lived for centuries in their dales or on their small farms and commons were driven before the
torrent, losing
<poem>
'Estate and house and all their sheep,
A pretty flock, and which for aught I know
Had clothed the Ewbanks for a thousand years.'
</poem>
Ancient possessions and ancient families disappeared. But the first consequence was not the worst
consequence: so far from compensating for this misery, the ultimate result was still more disastrous.
The governing class killed by this policy the spirit of a race. The petitions that are buried with their
brief and unavailing pathos in the Journals of the House of Commons are the last voice of village
independence, and the unnamed commoners who braved the dangers of resistance to send their
doomed protests to the House of Commons that obeyed their lords, were the last of the English
peasants. These were the men, it is not unreasonable to believe, whom Gray had in mind when he
wrote: --
<poem>
'Some village Hampden that with dauntless breast
The little tyrant of his fields withstood,'
</poem>
As we read the descriptions of the state of France before the Revolution, there is one fact that
comforts the imagination and braces the heart. We read of the intolerable services of the peasant, of
his forced labour, his confiscated harvests, his crushing burdens, his painful and humiliating tasks,
including in some cases even the duty of protecting the sleep of the seigneur from the croaking of
the neighboring marshes. The mind of Arthur Young was filled with this impression of unsupportable
servitude. But a more discerning eye might have perceived a truth that escaped the English
traveller. It is contained in an entry that often greets us in the official reports on the state of the
provinces: ce seigneur litige avec ses vaissaux. Those few words flash like a gleam of the dawn
across this sombre and melancholy page. The peasant may be overwhelmed by the dîme, the taille,
the corvée, the hundred and one services that knit his tenure to the caprice of a lord: he may be
wretched, brutal, ignorant, ill-clothed, ill-fed, and ill-housed: but he has not lost his status: he is not a
casual figure in a drifting proletariat: he belongs to a community that can withstand the seigneur,
dispute his claims at law, resume its rights, recover its possessions, and establish, one day, its
independence.
In England the aristocracy destroyed the promise of such a development when it broke the back of
the peasant community. The enclosures created a new organisation of classes. The peasant with
rights and a status, with a share in the fortunes and government of his village, standing in rags, but
standing on his feet, makes way for the labourer with no corporate rights to defend, no corporate
power to invoke, no property to cherish, no ambition to pursue, bent beneath the fear of his masters,
and the weight of a future without hope. No class in the world has so beaten and crouching a
history, and if the blazing ricks in 1830 once threatened his rulers with the anguish of his despair, in
no chapter of that history could it have been written, 'This parish is at law with its squire.' For the
parish was no longer the community that offered the labourer friendship and sheltered his freedom:
it was merely the shadow of his poverty, his helplessness, and his shame. 'Go to an ale-house
kitchen of an old enclosed country, and there you will see the origin of poverty and Poor-rates. For
whom are they to be sober? For whom are they to save? For the parish? If I am diligent, shall I have
leave to build a cottage? If I am sober, shall I have land for a cow? If I am frugal, shall I have half an
acre of potatoes? You offer no motives; you have nothing but a parish officer and a workhouse! --
Bring me another pot --.'(16*)
NOTES:
1. See the Evidence of Witnesses before the Committee on Commons Inclosure of 1844. (Baily,
land-agent): 'General custom to give the Lord of Manor 1/16th as compensation for his rights
exclusive of the value of minerals and of his rights as a common right owner.' Another witness
(Coulson, a solicitor) defined the surface rights as 'game and stockage,' and said that the proportion
determined upon the result of a bargain beforehand.
2. 'Many small proprietors have been seriously injured by being obliged in pursuance of ill-framed
private bills to enclosure lands which newer repaid the expense.' Marshall, The Appropriation and
Enclosures of Commonable and Intermixed Lands, 1801, p. 52.
3. Cost of Enclosure -- The expenses of particular Acts varied very much. Billingsley in his Report
on Somerset (p. 57) gives £3 an acre as the cost of enclosing a lowland parish, £2, 10s. for an
upland parish. The enclosure of the 12,000 acre King's Sedgmoor (Ibid., p. 196) came (with the
subdivisions) to no less than £59,624, 4s. 8d., or nearly £5 an acre. Stanwell Enclosure, on the
other hand, came to about 23s. an acre, and various instance given in the Report for Bedfordshire
work out at about the same figure. When the allotments to the tithe-owners and the lord of the
manor were exempted, the sum per acre would of course fall more heavily on the other allottees,
e.g., of Louth, where more than a third of the 1701 acres enclosed were exempt. In many cases, of
course, land was sold to cover expenses. The cost of fencing allotments would also vary in different
localities. In Somerset, from 7s. 7d. to 8s. 7d. for 20 feet of quickset hedge was calculated, in
Bedfordshire, 10s. 6d. per pole. See also for expense Hasbach, pp. 64, 65, and General Report on
Enclosures, Appendix, xvii. Main Items: --
1. Country solictor's fees for drawing up Bill and attending in town;
2. Attendance of witnesses at House of Commons and House of Lords to prove that Standing
Orders had been complied with;
3. Expenses of persons to get signatures of consents and afterwards to attend to get consent of
principal proprietors);
4. Expense of Parliamentary solicitor, 20 gs., but more if opposition;
5. Expense of counsel if there was opposition;
6. Parliament fees, see p. 76.
4. Inquiry into the Advantages and Disadvantages resulting from Bills of Enclosure, 1789, p. 14.
5. Cf. Ashelworth, Cheshunt, Knaresborough.
6. Previous to enclosure there were twenty-five farmers; the land is now divided among five or six
persons only.
7. It was then confidently said that several poor persons actually perished from want, and so great
was the outcry that some of the farmers were hissed in the public market at Bicester.
8. Dunkin's Oxfordshire, pp. 2 and 3.
9. F. Moore, Considerations on the Exorbitant Price of Proprietors, 1773, p. 22; quoted by Levy, p.
27.
10. Essay on the Nature and Method of ascertaining the specific Share of Proprietors upon the
Inclosure of Common fields, with observations on the inconveniences of common fields, etc., p. 22.
11. The Kirton, Sutterton and Wigtoft (Lincs) Acts prescribed a penalty for taking turf or sod after the
passing of the Act, of £10, and in default of payment imprisonment in the House of Correction with
hard labour for three months.
12. p. 235.
13. The only provision for the poor in the Maulden Act, (36 Geo. III, c. 65) was a fuel allotment as a
compensation for the ancient usage of cutting peat or moor turf. The trustees (rector, churchwarden
and overseers) were to distribute the turf to poor families, and were to pay any surplus from the rent
of the herbage to the poor rates.
14. p. 240.
15. At St. Neots a gentleman complained to Arthur Young in 1791 that in the enclosure which took
place sixteen years before, 'the poor were ill-treated by having about half a rood given them in lieu
of a cow keep, the inclosure of which land costing more than they could afford, they sold the lots at
£5, the money was drank out at the ale-house, and the men, spoiled by the habit, came, with their
families to the parish.' -- Annuals of Agriculture, vol xvi. p. 482.
16. Annals of Agriculture, vol. xxxvi. p. 508.
Chapter Five
The Labourer in 1795
In an unenclosed village, as we have seen, the normal labourer did not depend on his wages alone.
His livelihood was made up from various sources. His firing he took from the waste, he had a cow or
a pig wandering on the common pasture, perhaps he raised a little crop on a strip in the common
fields. He was not merely a wage earner, receiving so much money a week or a day for his labour,
and buying all the necessaries of life at a shop: he received wages as a labourer, but in part he
maintained himself as a producer. Further, the actual money revenue of the family was not limited to
the labourer's earnings, for the domestic industries that flourished in the village gave employment to
his wife and children.
In an enclosed village at the end of the eighteenth century the position of the agricultural labourer
was very different. All his auxiliary resources had been taken from him, and he was now a wage
earner and nothing more. Enclosure had robbed him of the strip that he tilled, of the cow that he
kept on the village pasture, of the fuel that he picked up in the woods, and of the turf that he tore
from the common. And while a social revolution had swept away his possessions, an industrial
revolution had swept away his family's earnings. To families living on the scale of the village poor,
each of these losses was a crippling blow, and the total effect of the changes was to destroy their
economic independence.
Some of these auxiliary resources were not valued very highly by the upper classes, and many
champions of enclosure proved to their own satisfaction that the advantage, for example, of the right
of cutting fuel was quite illusory. Such writers had a very superficial knowledge of the lot of the
cottagers. They argued that it would be more economical for the labourer to spend on his ordinary
employment the time he devoted to cutting fuel and turf, and to buy firing out of his wages: an
argument from the theory of the division of labour that assumed that employment was constant.
Fortunately we have, thanks to Davies, a very careful calculation that enables us to form rather a
closer judgment. He estimates(1*) that a man could cut nearly enough in a week to serve his family
all the year, and as the farmers will give the carriage of it in return for the ashes, he puts the total
cost at 10s. a year, or a little more than a week's wages.(2*) If we compare this with his accounts of
the cost of fuel elsewhere, we soon see how essential common fuel rights were to a labourer's
economy. As Sidlesham in Surrey, for instance,(3*) in the expenses of five families of labourers, the
fuel varies from £1, 15s. 0d. up to £4, 3s. 0d., with an average of £2, 8s. 0d. per family. It must be
remembered, too, that the sum of 10s. for fuel from the common is calculated on the assumption
that the man would otherwise be working; whereas, in reality, he could cut his turf in slack times and
in odd hours, when there was no money to be made by working for some one else.
There was another respect in which the resources of a labouring family were diminished towards the
end of the century, and this too was a loss that the rich thought trifling. From time immemorial the
labourer had sent his wife and children into the fields to glean or leaze after the harvest. The profits
of gleaning, under the old, unimproved system of agriculture, were very considerable. Eden says of
Rode in Northamptonshire, where agriculture was in a 'wretched state, from the land being in
common-fields,' that 'several families will gather as much wheat as will serve them for bread the
whole year, and as many beans as will keep a pig.'(4*) From this point of view enclosure, with its
improved methods of agriculture, meant a sensible loss to the poor of the parish, but even when
there was less to be gleaned the privilege was by no means unimportant. A correspondent in the
Annals of Agriculture,(5*) writing evidently of land under improved cultivation in Shropshire,
estimates that a wife can glean three or four bushels. The consumption of wheat, exclusive of other
food, by a labourer's family he puts at half a bushel a week at least; the price of wheat at 13s. 6d. a
bushel; the labourer's wages at 7s. or 8s. To such a family gleaning rights represented the
equivalent of some six or seven weeks' wages.
With the introduction of large farming these customary rights were in danger. It was a nuisance for
the farmer to have his fenced fields suddenly invaded by bands of women and children. The ears to
be picked up were now few and far between, and there was a risk that the labourers, husbands and
fathers of the gleaners, might wink at small thefts from the sheaves. Thus it was that customary
rights, which had never been questioned before, and seemed to go back to the Bible itself, came to
be the subject of dispute. On the whole question of gleaning there is an animated controversy in the
Annals of Agriculture(6*) between Capel Lofft,(7*) a romantic Suffolk Liberal, who took the side of
the gleaners, and Ruggles,(8*) the historian, who argued against them. Capel Lofft was a humane
and chivalrous magistrate who, unfortunately for the Suffolk poor, was struck off the Commission of
the Peace a few years later, apparently at the instance of the Duke of Portland, for persuading the
Deputy-Sheriff to postpone the execution of a girl sentenced to death for stealing, until he had
presented a memorial to the Crown praying for clemency. The chief arguments on the side of the
gleaners were (1) that immemorial custom gave legal right, according to the maxim, consuetudo
angliae lex est angliae communis; (2) that Blackstone had recognised the right in his
Commentaries, basing his opinion upon Hale and Gilbert, 'Also it hath been said, that by the
common law and custom of England the poor are allowed to enter and glean on another's ground
after harvest without being guilty of trespass, which humane provision seems borrowed from the
Mosaic law, (iii. 212, 1st edition); (3) that in Ireland the right was recognised by statutes of Henry
VIII's reign, which modified it; (4) that it was a custom that helped to keep the poor free from
degrading dependence on poor relief. It was argued, on the other hand, by those who denied the
right to glean, that though the custom had existed from time immemorial, it did not rest on any basis
of actual right, and that no legal sanction to it had ever been explicitly given, Blackstone and the
authorities on whom he relied being too vague to be considered final. Further, the custom was
demoralising to the poor; it led to idleness, 'how many days during the harvest are lost by the mother
of a family and all her children, in wandering about from field to field, to glean what does not repay
them the wear of their cloathes in seeking;' it led to pilfering from the temptation to take handfuls
from the swarth or shock; and it was deplorable that on a good-humoured permission should be
grafted 'a legal claim, in its use and exercise so nearly approaching to licentiousness.'
Whilst this controversy was going on, the legal question was decided against the poor by a majority
of judges in the Court of Common Pleas in 1788. One judge, Sir Henry Gould,(9*) dissented in a
learned judgment; the majority based their decision partly on the mischievous consequences of the
practice to the poor. The poor never lost a right without being congratulated by the rich on gaining
something better. It did not, of course, follow from this decision that the practice necessary ceased
altogether, but from that time it was a privilege given by the farmer at his own discretion, and he
could warn off obnoxious or 'saucy' persons from his fields. Moreover, the dearer the corn, and the
more important the privilege for the poor, the more the farmer was disinclined to largess the
precious ears. Capel Lofft had pleaded that with improved agriculture the gleaners could pick up so
little that that little should not be grudged, but the farmer found that under famine prices this little
was worth more to him than the careless scatterings of earlier times.(10*)
The loss of his cow and his produce and his common and traditional rights was rendered particularly
serious to the labourer by the general growth of prices. For enclosure which had produced the
agrarian proletariat, had raised the cost of living for him. The accepted opinion that under enclosure
England became immensely more productive tends to obscure the truth that the agricultural
labourer suffered in his character of consumer, as well as in his character of producer, when the
small farms and the commons disappeared. Not only had he to buy the food that formerly he had
produced himself, but he had to buy it in a rising market. Adam Smith admitted that the rise of price
of poultry and pork had been accelerated by enclosure, and Nathaniel Kent laid stress on the
diminution in the supply of these and other small provisions. Kent has described the change in the
position of the labourers in this respect: 'Formerly they could buy milk, butter, and many other small
articles in every parish, in whatever quantity they are wanted. But since small farms have decreased
in number, no such articles are to be had; for the great farmers have no idea of retailing such small
commodities, and those who do retail them carry them all to town. A farmer is even unwilling to sell
the labourer who works for him a bushel of wheat, which he might get ground for three or four pence
a bushel. For want of this advantage he is driven to the mealman or baker, who, in the ordinary
course of their profit, get at least ten per cent. of them, upon this principal article of their
consumption.'(11*) Davies, the author of The Case of Labourers in Husbandry, thus describes the
new method of distribution. 'The great farmer deals in a wholesale way with the miller: the miller with
the mealman: the mealman with the shopkeeper, of which last the poor man buys his flour by the
bushel. For neither the miller nor the mealman will sell the labourer a less quantity than a sack of
flour, under the retail price of shops, and the poor man's pocket will seldom allow of his buying a
whole sack at once.'(12*)
It is clear from these facts that it would have needed a very large increase of wages to compensate
the labourer for his losses under enclosure. But real wages, instead of rising, had fallen, and fallen
far. The writer of the Bedfordshire Report (p. 67), comparing the period of 1730-50 with that of 1802-
6 in respect of prices of wheat and labour, points out that to enable him to purchase equal quantities
of bread in the second period and in the first, the pay of the day labourer in the second period
should have been 2s. a day, whereas it was 1s. 6d. Nathaniel Kent, writing in 1796,(13*) says that in
the last forty or fifty years the price of provisions had gone up by 60 per cent, and wages by 25 per
cent, 'but this is not all, for the sources of the market which used to feed him are in a great measure
cut off since the system of large farms has been so much encouraged.' Professor Levy estimates
that wages rose between 1760 and 1813 by 60 per cent, and the price of wheat by 130 per cent.
(14*) Thus the labourer who now lived on wages alone earned wages of a lower purchasing power
than the wages which he had formerly supplemented by his own produce. Whereas his condition
earlier in the century had been contrasted with that of Continental peasants greatly to his advantage
in respect of quantity and variety of food, he was suddenly brought down to the barest necessities of
life. Arthur Young had said a generation earlier that in France bread formed nineteen parts in twenty
of the food of the people, but that in England all ranks consumed an immense quantity of meat,
butter and cheese.(15*) We know something of the manner of life of the poor in 1789 and 1795 from
the family budgets collected by Eden and Davies from different parts of the country.(16*) These
budgets show that the labourers were rapidly sinking in this respect to the condition that Young had
described as the condition of the poor in France. 'Bacon and other kinds of meat form a very small
part of their diet, and cheese becomes a luxury.' But even on the meagre food that now became the
ordinary fare of the cottage, the labourers could not make ends meet. All the budgets tell the same
tale of impoverished diet accompanied by an overwhelming strain and an actual deficit. The normal
labourer, even with constant employment, was no longer solvent.
If we wish to understand fully the predicament of the labourer, we must remember that he was not
free to roam over England, and try his luck in some strange village or town when his circumstances
became desperate at home. He lived under the capricious tyranny of the old law of settlement, and
enclosure had made that net a much more serious fact for the poor. The destruction of the
commons had deprived him of any career within his own village; the Settlement Laws barred his
escape out of it. It is worth while to consider what the Settlement Laws were, and how they acted,
and as the subject is not uncontroversial it will be necessary to discuss it in some detail.
Theoretically every person had one parish, and one only, in which he or she had a settlement and a
right to parish relief. In practice it was often difficult to decide which parish had the duty of relief, and
disputes gave rise to endless litigation. From this point of view eighteenth-century England was like
a chessboard of parishes, on which the poor were moved about like pawns. The foundation of the
various laws on the subject was an Act passed in Charles II's reign (13 and 14 Charles II. c. 12) in
1662. Before this Act each parish had, it is true, the duty of relieving its own impotent poor and of
policing its own vagrants, and the infirm and aged were enjoined by law to betake themselves to
their place of settlement, which might be their birthplace, or the place where they had lived for three
years, but, as a rule, 'a poor family might, without the fear of being sent back by the parish officers,
go where they choose, for better wages, or more certain employment.'(17*) This Act of 1662
abridged their liberty, and, in place of the old vagueness, established a new and elaborate system.
The Act was declared to be necessary in the preamble, because 'by reason of some defects in the
law, poor people are not restrained from going from one parish to another, and therefore do
endeavour to settle themselves in those parishes where there is the best stock, the largest
commons or wastes to build cottages, and the most woods for them to burn and destroy; and when
they have consumed it, then to another parish; and at last become rogues and vagabonds; to the
great discouragement of parishes to provide stock, when it is liable to be devoured by strangers.' By
the Act any new-comer, within forty days of arrival, could be ejected from a parish by an order from
the magistrates, upon complaint from the parish officers, and removed to the parish where he or she
was last legally settled. If, however, the new-comer settled in a tenement of the yearly value of £10,
or could give security for the discharge of the parish to the magistrates' satisfaction, he was exempt
from this provision.
As this Act carried with it the consequence that forty days' residence without complaint from the
parish officers gained the new-comer a settlement, it was an inevitable temptation to Parish A to
smuggle its poor into Parish B, where forty days' residence without the knowledge of the parish
officers would gain them a settlement. Fierce quarrels broke out between the parishes in
consequence. To compose these it was enacted (1 James II. c. 17) that the forty days' residence
were to be reckoned only after a written notice had been given to a parish officer. Even this was not
enough to protect Parish B, and by 3 William and Mary, c. 11 (1691) it was provided that this notice
must be read in church, immediately after divine service, and then registered in the book kept for
poor's accounts. Such a condition made it practically impossible for any poor man to gain a
settlement by forty days' residence, unless his tenement were of the value of £10 a year, but the Act
allowed an immigrant to obtain a settlement in any one of four ways; (1) by paying the parish taxes;
(2) by executing a public annual office in the parish; (3) by serving an apprenticeship in the parish;
(4) by being hired for a year's service in the parish. (This, however, only applied to the unmarried.)
In 1697 (8 and 9 William III. e. 30) a further important modification of the settlement laws was made.
To prevent the arbitrary ejection of new-comers by parish officers, who feared that the fresh arrival
or his children might somehow or other gain a settlement, it was enacted that if the new-comer
brought with him to Parish B a certificate from the parish officers of Parish A taking responsibility for
him, then he could not be removed till be became actually chargeable. It was further decided by this
and subsequent Acts and by legal decisions, that the granting of a certificate was to be left to the
discretion of the parish officers and magistrates, that the cost of removal fell on the certificating
parish, and that a certificate holder could only gain a settlement in a new parish by renting a
tenement of £10 annual value, or by executing a parish office, and that his apprentice or hired
servant could not gain a settlement.
In addition to these methods of gaining a settlement there were four other ways, 'through which,'
according to Eden, 'it is probable that by far the greater part of the labouring Poor... are actually
settled.'(18*) (1) Bastards, with some exceptions, acquired a settlement by birth;(19*) (2) legitimate
children also acquired a settlement by birth if their father's, or failing that, their mother's legal
settlement was not known; (3) women gained a settlement by marriage; (4) persons with an estate
of their own were irremovable, if residing on it, however small it might be.
Very few important modifications had been made in the laws of Settlement during the century after
1697. In 1722 (9 George I. c. 7) it was provided that no person was to obtain a settlement in any
parish by the purchase of any estate or interest of less value than £30, to be 'bona fide paid,' a
provision which suggests that parishes had connived at gifts of money for the purchase of estates in
order to discard their paupers: by the same Act the payment of the scavenger or highway rate was
declared not to confer a settlement. In 1784 (24 George III. c. 6) soldiers, sailors and their families
were allowed to exercise trades where they liked, and were not to be removable till they became
actually chargeable; and in 1793 (33 George III. c. 54) this latter concession was extended to
members of Friendly Societies. None of these concessions affected the normal labourer, and down
to 1795 a labourer could only make his way to a new village if his own village would give him a
certificate, or if the other village invited him. His liberty was entirely controlled by the parish officers.
How far did the Settlement Acts operate? How far did this body of law really affect the comfort and
liberty of the poor? The fiercest criticism comes from Adam Smith, whose fundamental instincts
rebelled against so crude and brutal an interference with human freedom. 'To remove a man who
has committed no misdemeanour, from a parish where he chuses to reside, is an evident violation
of natural liberty and justice. The common people of England, however, so jealous of their liberty,
but, like the common people of most other countries, never rightly understanding wherein it consists,
have now, for more than a century together, suffered themselves to be exposed to this oppression
without a remedy. Though men of reflexion, too, have sometimes complained of the law of
settlements as a public grievance; yet it has never been the object of any general popular clamour,
such as that against general warrants, an abusive practice undoubtedly, but such a one as was not
likely to occasion any general oppression. There is scarce a poor man in England, of forty years of
age, I will venture to say, who has not, in some part of his life, felt himself most cruelly oppressed by
this ill-contrived law of settlements.'(20*)
Adam Smith's view is supported by two contemporary writers on the Poor Law, Dr. Burn and Mr.
Hay. Dr. Burn, who published a history of the Poor Law in 1764, gives this picture of the overseer:
'The office of an Overseer of the Poor seems to be understood to be this, to keep an extraordinary
look-out to prevent persons coming to inhabit without certificates, and to fly to the Justices to
remove them: and if a man brings a certificate, then to caution the inhabitants not to let him a farm
of £10 a year, and to take care to keep him out of all parish offices.'(21*) He further says that the
parish officers will assist a poor man in taking a farm in a neighboring parish, and give him £10 for
the rent. Mr. Hay, M.P., protested in his remarks on the Poor Laws against the hardships inflicted on
the poor by the Laws of Settlement. 'It leaves it in the breast of the parish officers whether they will
grant a poor person a certificate or no.'(22*) Eden, on the other hand, thought Adam Smith's picture
overdrawn, and he contended that though there were no doubt cases of vexatious removal, the
Laws of Settlement were not administered in this way everywhere. Howlett also considered the
operation of the Laws of Settlement to be 'trifling,' and instanced the growth of Sheffield,
Birmingham, and Manchester as proof that there was little interference with the mobility of labour.
A careful study of the evidence seems to lead to the conclusion that the Laws of Settlement were in
practice, as they were on paper, a violation of natural liberty; that they did not stop the flow of labour,
but that they related it in the interest of the employing class. The answer to Howlett is given by
Ruggles in the Annals of Agriculture.(23*) He begins by saying that the Law of Settlement has made
a poor family 'of necessity stationary; and obliged them to rest satisfied with those wages they can
obtain where their legal settlement happens to be; a restraint on them which ought to insure to them
wages in the parish where they must remain, more adequate to their necessities, because it
precludes them in a manner from bringing their labour, the only marketable produce they possess,
to the best market; it is this restraint which has, in all manufacturing towns, been one cause of
reducing the poor to such a state of miserable poverty; for, among the manufacturers, they have too
frequently found masters who have taken, and continue to take every advantage, which strict law
will give; of consequence, the prices of labour have been, in manufacturing towns, in an inverse
ratio of the number of poor settled in the place; and the same cause has increased that number, by
inviting foreigners, in times when large orders required many workmen; the masters themselves
being the overseers, whose duty as parish officers has been opposed by their interest in supplying
the demand.' In other words, when it suited an employer to let fresh workers in, he would, qua
overseer, encourage them to come with or without certificates; but when they were once in and
'settled' he would refuse them certificates to enable them to go and try their fortunes elsewhere, in
parishes where a certificate was demanded with each poor new-comer.(24*) Thus it is not surprising
to find, from Eden's Reports, that certificates are never granted at Leeds and Skipton; seldom
granted at Sheffield; not willingly granted at Nottingham, and that at Halifax certificates are not
granted at present, and only three have been granted in the last eighteen years.
It has been argued that the figures about removals in different parishes given by Eden in his second
and third volumes show that the Law of Settlement was 'not so black as it has been painted.'(25*)
But in considering the small number of removals, we must also consider the large number of places
where there is this entry, 'certificates are never granted.' It needed considerable courage to go to a
new parish without a certificate and run the risk of an ignominious expulsion, and though all
overseers were not so strict as the one described by Dr. Burn, yet the fame of one vexatious
removal would have a far-reaching effect in checking migration. It is clear that the law must have
operated in this way in districts where enclosures took away employment within the parish. Suppose
Hodge to have lived at Kibworth-Beauchamp in Leicestershire. About 1780, 3600 acres were
enclosed and turned from arable to pasture; before enclosure the fields 'were solely applied to the
production of corn,' and 'the Poor had then plenty of employment in weeding, reaping, threshing,
etc., and could also collect a great deal of corn by gleaning.'(26*) After the change, as Eden admits,
a third or perhaps a fourth of the number of hands would be sufficient to do all the farming work
required. Let us say that Hodge was one of the superfluous two-thirds, and that the parish
authorities refused him a certificate. What did he do? He applied to the overseer, who sent him out
as a roundsman.(27*) He would prefer to bear the ills he knew rather than face the unknown in the
shape of a new parish officer, who might demand a certificate, and send him back with ignominy if
he failed to produce one. If he took his wife and family with him there was even less chance of the
demand for a certificate being waived.(28*) So at Kibworth-Beauchamp Hodge and his companions
remained, in a state of chronic discontent. 'The Poor complain of hard treatment from the overseers,
and the overseers accuse the Poor of being saucy.'(29*)
Now, at first sight, it seems obvious that it would be to the interest of a parish to give a poor man a
certificate, if there were no market for his labour at home, in order to enable him to go elsewhere
and make an independent living. This seems the reasonable view, but it is incorrect. In the same
way, it would seem obvious that a parish would give slight relief to a person whose claim was in
doubt rather than spend ten times the amount in contesting that claim at law. In point of fact, in
neither case do we find what seems the reasonable course adopted. Parishes spent fortunes in
lawsuits. And to the parish authorities it would seem that they risked more in giving Hodge a
certificate than in obliging him to stay at home, even if he could not make a living in his native place;
for he might, with his certificate, wander a long way off, and then fall into difficulties, and have to be
fetched back at great expense, and the cost of removing him would fall on the certificating parish.
There is a significant passage in the Annals of Agriculture(30*) about the wool trade in 1788. 'We
have lately had some hand-bills scattered about Bocking, I am told, promising full employ to
combers and weavers, that would migrate to Nottingham. Even if they chose to try this offer; as
probably a parish certificate for such a distance would be refused; it cannot be attempted.' Where
parishes saw an immediate prospect of getting rid of their superfluous poor into a neighboring parish
with open fields or a common, they were indeed not chary of granting certificates. At Hothfield in
Kent, for example, 'full half of the labouring poor are certificated persons from other parishes: the
above-mentioned common, which affords them the means of keeping a cow, or poultry, is supposed
to draw many Poor into the parish; certificated persons are allowed to dig peat.'(31*)
In the Rules for the government of the Poor in the hundreds of Loes and Wilford in Suffolk(32*) very
explicit directions are given about the granting of certificates. In the first place, before any certificate
is granted the applicant must produce an examination taken before a Justice of the Peace, showing
that he belongs to one of the parishes within the hundred. Granted that he has complied with this
condition, then, (1) if he be a labourer or husbandman no certificate will be granted him out of the
hundreds unless he belongs to the parish of Kenton, and even in that case it is 'not to exceed the
distance of three miles;' (2) if he be a tradesman, artificer, or manufacturer a certificate may be
granted to him out of the hundreds, but in no case is it to exceed the distance of twenty miles from
the parish to which he belongs. The extent of the hundreds was roughly fourteen miles by five and a
half.
Eden, describing the neighbourhood of Coventry, says: 'In a country parish on one side the city,
chiefly consisting of cottages inhabited by ribbon-weavers, the Rates are as high as in Coventry;
whilst, in another parish, on the opposite side, they do not exceed one-third of the City Rate: this is
ascribed to the care that is taken to prevent manufacturers from settling in the parish.'(33*) In the
neighbourhood of Mollington (Warwickshire and Oxon) the poor rates varied from 2s. to 4s. in the
pound. 'The difference in the several parishes, it is said, arises, in a great measure, from the facility
or difficulty of obtaining settlements: in several parishes, a fine is imposed on a parishoner, who
settles a newcomer by hiring, or otherwise, so that a servant is very seldom hired for a year. Those
parishes which have for a long time been in the habit of using these precautions, are now very
lightly burthened with Poor. This is often the case, where farms are large, and of course in few
hands; while other parishes, not politic enough to observe these rules, are generally burthened with
an influx of poor neighbours.'(34*) Another example of this is Deddington (Oxon) which like other
parishes that possessed common fields suffered from an influx of small farmers who had been
turned out elsewhere, whereas neighbouring parishes, possessed by a few individuals, were
cautious in permitting newcomers to gain settlements.(35*) This practice of hiring servants for fifty-
one weeks only was common: Eden thought it fraudulent and an evasion of the law that would not
be upheld in a court of justice,(36*) but he was wrong, for the 1817 Report on the Poor Law
mentions among 'the measures, justifiable undoubtedly in point of law, which are adopted very
generally in many parts of the kingdom, to defeat the obtaining a settlement, that of hiring labourers
for a less period than a year; from whence it naturally and necessarily follows, that a labourer may
spend the season of his health and industry in one parish, and be transferred in the decline of life to
a distant Part of the kingdom.'(37*) We hear little about the feelings of the unhappy labourers who
were brought home by the overseers when they fell into want in a parish which had taken them in
with their certificate, but it is not difficult to imagine the scene. It is significant that the Act of 1795 (to
which we shall refer later), contained a provision that orders of removal were to be suspended in
cases where the pauper was dangerously ill.
From the Rules for the Government of the Poor in the Hundreds of Loes and Wilford, already
alluded to, we learn some particulars of the allowance made for the removal of paupers. Twenty
miles was to be considered a day's journey; 2d. was to be allowed for one horse, and so on in
proportion per mile: but if the distance were over twenty miles, or the overseer were obliged to be
out all night, then 2s. was to be allowed for him, 1s. for his horse, and 6d. for each pauper.(38*) It is
improbable that such a scale of payment would induce the overseer to look kindly on the causes of
his trouble: much less would a pauper be a persona grata if litigation over his settlement had
already cost the parish large sums.
It has been necessary to give these particulars of the Law of Settlement for two reasons. In the first
place, the probability of expulsion, 'exile by administrative order,' as it has been called, threw a
shadow over the lives of the poor. In the second place, the old Law of Settlement became an
immensely more important social impediment when enclosure and the great industrial inventions
began to redistribute population. When the normal labourer had common rights and a strip and a
cow, he would not wish to change his home on account of temporary distress: after enclosure he
was reduced to a position in which his distress, if he stayed on in his own village, was likely to be
permanent.
The want and suffering revealed in Davies' and Eden's budgets came to a crisis in 1795, the year of
what may be called the revolt of the housewives. That year, when exceptional scarcity sharpened
the edge of the misery caused by the changes we have summarised, was marked by a series of
food riots all over England, in which a conspicuous part was taken by women. These disturbances
are particularly interesting from the discipline and good order which characterise the conduct of the
rioters. The rioters when they found themselves masters of the situation did not use their strength to
plunder the shops: they organised distribution, selling the food they seized at what they considered
fair rates, and handing over the proceeds to the owners. They did not rob: they fixed prices, and
when the owner of provisions was making for a dearer market they stopped his carts and made him
sell on the spot. At Aylesbury in March 'a numerous mob, consisting chiefly of women, seized on all
the wheat that came to market, and compelled the farmers to whom it belonged to accept of such
prices as they thought proper to name.'(39*) In Devonshire the rioters scoured the country round
Chudleigh, destroying two mills: 'from the great number of petticoats, it is generally supposed that
several men were dressed in female attire.'(40*) At Carlisle a band of women accompanied by boys
paraded the streets, and in spite of the remonstrances of a magistrate, entered various houses and
shops, seized all the grain, deposited it in the public hall, and then formed a committee to regulate
the price at which it should be sold.(41*) As Ipswich there was a riot over the price of butter, and at
Fordingbridge, a certain Sarah Rogers, in company with other women started a cheap butter
campaign. Sarah took some butter from Hannah Dawson 'with a determination of keeping it at a
reduced price,' an escapade for which she was afterwards sentenced to three months' hard labour
at the Winchester Assizes.' Nothing but the age of the prisoner (being very young) prevented the
Court from passing a more severe sentence.(42*) At Bath the women actually boarded a vessel,
laden with wheat and flour. which was lying in the river and refused to let her go. When the Riot Act
was read they retorted that they were not rioting, but were resisting the sending of corn abroad, and
sang God save the King. Although the owner took an oath that the corn was destined for Bristol,
they were not satisfied, and ultimately soldiers were called in, and the corn was relanded and put
into a warehouse.(43*) In some places the soldiers helped the populace in their work of fixing
prices: at Seaford, for example, they seized and sold meat and flour in the churchyard, and at
Guildford they were the ringleaders in a movement to lower the price of meat to 4d. a pound, and
were sent out of the town by the magistrates in consequence.(44*) These spontaneous leagues of
consumers sprang up in many different parts, for in addition to the places already mentioned there
were disturbances of sufficient importance to be chronicled in the newspapers, in Wiltshire, Suffolk,
and Norfolk, whist Eden states that at Deddington the populace seized on a boat laden with flour,
but restored it on the miller's promising to sell it at a reduced price.(45*)
These riots are interesting from many points of view. They are a rising of the poor against an
increasing pressure of want, and the forces that were driving down their standard of life. They did
not amount to a social rebellion, but they mark a stage in the history of the poor. To the rich they
were a signal of danger. Davies declared that if the ruling classes learnt from his researches what
was the condition of the poor, they would intervene to rescue the labourers from 'the abject state
into which they are sunk.' Certainly the misery of which his budgets paint the plain surface could not
be disregarded. If compassion was not a strong enough force to make the ruling classes attend to
the danger that the poor might starve, fear would certainly have made them think of the danger that
the poor might rebel. Some of them at any rate knew their Virgil well enough to remember that in the
description of the threshold of Orcus, while 'senectus' is 'tristis' and 'egestas' is 'turpis,' 'fames' is
linked with the more ominous epithet 'malesuada.' If a proletariat were left to starve despair might
teach bad habits, and this impoverished race might begin to look with ravenous eyes on the lot of
those who lived on the spoils and sinecures of the State. Thus fear and pity united to sharpen the
wits of the rich, and to turn their minds to the distresses of the poor.
NOTES:
1. Davies, The Case of Labourers in Husbandry, p. 15.
2. In some instance it is reckoned as costing only 7s. Ibid., see p. 185.
3. Davies, p. 181.
4. Eden, vol. ii, p. 547.
5. Vol. xxv, p. 488.
6. See Annuals of Agriculture, vol. ix, pp. 13, 14, 165-167, 636-646, and vol. x, pp. 218-227.
7. Capel Lofft (1751-1824); follower of Fox; writer of poems and translations from Virgil and
Petrarch; patron of Robert Bloomfield, author of Farmer's Boy. Called by Boswell 'This little David of
popular spirit.'
8. Thomas Ruggles (1737-1813), author of History of the Poor, published in 1793, Deputy-
Lieutenant of Essex and Suffolk.
9. Sir Henry Gould, 1710-1794.
10. The Annuals of Agriculture (vol. xvii, p. 293) contains a curious apology by a gleaner in 1791 to
the owner of some fields, who had begun legal proceedings against her and her husband. 'Whereas
I, Margaret Abree, with of Thomas Abree, of the city of New Sarum, blacksmith, did, during the
barley harvest, in the mouth of September las, many times wilfully and maliciously go into the fields
of, and belonging to, Mr Edward Perry, at Clarendon Park, and take with me my children, and did
there leaze, collect, and carry away a quantity of barley... Now we do hereby declare, that we are
fully convinced of the illegality of such proceedings, and that no person has a right to leaze any sort
of grain, or to come on any field whatsoever, without the consent of the owner; and are also truly
sensible of the obligation we are under to the said Edward Perry for his lenity towards us, inasmuch
as the damages given, together with the heavy cost incurred, would have been much greater than
we could possibly have discharged, and must have amounted to perpetual imprisonment, as even
those who have least disapproved of our conduct, would certainly not have contributed so large a
sum to deliver us from the legal consequences of it. And we do hereby faithfully promise never to be
guilty of the same, or any like offence in future. Thomas Abree, Margaret Abree. Her + Mark.' It is
interesting to compare with this judge-made law of England the Mosaic precept: 'And when ye reap
the harvest of your land, thou shalt not make clean riddance of the corners of they field when thou
reapest, neither shalt thou gather any gleaning of thy harvest: thou shalt leave them unto the poor,
and to the stranger.' (Leviticus xxiii, 22).
11. Kent, Hints. p. 238.
12. p. 34; cf. Marshall on the Southern Department, p. 9, 'Yorkshire bacon, generally of the worst
sort, is retailed to the poor from little chandlers' shops at an advanced price, bread in the same way.'
13. Notes on the Agriculture of Norfolk, p. 165.
14. Large and Small Holdings, p. 11.
15. Young's Political Arithmetic, quoted by Lecky, vol. vii, p. 263 note.
16. See Appendix B for six of these budgets.
17. Ruggles, Annals of Agriculture, vol. xiv, p. 205.
18. Eden, vol. i, p. 180.
19. The parish might have the satisfaction of punishing the mother by a year's hard labour (7 James
I, c. 4, altered in 1810), but could not get rid of the child.
20. Wealth of Nations, vol. i, p. 194.
21. Quoted by Eden, vol. i, p. 347.
22. See Ibid., p. 296.
23. Vol. xiv, pp. 205, 206.
24. An example of a parish where the interests of the employer and of the parish officers differed is
given in the House of Commons Journal for February 4, 1788, when a petition was presented from
Mr John Wilkinson, a master iron founder at Bradley, near Bilston, in the parish of Wolverhampton.
The petitioner states 'that the present Demand for the Iron of his Manufacture and the Improvement
of which is capable, naturally encourage a very considerable Extension of his Works, but that the
Experience he has had of the vexation Effect, as well as of the constantly increasing Amount of
Poor Rates to which he is subject, has filled him with Apprehensions of final Ruin to his
Establishment; and that the Parish Officers... are constantly alarming his Workmen with Threats of
Removal to the various Parishes from which the Necessity of employing skilful Manufacturers has
obliged him to collect them.' He goes on to ask that his district shall be made extra-parochial to the
poor rates.
25. Hasbach, pp. 172-3.
26. Eden, vol. ii, p. 384.
27. See p. 148.
28. The unborn were the special objects of parish officers' dread. At Derby the persons sent out
under orders of removal are chiefly pregnant girls. (Eden vol. ii, p. 126). Bastards (see above) with
some exceptions gained a settlement in their birthplace, and Hodge's legitimate children might gain
one too if there was any doubt about the place of their parents' settlements.
29. Eden, vol. ii, p. 383.
30. vol. ix, p. 660.
31. Eden, vol. ii, p. 288. 'In considering the accounts of the state of the commons, it must be
remember that the open parishes thus paid the penalty of enclosure elsewhere. Colluvies vicorum.
But these open fields and commons were becoming rapidly more scarce.
32. Ibid., p. 691.
33. Eden, vol. ii, p. 743.
34. Ibid.
35. Ibid., vol. ii, p. 591.
36. Ibid., p. 654, re Litchfield. 'In two or three small parishes in this neighbourhood, which consist of
large farms, there are very few poor: the farmers, in order to prevent the introduction of poor from
other parishes, hire their servants for fifty-one weeks only. I conceive, however, that this practice
would be considered, by a court of justice, as fraudulent, and a mere evasion in the master; and that
a servant thus hired, if he remained the fifty-second week with his master, on a fresh contract, would
acquire a settlement in the parish.'
37. See Annual Register, 1817, p. 298.
38. Eden, vol. ii, p. 689.
39. Reading Mercury, April 20, 1795; also Ipswich Journal, March 28.
40. Ipswich Journal, April 18.
41. Ibid., August 8.
42. Ibid.
43. Ibid.
44. Reading Mercury, April 27, 1795.
45. Eden, vol. ii, p. 591.
Chapter Six
The Remedies of 1795
The collapse of the economic position of the labourer was the result of many causes, and in
examining the various remedies that were proposed we shall see that they touch in turn on the
several deficiencies that produced this failure. The governing fact of the situation was that the
labourer's wages no longer sufficed to provide even a bare and comfortless existence. It was
necessary then that his wages should be raised, or that the effects of the rise in prices should be
counteracted by changes of diet and manner of life, or that the economic resources which formerly
supplemented his earnings should in some way be restored, unless he was to be thrown headlong
on to the Poor Law. We shall see what advice was given and what advice was taken in these
momentous years.
DIET REFORM
A disparity between income and expenditure may be corrected by increasing income or by reducing
expenditure. Many of the upper classes thought that the second method might be tried in this
emergency, and that a judicious change of diet would enable the labourer to face the fall of wages
with equanimity. The solution seemed to lie in the simple life. Enthusiasts soon began to feel about
this proposal the sort of excitement that Robinson Crusoe enjoyed when discovering new resources
on his island: an infinite vista of kitchen reform beckoned to their ingenious imaginations: and many
of them began to persuade themselves that the miseries of the poor arose less from the scantiness
of their incomes than from their own improvidence and unthriftiness.(1*) The rich set an example in
the worst days by cutting off pastry and restricting their servants to a quartern loaf a week each.(2*)
It was surely not too much in these circumstances to ask the poor to adapt their appetites to the
changed conditions of their lives, and to shake off what Pitt called 'groundless prejudices' to mixed
bread of barley, rye, and wheat.(3*) Again oatmeal was a common food in the north, why should it
not be taken in the south? If no horses except post horses and perhaps cavalry horses were allowed
oats, there would be plenty for the poor.(4*) A Cumberland labourer with a wife and family of five
was shown by Eden(5*) to have spent £7, 9s. 2d. a year on oatmeal and barley, whereas a
Berkshire labourer with a wife and four children at home spent £36, 8s. a year on wheaten bread
alone.(6*) Clearly the starving south was to be saved by the introduction of cheap cereals.
Other proposals of this time were to break against the opposition of the rich. This broke against the
opposition of the poor. All attempts to popularise substitutes failed, and the poorer the labourer grew
the more stubbornly did he insist on wheaten bread. 'Even household bread is scarcely ever used:
they buy the finest wheaten bread, and declare (what I much doubt), that brown bread disorders
their bowels. Bakers do not now make, as they formerly did, bread of unsifted flour: at some
farmers' houses, however, it is still made of flour, as it comes from the mill; but this practice is going
much into disuse. 20 years ago scarcely any other than brown bread was used.'(7*) At Ealing, when
the charitable rich raised a subscription to provide the distressed poor with brown bread at a
reduced price, many of the labourers thought it so coarse and unpalatable that they returned the
tickets though wheaten bread was at 1s. 3d. the quartern loaf.(8*) Correspondent after
correspondent to the Annals of Agriculture notes and generally deplores the fact that the poor, as
one of them phrases it, are too fine-mouthed to eat any but the finest bread.(9*) Lord Sheffield,
judging from his address to Quarter Sessions at the end of 1795, would have had little mercy on
such grumblers. After explaining that in his parish relief was now given partly in potatoes, partly in
wheaten flour, and partly in oaten or barley flour, he declared: 'If any wretches should be found so
lost to all decency, and so blind as to revolt against the dispensations of providence, and to refuse
the food proposed for their relief, the parish officers will be justified in refusing other succour, and
may be assured of support from the magistracy of the county.'(10*)
To the rich, the reluctance of the labourer to change his food came as a painful surprise. They had
thought of him as a roughly built and hardy animal, comparatively insensible to his surroundings,
like the figure Lucretius drew of the primeval labourer:
<poem>
Et majoribus et solidis magis ossibus intus
Fundatum, et validis aptum per viscera nervis;
Nec facile ex aestu, nec frigore quod caperetur,
Nec novitate cibi, nec labi corporis ulla.
<poem>
They did not know that a romantic and adventurous appetite is one of the blessings of an easy life,
and that the more miserable a man's condition, and the fewer his comforts, the more does he shrink
from experiments of diet. They were therefore surprised and displeased to find that labourers
rejected soup, even soup served at a rich man's table, exclaiming, 'This is washy stuff, that affords
no nourishment: we will not be fed on meal, and chopped potatoes like hogs.'(11*) The dislike of
change of food was remarked by the Poor Law Commissioners in 1834, who observed that the
labourer had acquired or retained 'with the moral helplessness some of the other peculiarities of a
child. He is often disgusted to a degree which other classes scarcely conceive possible, by slight
differences in diet; and is annoyed by anything that seeks to him strange and new.'(12*)
Apart from the constitutional conservatism of the poor there were good reasons for the obstinacy of
the labourers. Davies put one aspect of the case very well. 'If the working people of other countries
are content with bread made of rye, barley, or oats, have they not milk, cheese, butter, fruits, or fish,
to eat with that coarser bread? And was not this the case of our own people formerly, when these
grains were the common productions of our land, and when scarcely wheat enough was grown for
the use of the nobility and principal gentry? Flesh-meat, butter, and cheese, were then at such
moderate prices, compared with the present prices, that poor people could afford to use them in
common. And with a competent quantity of these articles, a coarser kind of bread might very well
satisfy the common people of any country.'(13*) He also states that where land had not been so
highly improved as to produce much wheat, barley, oatmeal, or maslin bread were still in common
use. Arthur Young himself realised that the labourer's attachment to wheaten bread was not a mere
superstition of the palate. 'In the East of England I have been very generally assured, by the
labourers who work the hardest, that they prefer the finest bread, not because most pleasant, but
most contrary to a lax habit of body, which at once prevents all strong labour. The quality of the
bread that is eaten by those who have meat, and perhaps porter and port, is of very little
consequence indeed; but to the hardworking man, who nearly lives on it, the case is abundantly
different.'(14*) Fox put this point in a speech in the House of Commons in the debate on the high
price of corn in November 1795. He urged gentlemen, who were talking of mixed bread for the
people, 'not to judge from any experiment made with respect to themselves. I have myself tasted
bread of different sorts, I have found it highly pleasant, and I have no doubt it is exceedingly
wholesome. But it ought to be recollected how very small a part the article of bread forms of the
provisions consumed by the more opulent classes of the community. To the poor it constitutes, the
chief, if not the sole article of subsistence.'(15*) The truth is that the labourer living on bread and tea
had too delicate a digestion to assimilate the coarser cereals, and that there was, apart from climate
and tradition, a very important difference between the labourer in the north and the labourer in the
south, which the rich entirely overlooked. That difference comes out in an analysis of the budgets of
the Cumberland labourer and the Berkshire labourer. The Cumberland labourer who spent only £7,
9s. on his cereals, spent £2, 13s. 7d. a year on milk. The Berkshire labourer who spent £36, 8s. on
wheaten bread spent 8s. 8d. a year on milk. The Cumberland family consumed about 1300 quarts in
the year, the Berkshire family about two quarts a week. The same contrast appears in all budget
comparisons between north and south. A weaver at Kendal (eight in the family) spends £12, 9s. on
oatmeal and wheat, and £5, 4s. on milk.(16*) An agricultural labourer at Wetherall in Cumberland
(five in family) spends £7, 6s. 9d. on cereals and £2, 13s. 4d. on milk.(17*) On the other side we
have a labourer in Shropshire (four in family) spending £10, 8s. on bread (of wheat rye), and only
8s. 8d. on milk,(18*) and a cooper at Frome, Somerset (seven in family) spending £45, 10s. on
bread, and about 17s. on milk.(19*) These figures are typical.(20*)
Now oatmeal eaten with milk is a very different food from oatmeal taken alone, and it is clear from a
study of the budgets that if oatmeal was to be acclimatised in the south, it was essential to increase
the consumption of milk. But the great difference in consumption represented not a difference of
demand, but a difference of supply. The southern labourer went without milk not from choice but
from necessity. In the days when he kept cows he drank milk, for there was plenty of milk in the
village. After enclosure, milk was not to be had. It may be that more cows were kept under the new
system of farming, though this is unlikely, seeing that at this time every patch of arable was a gold-
mine, but it is certainly true that milk became scarce in the villages. The new type of farmer did not
trouble to sell milk at home. 'Farmers are averse to selling milk; while poor persons who have only
one cow generally dispose of all they can spare.'(21*) The new farmer produced for a larger market:
his produce was carried away, as Cobbett said, to be devoured by 'the idlers, the thieves, the
prostitutes who are all taxeaters in the wens of Bath and London.' Davies argued, when pleading for
the creation of small farms, 'The occupiers of these small farms, as well as the occupiers of Mr.
Kent's larger cottages, would not think much of retailing to their poorer neighbours a little corn or a
little milk, as they might want, which the poor can now seldom have at all, and never but as a great
favour from the rich farmers.'(22*) Sir Thomas Bernard mentioned among the advantages of the
Winchilsea system the 'no inconsiderable convenience to the inhabitants of that neighbourhood, that
these cottagers are enabled to supply them, at a very moderate price, with milk, cream, butter,
poultry, pig-meat, and veal: articles which, in general, are not worth the farmer's attention, and
which, therefore, are supplied by speculators, who greatly enhance the price on the public.'(23*)
Eden(24*) records that in Oxfordshire the labourers bitterly complain that the farmers, instead of
selling their milk to the poor, give it to their pigs, and a writer in the Reports of the Society for
Bettering the Condition of the Poor says that this was a practice not unusual in many parts of
England.(25*)
The scarcity of milk must be considered a contributory cause of the growth of tea-drinking, a habit
that the philanthropists and Cobbett agreed in condemning. Cobbett declared in his Advice to
Young Men(26*) that 'if the slops were in fashion amongst ploughmen and carters, we must all be
starved; for the food could never be raised. The mechanics are half ruined by them.' In the Report
on the Poor presented to the Hants Quarter Sessions in 1795,(27*) the use of tea is described as 'a
vain present attempt to supply to the spirits of the mind what is wanting to the strength of the body;
but in its lasting effects impairing the nerves, and therein equally injuring both the body and the
mind.' Davies retorted on the rich who found fault with the extravagance of the poor in tea-drinking,
by pointing out that it was their 'last resource.' 'The topic on which the declaimers against the
extravagance of the poor display their eloquence with most success, is tea-drinking. Why should
such people, it is asked, indulge in a luxury which is only proper for their betters; and not rather
content themselves with milk, which is in every form wholesome and nourishing? Were it true that
poor people could every where procure so excellent an article as milk, there would be then just
reason to reproach them for giving the preference to the miserable infusion of which they are so
fond. But it is not so. Wherever the poor can get milk, do they not gladly use it? And where they
cannot get it, would they not gladly exchange their tea for it?(28*)... Still you exclaim, Tea is a luxury.
If you mean fine hyson tea, sweetened with refined, sugar, and softened with cream, I readily admit
it to be so. But this is not the tea of the poor. Spring water, just coloured with a few leaves of the
lowest-priced tea, and sweetened with the brownest sugar, is the luxury for which you reproach
them. To this they have recourse from mere necessity: and were they now to be deprived of this,
they would immediately be reduced to bread and water. Tea-drinking is not the cause, but the
consequence, of the distresses of the poor.'(29*) We learn from the Annals of Agriculture that at
Sedgefield in Durham(30*) many of the poor declared that they had been driven to drinking tea from
not being able to procure milk.(31*)
No doubt the scarcity of milk helped to encourage a taste that was very quickly acquired by all
classes in England, and not in England only, for, before the middle of the eighteenth century, the
rapid growth of tea-drinking among the poor in the Lowlands of Scotland was affecting the revenue
very. The English poor liked tea for the same reason seriously(32*) that Dr. Johnson liked it, as a
stimulant, and the fact that their food was monotonous and insipid made it particularly attractive.
Eden shows that by the end of the eighteenth century it was in general use among poor families,
taking the place both of beer and of milk, and excluding the substitutes that Eden wished to make
popular. It seems perhaps less surprising to us than it did to him, that when the rich, who could eat
or drink what they liked, enjoyed tea, the poor thought bread and tea a more interesting diet than
bread and barley water.
A few isolated attempts were made to remedy the scarcity of milk,(33*) which had been caused by
enclosure and the consolidation of farms. Lord Winchilsea's projects have already been described.
In the Reports of the Society for bettering the Condition of the Poor, there are two accounts of plans
for supplying milk cheap, one in Staffordshire, where a respectable tradesman undertook to keep a
certain number of cows for the purpose in a parish where 'the principal number of the poorer
inhabitants were destitute of all means of procuring milk for their families,'(34*) another at Stockton
in Durham, where the bishop made it a condition of the lease of a certain farm, that the tenant
should keep fifteen cows whose milk was to be sold at 1/2d. a pint to the poor.(35*) Mr. Curwen
again, the Whig M.P. for Carlisle, had a plan for feeding cows in the winter with a view to providing
the poor with milk.(36*)
There was another way in which the enclosures had created an insuperable obstacle to the
popularising of 'cheap and agreeable substitutes' for expensive wheaten bread. The Cumberland
housewife could bake her own barley bread in her oven 'heated with heath, furze or brush-wood, the
expence of which is inconsiderable;'(37*) she had stretches of waste land at her door where the
children could be sent to fetch fuel. 'There is no comparison to the community,' wrote a contributor
to the Annals of Agriculture,(38*) 'whether good wheat, rye, turnips, etc., are not better than brakes,
goss, furz, broom, and heath,' but as acre after acre in the midlands and south was enclosed, the
fuel of the poor grew ever scantier. When the common where he had gleaned his firing was fenced
off, the poor man could only trust for his fuel to pilferings from the hedgerows. To the spectator,
furze from the common might seem 'gathered with more loss of time than it appears to be
worth;'(39*) to the labourer whose scanty earnings left little margin over the expense of bread alone,
the loss of firing was not balanced by the economy of time.(40*)
Insufficient firing added to the miseries caused by insufficient clothes and food. An ingenious writer
in the Annals of Agriculture(41*) suggested that the poor should resort to the stables for warmth, as
was the practice in the duchy of Milan. Fewer would suffer death from want of fire in winter, he
argued, and also it would be a cheap way of helping them, as it cost no fuel, for cattle were so
obliging as to dispense warmth from their persons for nothing. But even this plan (which was not
adopted) would not have solved the problem of cooking. The labourer might be blamed for his diet
of fine wheaten bread and for having his meat (when he had any) roasted instead of made into
soup, but how could cooking be done at home without fuel? 'No doubt, a labourer,' says Eden,(42*)
'whose income was only £20 a year, would, in general, act wisely in substituting hasty-pudding,
barley bread, boiled milk, and potatoes, for bread and beer; but in most parts of this county, he is
debarred not more by prejudice, than by local difficulties, from using a diet that requires cooking at
home. The extreme dearness of fuel in Oxfordshire, compels him to purchase his dinner at the
baker's; and, from his unavoidable consumption of bread, he has little left for cloaths, in a country
where warm cloathing is most essentially wanted.' In Davies' more racy and direct language, 'it is
but little that in the present state of things the belly can spare for the back.'(43*) Davies also pointed
out the connection between dear fuel and the baker. 'Where fuel is scarce and dear, poor people
find it cheaper to buy their bread of the baker than to bake for themselves.... But where fuel
abounds, and costs only the trouble of cutting and carrying home, there they may save something
by baking their own bread.'(44*) Complaints of the pilfering of hedgerows were very common.
'Falstaff says " his soldiers found linen on every hedge;" and I fear it is but too often the case, that
labourers' children procure fuel from the same quarter.'(45*) There were probably many families like
the two described in Davies(46*) who spent nothing on fuel, which they procured 'by gathering cow-
dung, and breaking their neighbours' hedges.'(47*)
In some few cases, the benevolent rich did not content themselves with attempting to enforce the
eighth commandment, but went to the root of the matter, helping to provide a substitute for their
hedgerows. An interesting account of such an experiment is given in the Reports on the Poor(48*)
by Scrope Bernard. 'There having been several prosecutions at the Aylesbury Quarter Sessions, for
stealing fuel last winter, I was led to make particular inquiries, respecting the means which the poor
at Lower Winchendon had of providing fuel. I found that there was no fuel then to be sold within
several miles of the place; and that, amid the distress occasioned by the long frost, a party of
cottagers had joined in hiring a person, to fetch a load of pit-coal from Oxford, for their supply. In
order to encourage this disposition to acquire fuel in an honest manner,' a present was made to all
this party of as much coal again as they had already purchased carriage free. Next year the vestry
determined to help, and with the aid of private donations coal was distributed at 1s. 4d. the cwt. (its
cost at the Oxford wharf), and kindling faggots at 1d. each. 'It had been said that the poor would not
find money to purchase them, when they were brought: instead of which out of 35 poor families
belonging to the parish, 29 came with ready money, husbanded out of their scanty means, to profit
with eagerness of this attention to their wants; and among them a person who had been lately
imprisoned by his master for stealing wood from his hedges.' Mr. Bernard concludes his account
with some apt remarks on the difficulties of combining honesty with grinding poverty.(49*)
MINIMUM WAGE
The attempts to reduce cottage expenditure were thus a failure. We must now describe the attempts
to increase the cottage income. There were two ways in which the wages of the labourers might
have been raised. One way, the way of combination, was forbidden by law. The other way was the
fixing of a legal minimum wage in relation to the price of food. This was no new idea, for the
regulation of wages by law was a venerable English institution, as old as the Statute of Edward III.
The most recent laws on the subject were the famous Act of Elizabeth, an Act of James I, and an
Act of George II (1747). The Act of Elizabeth provided that the Justices of the Peace should meet
annually and assess the wages of labourers in husbandry and of certain other workmen. Penalties
were imposed on all who gave or took a wage in excess of this assessment. The Act of James I was
passed to remove certain ambiguities that were believed to have embarrassed the operation of the
Act of Elizabeth, and among other provisions imposed a penalty on all who gave a wage below the
wage fixed by the magistrates. The Act of 1747(50*) was passed because the existing laws were
'insufficient and defective,' and it provided that disputes between masters and men could be referred
to the magistrates, 'although no rate or assessment of wages has been made that year by the
Justices of the shire, where such complaint shall be made.'
Two questions arise on the subject of this legislation, Was it operative? In whose interests was it
administered, the interests of the employers or the interests of the employed? As to the first
question there is a good deal of negative evidence to show that during the eighteenth century these
laws were rarely applied. An example of an assessment (an assessment declaring a maximum)
made by the Lancashire magistrates in 1725, was published in the Annals of Agriculture in 1795
(51*) as an interesting curiosity, and the writer remarks: 'It appears from Mr. Ruggles' excellent
History of the Poor that such orders must in general be searched for in earlier periods, and a friend
of ours was much surprised to hear that any magistrates in the present century would venture on so
bold a measure.'(52*)
As to the second question, at the time we are discussing it was certainly taken for granted that this
legislation was designed to keep wages down. So implicitly was this believed that the Act of James I
which provided penalties in cases where wages were given below the fixed rate was generally
ignored, and speakers and writers mentioned only the Act of Elizabeth, treating it as an Act for fixing
a maximum. Whitbread, for example, when introducing a Bill in 1795 to fix a minimum wage, with
which we deal later, argued that the Elizabethan Act ought to be repealed because it fixed a
maximum. This view of the earlier legislation was taken by Fox, who supported Whitbread's Bill, and
by Pitt who opposed it. Fox said of the Act of Elizabeth that 'it secured the master from a risk which
could but seldom occur, of being charged exorbitantly for the quantity of service; but it did not
authorise the magistrate to protect the poor from the injustice of a grinding and avaricious master,
who might be disposed to take advantage of their necessities, and undervalue the rate of their
services.'(53*) Pitt said that Whitbread 'imagined that he had on his side of the question the support
of experience in this country, and appealed to certain laws upon the statute-book in confirmation of
his proposition. He did not find himself called upon to defend the principle of these statutes, but they
were certainly introduced for purposes widely different from the object of the present bill. They were
enacted to guard the industry of the country from being checked by a general combination among
labourers; and the bill now under consideration was introduced solely for the purpose of remedying
the inconveniences which labourers sustain from the disproportion existing between the price of
labour and the price of living.'(54*) Only one speaker in the debates, Vansittart, afterwards
Chancellor of the Exchequer, took the view that legislation was not needed because the Act of
James I gave the magistrates the powers with which Whitbread sought to arm them.
It was natural that many minds searching after a way of escape from the growing distress of the
labourers, at a time when wages had not kept pace with prices, should have turned to the device of
assessing wages by law in accordance with the price of provisions. If prices could not be
assimilated to wages, could not wages be assimilated to prices? Nathaniel Kent, no wild visionary,
had urged employers to raise wages in proportion to the increase of their profits, but his appeal had
been without effect. But the policy of regulating wages according to the price of food was
recommended in several quarters, and it provoked a great deal of discussion. Burke, whose days
were closing in, was tempted to take part in it, and he put an advertisement into the papers
announcing that he was about to publish a series of letters on the subject. The letters never
appeared, but Arthur Young has described the visit he paid to Beaconsfield at this time and Burke's
rambling thunder about 'the absurdity of regulating labour and the mischief of our poor laws,' and
Burke's published works include a paper Thoughts and details on Scarcity, presented to Pitt in
November 1795. In this paper Burke argued that the farmer was the true guardian of the labourer's
interest, in that it would never be profitable to him to underpay the labourer: an uncompromising
application of the theory of the economic man, which was not less superficial than the Jacobins'
application of the theory of the natural man.
In October 1795 Arthur Young sent out to the various correspondents of the Board of Agriculture a
circular letter containing this question among others: 'It having been recommended by various
quarter-sessions, that the price of labour should be regulated by that of bread corn, have the
goodness to state what you conceive to be the advantages or disadvantages of such a
system?'(55*) Arthur Young was himself in favour of the proposal, and the Suffolk magistrates, at a
meeting which he attended on the 12th of October, ordered: 'That the Members for this county be
requested by the chairman to bring a bill into parliament, so to regulate the price of labour, that it
may fluctuate with the average price of bread corn.'(56*) Most of the replies were adverse, but the
proposal found a warm friend in Mr. Howlett, the Vicar of Dunmow, who put into his answer some of
the arguments which he in reply to afterwards developed in a pamphlet published. Pitt's criticisms of
Whitbread's Bill.(57*) Howlett argued that Parliament had legislated with success to prevent
combinations of workmen, and as an example he quoted the Acts of 8 George III, which had made
the wages of tailors and silkweavers subject to the regulations of the magistrates. It was just as
necessary and just as practicable to prevent a combination of a different kind, that of masters. 'Not a
combination indeed formally drawn up in writing and sanctioned under hand and seal, a
combination, however, as certain (the result of contingencies or providential events) and as fatally
efficacious as if in writing it had filled five hundred skins of parchment: a combination which has
operated for many years with a force rapidly increasing, a combination which has kept back the hire
of our labourers who have reaped down our fields, and has at length torn the clothes from their
backs, snatched the food from their mouths, and ground the flesh from their bones.' Howlett, it will
be seen, took the same view as Thelwall, that the position of the labourers was deteriorating
absolutely and relatively. He estimated from a survey taken at Dunmow that the average family
should be taken as five; if wages had been regulated on this basis, and the labourer had been given
per head no more than the cost of a pauper's keep in the workhouse sixty years ago, he would have
been very much better off in 1795. He would himself take a higher standard. In reply to the
argument that the policy of the minimum wage would deprive the labourers of all spur and incentive
he pointed to the case of the London tailors; they at any rate displayed plenty of life and ingenuity,
and nobody could say that the London fashions did not change fast enough. Employers would no
more raise wages without compulsion than they would make good roads without the aid of turnpikes
or the prescription of statutes enforced by the magistrates. His most original contribution to the
discussion was the argument that the legal regulation should not be left to the unassisted judgment
of the magistrates: 'it should be the result of the clearest, fullest, and most accurate information, and
at length be judiciously adapted to each county, hundred, or district in every quarter of the kingdom.'
Howlett differed from some of the supporters of a minimum wage, in thinking that wages should be
regulated by the prices of the necessaries of life, not merely by that of bread corn.
The same policy was advocated by Davies in The Case of Labourers in Husbandry.(58*) Davies
argued that if the minimum only were fixed, emulation would not be discouraged, for better workmen
would both be more sure of employment and also obtain higher wages. He suggested that the
minimum wage should be fixed by calculating the sum necessary to maintain a family of five, or by
settling the scale of day wages by the price of bread alone, treating the other expenses as tolerably
steady. He did not propose to regulate the wages of any but day labourers, nor did he propose to
deal with piecework, although piecework had been included in the Act of Elizabeth. He further
suggested that the regulation should be in force only for half the year, from November to May, when
the labourers' difficulties pressed hardest upon them. Unfortunately he coupled with his minimum
wage policy a proposal to give help from the rates to families with more than five members, if the
children were unable to earn.
But the most interesting of all the declarations in favour of a minimum wage was a declaration from
labourers. A correspondent sent the following advertisement to the Annals of Agriculture: --
'The following is an advertisement which I cut out of a Norwich newspaper: --
"DAY LABOURERS"
At a numerous meeting of the day labourers of the little parishes of Heacham, Snettisham, and
Sedgford, this day, 5th November, in the parish church of Heacham, in the county of Norfolk, in
order to take into consideration the best and most peaceable mode of obtaining a redress of all the
severe and peculiar hardships under which they have for many years so patiently suffered, the
following resolutions were unanimously agreed to: -- 1st, That -- The labourer is worthy of his hire,
and that the mode of lessening his distresses, as hath been lately the fashion, by selling him flour
under the market price, and thereby rendering him an object of a parish rate, is not only an indecent
insult on his lowly and humble situation (in itself sufficiently mortifying from his degrading
dependence on the caprice of his employer) but a fallacious mode of relief, and every way
inadequate to a radical redress of the manifold distresses of his calamitous state. 2nd, That the
price of labour should, at all times, be proportioned to the price of wheat, which should invariably be
regulated by the average price of that necessary article of life; and that the price of labour, as
specified in the annexed plan, is not only well calculated to make the labourer happy without being
injurious to the farmer, but it appears to us the only rational means of securing the permanent
happiness of this valuable and useful class of men, and, if adopted in its full extent, will have an
immediate and powerful effect in reducing, if it does not entirely annihilate, that disgraceful and
enormous tax on the public -- the POOR RATE.
"Plan of the Price of Labour proportionate to the Price of Wheat
per last. per day.
When wheat shall be 14 l. the price of labour shall be 1s. 2d.
"" 16""" 1s. 4d.
"" 18""" 1s. 6d.
"" 20""" 1s. 8d.
"" 22""" 1s. 10d.
"" 24""" 2s. 0d.
"" 26""" 2s. 2d.
"" 28""" 2s. 4d.
"" 30""" 2s. 6d.
"" 32""" 2s. 8d.
"" 34""" 2s. 10d.
"" 36""" 3s. 0d.
And so on, according to this proportion.
"3rd, That a petition to parliament to regulate the price of labour, conformable to the above plan, be
immediately adopted; and that the day labourers throughout the county be invited to associate and
co-operate in this necessary application to parliament, as a peaceable, legal, and probable mode of
obtaining relief; and, in doing this, no time should be lost, as the petition must be presented before
the 29th January 1796.
"4th, That one shilling shall be paid into the hands of the treasurer by every labourer, in order to
defray the expences of advertising, attending on meetings, and paying counsel to support their
petition in parliament.
"5th, That as soon as the sense of the day labourers of this county, or a majority of them, shall be
made known to the clerk of the meeting, a general meeting shall be appointed, in some central
town, in order to agree upon the best and easiest mode of getting the petition signed: when it will be
requested that one labourer, properly instructed, may be deputed to represent two or three
contiguous parishes, and to attend the above intended meeting with a list of all the labourers in the
parishes he shall represent, and pay their respective subscriptions; and that the labourer, so
deputed, shall be allowed two shillings and six pence a day for his time, and two shillings and six
pence a day for his expences.
"6th, That Adam Moore, clerk of the meeting, be directed to have the above resolutions, with the
names of the farmers and labourers who have subscribed to and approved them, advertised in one
Norwich and one London Raper; when it is hoped that the above plan of a petition to parliament will
not only be approved and immediately adopted by the day labourers of this county, but by the day
labourers of every county in the kingdom.
"7th, That all letters, post paid, addressed to Adam Moore, labourer, at Heacham, near Lynn,
Norfolk, will be duly noticed."(59*)
This is one of the most interesting and instructive documents of the time. It shows that the labourers,
whose steady decline during the next thirty years we are about to trace, were animated by a sense
of dignity and independence. Something of the old spirit of the commoners still survived. But there is
no sequel to this incident. This great scheme of a labourers' organisation vanishes: it passes like a
flash of summer lightning. What is the explanation? The answer is to be found, we suspect, in the
Treason and Sedition Acts that Pitt was carrying through Parliament in this very month. Under those
Acts no language of criticism was safe, and fifty persons could not meet except in the presence of a
magistrate, who had power to extinguish the meeting and arrest the speaker. Those measures
inflicted even wider injury upon the nation than Fox and Sheridan and Erskine themselves believed.
The policy of a minimum wage was brought before Parliament in the winter of 1795, in a Bill
introduced by Samuel Whitbread, one of the small band of brave Liberals who had stood by Fox
through the revolutionary panic. Whitbread is a politician to whom history has done less than justice,
and he is generally known only as an implacable opponent of the Peninsular War. That opposition
he contrived to conduct, as we know from the Creevey Papers, in such a way as to win and keep the
respect of Wellington. Whitbread's disapproval of that war, of which Liberals like Holland and Lord
John Russell, who took Fox's view of the difference of fighting revolutions by the aid of kings and
fighting Napoleon by the aid of peoples, were strong supporters, sprang from his compassion for the
miseries of the English poor. His most notable quality was his vivid and energetic sympathy; he
spent his life in hopeless battles, and he died by his own hand of public despair. The Bill he now
introduced was the first of a series of proposals designed for the rescue of the agricultural labourers.
It was backed by Sheridan and Grey,(60*) and the members for Suffolk.
The object of the Bill(61*) was to explain and amend the Act of Elizabeth, which empowered
Justices of the Peace at or within six weeks of every General Quarter Sessions held at Easter to
regUlate the wages of labourers in husbandry. The provisions of the Bill were briefly as follows. At
any Quartet Sessions the justices could agree, if they thought fit, to hold a General Sessions for
carrying into execution the powers given them by the Act. If they thought good to hold such a
General Sessions, the majority of them could 'rate and appoint the wages and fix and declare the
hours of working of all labourers in husbandry, by the day, week, month or year, and with beer or
cyder or without, respect being had to the value of money and the plenty or scarcity of the time.' This
rate was to be printed and posted on the church doors, and was to hold good till superseded by
another made in the same way. The rate was not to apply to any tradesman or artificer, nor to any
labourer whose diet was wholly provided by his employer, not to any labourer bona fide employed
on piecework, nor to any labourer employed by the parish. The young, the old, and the infirm were
also exempted from the provisions of the Act. It was to be lawful 'to contract with and pay to any
male person, under the age of ---- (62*) years, or to any man who from age ot infirmity or any other
incapacity shall be unable to do the ordinary work of a labouring man, so much as he shall
reasonably deserve for the work which he shall be able to do and shall do.' In case of complaint the
decision as to the ability of the labourer rested with the justices.
With the above exceptions no labourer was to be hired under the appointed rates, and any contract
for lower wages was void. If convicted of breaking the law, an employer was to be fined; if he
refused to pay the fine, his goods were to be distrained on, and if this failed to produce enough to
pay the expenses, he could be committed to the common gaol or House of Correction. A labourer
with whom an illegal contract was made was to be a competent witness.
The first discussions of the Bill were friendly in tone. On 25th November Whitbread asked for leave
to bring it in. Sir William Young, Lechmere, Charles Dundas, and Sir John Rous all spoke with
sympathy and approval. The first reading debate took place on 9th december, and though
Whitbread had on that occasion the powerful support of Fox, who, while not concealing his
misgivings about the Bill, thought the alternative of leaving the great body of the people to depend
on the charity of the rich intolerable, an ominous note was struck by Pitt and Henry Dundas on the
other side. The Bill came up for second reading on 12th February 1796.(63*) Whitbread's opening
speech showed that he was well aware that he would have to face a formidable opposition. Pitt rose
at once after the motion had been formally seconded by one of the Suffolk members, and assailed
the Bill in a speech that made an immediate and overwhelming impression. He challenged
Whitbread's argument that wages had not kept pace with prices; he admitted the hardships of the
poor, but he thought the picture overdrawn, for their hardships had been relieved by 'a display of
beneficence never surpassed at any period,' and he argued that it was a false remedy to use
legislative interference, and to give the justices the power to regUlate the price of labour, and to
endeavour 'to establish by authority what would be much better accomplished by the unassisted
operation of principles.' This led naturally to an attack on the restrictions on labour imposed by the
Law of Settlement, and a discussion of the operation of the Poor Laws, and the speech ended, after
a glance at the great possibilities of child employment, with the promise of measures which should
restore the original purity of the Poor Laws, and make them a blessing instead of the curse they had
become. The speech seems to have dazzled the House of Commons, and few stood up against the
general opinion that Whitbread's proposal was dangerous, and that the whole question had better
be left to Pitt. Lechmere, a Worcestershire member, was one of them, and he made an admirable
little speech in which he tried to destroy the general illusion that the poor could not be unhappy in a
country where the rich were so kind. Whitbread himself defended his Bill with spirit and ability,
showing that Pitt had not really found any substantial argument against it, and that Pitt's own
remedies were all hypothetical and distant. Fox reaffirmed his dislike of compulsion, but restated at
the same time his opinion that Whitbread's Bill, though not an ideal solution, was the best solution
available of evils which pressed very hardly on the poor and demanded attention. General Smith
pointed out that one of Pitt's remedies was the employment of children, and warned him that he had
himself seen some of the consequences of the unregulated labour of children 'whose wan and pale
complexions bespoke that their constitutions were already undermined, and afforded but little
promise of a robust manhood, or of future usefulness to the community.' But the general sense of
the House was reflected in the speeches of Buxton, Coxhead and Burdon, whose main argument
was that the poor were not in so desperate a plight as Whitbread supposed, and that whatever their
condition might be, Pitt was the most likely person to find such remedies as were practicable and
effective. The motion for second reading was negatived without a division. The verdict of the House
was a verdict of confidence in Pitt.
Four years later (11th February 1800) Whitbread repeated his attempt.(64*) He asked for leave to
bring in a Bill to explain and amend the Act of Elizabeth, and said that he had waited for Pitt to carry
out his promises. He was aware of the danger of overpaying the poor, but artificers and labourers
should be so paid as to be able to keep themselves and their families in comfort. He saw no way of
securing this result in a time of distress except the way he had suggested. Pitt rose at once to reply.
He had in the interval brought in and abandoned his scheme of Poor Law Reform. He had spent his
only idea, and he was now confessedly without any policy at all. All that he could contribute was a
general criticism of legislative interference, and another discourse on the importance of letting
labour find its own level. He admitted the fact of scarcity, but he believed the labouring class seldom
felt fewer privations. History scarcely provides a more striking spectacle of a statesman paying
himself with soothing phrases in the midst of a social cyclone. The House was more than ever on
his side. All the interests and instincts of class were disguised under the gold dust of Adam Smith's
philosophy. Sir William Young, Buxton, Wilberforce, Ellison, and Perceval attacked the Bill.
Whitbread replied that charity as a substitute for adequate wages had mischievous effects, for it
took away the independence of the poor, 'a consideration as valuable to the labourer as to the man
of high rank,' and as for the argument that labour should be left to find its own level, the truth surely
was that labour found its level by combinations, and that this had been found to be so great an evil
that Acts of Parliament had been passed against it.
The date of the second reading of the Bill was hotly disputed:(65*) the friends of the measure
wanted it to be fixed for 28th April, so that Quarter Sessions might have time to deliberate on the
proposals; the opponents of the measure suggested 25th February, on the grounds that it was
dangerous to keep the Bill in suspense so long: 'the eyes of all the labouring poor,' said Mr. Ellison,
'must in that interval be turned upon it.' The opponents won their point, and when the Bill came up
for second reading its fate was a foregone conclusion. Whitbread made one last appeal, pleading
the cause of the labourers bound to practical serfdom in parishes where the landowner was an
absentee, employed at starvation wages by farmers, living in cottages let to them by farmers. But
his appeal was unheeded: Lord Belgrave retorted with the argument that legislative interference with
agriculture could not be needed, seeing that five hundred Enclosure Bills had passed the House
during a period of war, and the Bill was rejected.
So died the policy of the minimum wage. Even later it had its adherents, for, in 1805, Sir Thomas
Bernard criticised it(66*) as the 'favourite idea of some very intelligent and benevolent men.' He
mentioned as a reductio ad absurdum of the scheme, that had the rate of wages been fixed by the
standard of 1780 when the quartern loaf was 6d. and the labourer's pay 9s. a week, the result in
1800 when the quartern loaf cost 1s. 9d. would have been a wage of £1, 11s. 6d.
When Whitbread introduced his large and comprehensive Poor Law Bill in 1807,(67*) the proposal
for a minimum wage was not included.
From an examination of the speeches of the time and of the answers to Arthur Young's circular
printed in the Annals of Agriculture, it is evident that there was a genuine fear among the opponents
of the measure that if once wages were raised to meet the rise in prices it would not be easy to
reduce them when the famine was over. This was put candidly by one of Arthur Young's
correspondents: 'it is here judged more prudent to indulge the poor with bread corn at a reduced
price than to raise the price of wages.'(68*)
The policy of a minimum wage was revived later by a society called 'The General Association
established for the Purpose of bettering the Condition of the Agricultural and Manufacturing
Labourers.' Three representatives of this society gave evidence before the Select Committee on
Emigration in 1827, and one of them pointed out as an frustration of the injustice with which the
labourers were treated, that in 1825 the wages of agricultural labourers were generally 9s. a week,
and the price of wheat 9s. a bushel, whereas in 1732 the wages of agricultural labour were fixed by
the magistrates at 6s. a week, and the price of wheat was 2s. 9d. the bushel. In support of this
comparison he produced a table from The Gentleman's Magazine of 1732: --
Wheat in February 1732, 23s. to 25s. per quarter.
Wheat in March 1732, 20s. to 22s. per quarter.
Yearly wages appointed by the Justices to be taken by the servants in the county of Kent, not
exceeding the following sums:
Head ploughman waggoner or seedsman.. £8 0 0
His mate........ 4 0 0
Best woman....... 3 0 0
Second sort of woman..... 2 0 0
Second ploughman...... 6 0 0
His mate........ 3 0 0
Labourers by day in summer.... 1 2
In winter........ 1 0
JUSTICES OF GLOUCESTER
Head servant in husbandry.... 5 0 0
Second servant in husbandry.... 4 0 0
Driving boy under fourteen.... 1 0 0
Head maid servant or dairy servant... 2 10 0
Mower in harvest without drink per day.. 1 2
With drink....... 1 0
Other day labourers with drink.... 1 0
From corn to hay harvest with drink... 0 8
Mowers and reapers in corn harvest with drink. 1 0
Labourers with diet...... 0 4
Without diet or drink..... 0 10
Carpenter wheelwright or mason without drink. 1 2
With drink....... 1 0
One of the witnesses pointed out that there were five millions of labourers making with their families
eight millions, and that if the effect of raising their wages was to increase their expenditure by a
penny a day, there would be an increase of consumption amounting to twelve millions a year. These
arguments made little impression on the Committee, and the representations of the society were
dismissed with contempt: 'It is from an entire ignorance of the universal operation of the principle of
Supply and demand regUlating the rate of wages that all these extravagant propositions are
advanced, and recommendations spread over the country which are so calculated to excite false
hopes, and consequently discontent, in the minds of the labouring classes. Among the most
extravagant are those brought forward by the Society established for the purpose of bettering the
condition of the manufacturing and agricultural labourers.'
POOR LAW REFORM
Pitt, having secured the rejection of Whitbread's Minimum Wage Bill in 1796, produced his own
alternative: Poor Law Reform. It is necessary to state briefly what were the Poor Law arrangements
at the time of his proposals.
The Poor Law system reposed on the great Act of Elizabeth (1601), by which the State had
acknowledged and organised the duty to the poor which it had taken over from the Church. The
parish was constituted the unit, and overseers, unsalaried and nominated by the J.P.'s, were
appointed for administering relief, the necessary funds being obtained by a poor rate. Before 1722 a
candidate for relief could apply either to the overseers or to the magistrate. By an Act passed in that
year, designed to make the administration stricter, application was to be made first to the overseer.
If the overseer rejected the application the claimant could submit his case to a magistrate, and the
magistrate, after hearing the overseer's objection, could order that relief should be given. There
were, however, a number of parishes in which applications for relief were made to salaried
guardians. These were the parishes that had adopted an Act known as Gilbert's Act, passed in
1782.(69*) In these parishes,(70*) joined in incorporations, the parish overseers were not abolished,
for they still had the duty of collecting and accounting for the rates, but the distribution was in the
hands of paid guardians, one for each parish, appointed by the justices out of a list of names
submitted by the parishioners. In each set of incorporated parishes there was a 'Visitor' appointed
by the justices, who had practically absolute power over the guardians. If the guardians refused
relief, the claimant could still appeal, as in the case of the overseers, to the justices.
Such was the parish machinery. The method of giving relief varied greatly, but the main distinction
to be drawn is between (1) out relief, or a weekly pension of a shilling or two at home; and (2) indoor
relief, or relief in a workhouse, or poorhouse, or house of industry. Out relief was the earlier
institution, and it held its own throughout the century, being the only form of relief in many parishes.
Down to 1722 parishes that wished to build a workhouse had to get a special Act of Parliament. In
that year a great impetus was given to the workhouse movement by an Act(71*) which authorised
overseers, with the consent of the vestry, to start workhouses, or to farm out the poor, and also
authorised parishes to join together for this purpose. If applicants for relief refused to go into the
workhouse, they forfeited their title to any relief at all. A great many workhouses were built in
consequence of this Act: in 1732 there were stated to be sixty in the country, and about fifty in the
metropolis.(72*)
Even if the applicant for relief lived in a parish which had built or shared in a workhouse, it did not
follow that he was forced into it. He lost his title to receive relief outside, but his fate would depend
on the parish officers. In the parishes which had adopted Gilbert's Act the workhouse was reserved
for the aged, for the infirm, and for young children. In most parishes there was out relief as well as
indoor relief: in some parishes outdoor relief being allowed to applicants of a certain age or in
special circumstances. In some parishes all outdoor relief had stopped by 1795.(73*) There is no
doubt that in most parishes the workhouse accommodation would have been quite inadequate for
the needs of the parish in times of distress. It was quite common to put four persons into a single
bed.
The workhouses were dreaded by the poor,(74*) not only for the dirt and disease and the
devastating fevers that swept through them,(75*) but for reasons that are intelligible enough to any
one who has read Eden's descriptions. Those descriptions show that Crabbe's picture is no
exaggeration: --
<poem>
'Theirs is yon House that holds the Parish-Poor,
Whose walls of mud scarce bear the broken door.
There, where the putrid vapours, flagging, play,
And the dull wheel hums doleful through the day;
There Children dwell who know no Parents' care;
Parents, who know no Children's love, dwell there!
Heart-broken Matrons on their joyless bed,
Forsaken Wives and Mothers never wed;
Dejected Widows with unheeded tears,
And crippled Age with more than childhood fears;
The Lame, the Blind, and, £ar the happiest they!
The moping idiot and the Madman gay.
Here too the Sick their final doom receive,
Here brought, amid the scenes of grief, to grieve,
Where the loud groans from some sad chamber flow,
Mixt with the clamours of the crowd below;
Here sorrowing, they each kindred sorrow scan,
And the cold charities of man to man:
Whose laws indeed for ruin'd Age provide,
And strong compulsion plucks the scrap from pride;
But still that scrap is bought with many a sigh,
And pride embitters what it can't deny.'(76*)
<poem>
A good example of this mixture of young and old, virtuous and vicious, whole and sick, sane and
mad, is given in Eden's catalogue of the inmates of Epsom Workhouse in January 1796.(77*) There
were eleven men, sixteen women, and twenty-three children. We read of J. H., aged forty-three,
'always... somewhat of an idiot, he is now become quite a driveller;' of E. E., aged sixty-two, 'of a
sluggish, stupid character;' of A. M., aged twenty-six, 'afflicted with a leprosy;' of R. M., aged
seventy-seven, 'worn out and paralytic;' of J. R., aged seventeen, who has contracted so many
disorderly habits that decent people will not employ him. It is interesting to notice that it was not till
1790 that the Justices of the Peace were given any power of inspecting workhouses.
In 1796, before Pitt's scheme was brought in, the Act of 1722, which had been introduced to stiffen
the administration of the Poor Laws, was relaxed. An Act,(78*) of which Sir William Young was the
author, abolished the restriction of right to relief to persons willing to enter the workhouse, and
provided that claimants could apply for relief directly to a magistrate. The Act declares that the
restrictions had been found 'inconvenient and oppressive.' It is evidence, of course, of the increasing
pressure of poverty.
But to understand the arrangements in force at this time, and also the later developments, we must
glance at another feature of the Poor Law system. The Poor Laws were a system of employment as
well as a system of relief. The Acts before 1722 are all called Acts for the Relief of the Poor: the Act
of 1722 speaks of 'the Settlement, Employment and Relief.' That Act empowered parishes to farm
out the poor to an employer. Gilbert's Act of 1782 provided that in the parishes incorporated under
that Act the guardians were not to send able-bodied poor to the poorhouse, but to find work for them
or maintain them until work was found: the guardian was to take the wage and provide the labourer
with a maintenance. Thus there grew up a variety of systems of public employment: direct
employment of paupers on parish work: the labour rate system, or the sharing out of the paupers
among the ratepayers: the roundsman system by which pauper labour was sold to the farmers.(79*)
This was the state of things that Pitt proposed to reform. His general ideas on the subject were put
before the House of Commons in the debate on the second reading of Whitbread's Bill.(80*) He
thought that persons with large families should be treated as entitled to relief, that persons without a
settlement, falling into want, should not be liable to removal at the caprice of the parish officer, that
Friendly Societies should be encouraged, and that Schools of Industry should be established. 'If any
one would take the trouble to compute the amount of all the earnings of the children who are
already educated in this manner, he would be surprised, when he came to consider the weight
which their support by their own labours took off the country, and the addition which, by the fruits of
their toil, and the habits to which they were formed, was made to its internal opulence.' On 22nd
december of that year, in a new Parliament, he asked for leave to bring in a Bill for the better
Support and Maintenance of the Poor. He said the subject was too extensive to be discussed at that
stage, that he only proposed that the Bill should be read a first and second time and sent to a
committee where the blanks could be filled up, and the Bill printed before the holidays, 'in order that
during the interval of Parliament it might be circulated in the country and undergo the most serious
investigation.'(81*) Sheridan hinted that it was unfortunate for the poor that Pitt had taken the
question out of Whitbread's hands, to which Pitt replied that any delay in bringing forward his Bill
was due to the time spent on taking advice. On 28th February of the next year (1797), while
strangers were excluded from the Gallery, there occurred what the Parliamentary Register calls 'a
conversation upon the farther consideration of the report of the Poor's Bill,' in which nobody but Pitt
defended the Bill, and Sheridan and Joliffe attacked it. With this its Parliamentary history ends.
The main features of the Bill were these.(82*) Schools of Industry were to be established in every
parish or group of parishes. These schools were to serve two purposes. First, the young were to be
trained there (this idea came, of course, from Locke). Every poor man with more than two children
who were not self-supporting, and every widow with more than one such child, was to be entitled to
a weekly allowance in respect of each extra child. Every allowance child who was five years or over
was to be sent to the School of Industry, unless his parent could instruct and employ him, and the
proceeds of his work was to go towards the upkeep of the school. Secondly, grown-up people were
to be employed there. The authorities were to provide 'a proper stock of hemp, flax, silk, cotton,
wool, iron, leather or other materials, and also proper tools and implements for the employment of
the poor,' and they were empowered to carry on all trades under this Act, 'any law or custom to the
contrary notwithstanding.' Any person lawfully settled in a parish was entitled to be employed in the
school; any person residing in a parish, able and willing to be employed at the usual rates, was
entitled to be employed there when out of work. Poor persons refusing to be employed there were
not to be entitled to relief. The authorities might either pay wages at a rate fixed by the magistrates,
or they might let the employed sell their products and merely repay the school for the material, or
they might contract to feed them and take a proportion of their receipts. If the wages paid in the
school were insufficient, they were to be supplemented out of the rates.
The proposals for outside relief were briefly and chiefly these. A person unable to earn the full rate
of wages usually given might contract with his employer to work at an inferior rate, and have the
balance between his earnings and an adequate maintenance made up by the parish. Money might
be advanced under certain circumstances for the purchase of a cow or other animal, if it seemed
likely that such a course would enable the recipient to maintain himself without the help of the
parish. The possession of property up to thirty pounds was not to disqualify a person for relief. A
parochial insurance fund was to be created, partly from private subscriptions and partly from the
rates. No person was to be removed from a parish on account of relief for temporary disability or
sickness.
The most celebrated and deadly criticism came from Bentham, who is often supposed to have killed
the Bill. Some of his objections are captious and eristical, and he is a good deal less than just to the
good elements of the scheme. Pitt deserves credit for one statesmanlike discovery, the discovery
that it is bad policy to refuse to help a man until he is ruined. His cow-money proposal was also
conceived in the right spirit if its form was impracticable. But the scheme as a whole was confused
and incoherent, and it deserved the treatment it received. It was in truth a huge patchwork, on which
the ideas of living and dead reformers were thrown together without order or plan. As a
consequence, its various parts did not agree. It is surprising that the politician who had attacked
Whitbread's Bill as an interference with wages could have included in his scheme the proposal to
pay wages in part out of rates. The whole scheme, though it would have involved a great
expenditure, would have produced very much the same result as the Speenhamland system, by
virtue of this clause. Pitt showed no more judgment or foresight than the least enlightened of County
Justices in introducing into a scheme for prodding relief, and dealing with unemployment, a proposal
that could only have the effect of reducing wages. The organisation of Schools of Industry as a
means of dealing with unemployment has sometimes been represented as quite a new proposal,
but it was probably based on the suggestion made by Fielding in 1753 in his paper, 'A proposal for
making an effectual provision for the poor, for amending their morals, and for rendering them useful
members of society.' Fielding proposed the erection of a county workhouse, which was to include a
house of correction. He drew up a sharp and drastic code which would have authorised the
committal to his County House, not only of vagrants, but of persons of low degree found harbouring
in an ale-house after ten o'clock at night. But the workhouse was not merely to be used as a penal
settlement, it was to find work for the unemployed. Any person who was unable to find employment
in his parish could apply to the minister or churchwardens for a pass, and this pass was to give him
the right to claim admission to the County House where he was to be employed. The County House
was also to be prodded with instructors who could teach native and foreign manufactures to the
inmates. Howlett, one of Pitt's critics, was probably right in thinking that Pitt was reviving this
scheme.
The Bill excited general opposition. Bentham's analysis is the most famous of the criticisms that
have survived, but in some senses his opposition was less serious than the dismay of magistrates
and ratepayers. Hostile petitions poured into the House of Commons from London and from all parts
of the country; among others there were petitions from Shrewsbury, Oswestry, Worcester, Bristol,
Lincoln, Carmarthen, Bedford, Chester and Godalming.(83*) Howlett attacked the scheme on the
ground of the danger of parish robbery and corruption. Pitt apparently made no attempt to defend
his plan, and he surrendered it without a murmur. We are thus left in the curious and disappointing
position of having before us a Bill on the most important subject of the day, introduced and
abandoned by the Prime Minister without a word or syllable in its defence. Whitbread observed(84*)
four years later that the Bill was brought in and printed, but never brought under the discussion of
the House. Pitt's excuse is significant: 'He was, as formerly, convinced of its propriety; but many
objections had been started to it by those whose opinion he was bound to respect. Inexperienced
himself in country affairs, and in the condition of the poor, he was diffident of his own opinion, and
would not press the measure upon the attention of the House.'
Poor Law Reform was thus abandoned, but two attempts were made, at the instance of Pitt, one of
them with success, to soften the brutalities of the Law of Settlement. Neither proposal made it any
easier to gain a settlement, and Pitt very properly declared that they did not go nearly far enough.
Pitt had all Adam Smith's just hatred of these restrictions, and in opposing Whitbread's Bill for a
minimum wage he pointed to 'a radical amendment' of the Law of Settlement as the true remedy. He
was not the formal author of the Act of 1795, but it may safely be assumed that he was the chief
power behind it. This Act(85*) provided that nobody was to be removeable until he or she became
actually chargeable to the parish. The preamble throws light on the working of the Settlement laws.
It declares that 'Many industrious poor persons, chargeable to the parish, township, or place where
they live, merely from want of work there, would in any other place where sufficient employment is to
be had, maintain themselves and families without being burthensome to any parish, township, or
place; and such poor persons are for the most part compelled to live in their own parishes,
townships, or places, and are not permitted to inhabit elsewhere, under pretence that they are likely
to become chargeable to the parish, township, or place into which they go for the purpose of getting
employment, although the labour of such poor persons might, in many instances, be very beneficial
to such parish, township, or place.' The granting of certificates is thus admitted to have been
ineffectual. The same Act provided that orders of removal were to be suspended in cases where the
pauper was dangerously ill, a provision that throws some light on the manner in which these orders
had been executed, and that no person should gain a settlement by paying levies or taxes, in
respect of any tenement of a yearly value of less than ten pounds.(86*)
From this time certificates were unnecessary, and if a labourer moved from Parish A to Parish B he
was no longer liable to be sent back at the caprice of Parish B's officers until he became actually
chargeable, but, of course, if from any cause he fell into temporary distress, for example, if he were
out of work for a few weeks, unless he could get private aid from 'the opulent,' he had to return to his
old parish. An attempt was made to remedy this state of things by Mr. Baker who, in March 1800,
introduced a Bill(87*) to enable overseers to assist the deserving but unsettled poor in cases of
temporary distress. He explained that the provisions of the Bill would apply only to men who could
usually keep themselves, but from the high cost of provisions had to depend on parochial aid. He
found a powerful supporter in Pitt, who argued that if people had enriched a parish with their
industry, it was unfair that owing to temporary pressure they should be removed to a place where
they were not wanted, and that it was better for a parish to suffer temporary inconvenience than for
numbers of industrious men to be rendered unhappy and useless. But in spite of Pitt's
unanswerable case, the Bill, which was denounced by Mr. Buxton as oppressive to the landed
interest, by Lord Sheffield as 'subversive of the whole economy of the country,' by Mr. Ellison as
submerging the middle ranks, and by Sir William Pulteney as being a 'premium for idleness and
extravagance,' was rejected by thirty votes to twenty-three.(88*)
ALLOTMENTS.
Another policy that was pressed upon the governing class was the policy of restoring to the labourer
some of the resources he had lost with enclosure, of putting him in such a position that he was not
obliged to depend entirely on the purchasing power of his wages at the shop. This was the aim of
the allotment movement. The propaganda failed, but it did not fail for the want of vigorous and
authoritative support. We have seen in a previous chapter that Arthur Young awoke in 1801 to the
social mischief of depriving the poor of their land and their cows, and that he wanted future
Enclosure Acts to be juster and more humane. Cobbett suggested a large scheme of agrarian
settlement to Windham in 1806. These proposals had been anticipated by Davies, whose
knowledge of the actual life of the poor made him understand the important difference between a
total and a partial dependence on wages. 'Hope is a cordial, of which the poor man has especially
much need, to cheer his heart in the toilsome journey through life. And the fatal consequence of that
policy, which deprives labouring people of the expectation of possessing any property in the soil,
must be the extinction of every generous principle in their minds.... No gentleman should be
permitted to pull down a cottage, until he had first erected another, upon one of Mr. Kent's plans,
either on some convenient part of the waste, or on his own estate, with a certain quantity of land
annexed.' He praised the Act of Elizabeth which forbade the erection of cottages with less than four
acres of land around them, 'that poor people might secure for themselves a maintenance, and not
be obliged on the loss of a few days labour to come to the parish,'(89*) and urged that this
prohibition, which had been repealed in 1775,(90*) should be set up again.
The general policy of providing allotments was never tried, but we know something of individual
experiments from the Reports of the Society for Bettering the Condition and Increasing the Comforts
of the Poor. This society took up the cause of allotments very zealously, and most of the examples
of private benevolence seem to have found their way into the pages of its reports.
These experiments were not very numerous. Indeed, the name of Lord Winchilsea recurs so
inevitably in every allusion to the subject as to create a suspicion that the movement and his estates
were coextensive. This is not the truth, but it is not very wide of the truth, for though Lord Winchilsea
had imitators, those imitators were few. The fullest account of his estate in Rutlandshire is given by
Sir Thomas Bernard.(91*) The estate embraced four parishes Hambledon, Egleton, Greetham, and
Burley on the Hill. The tenants included eighty cottagers possessing one hundred and seventy-four
cows. 'About a third part have all their land in severalty; the rest of them have the use of a cow-
pasture in common with others; most of them possessing a small homestead, adjoining to their
cottage; every one of them having a good garden, and keeping one pig at least, if not more.... Of all
the rents of the estate, none are more punctually paid than those for the cottagers' land.' In this
happy district if a man seemed likely to become a burden on the parish his landlord and neighbours
saved the man's self-respect and their own pockets as ratepayers, by setting him up with land and a
cow instead. So far from neglecting their work as labourers, these proprietors of cows are described
as 'most steady and trusty.' We have a picture of this little community leading a hard but energetic
and independent life, the men going out to daily work, but busy in their spare hours with their cows,
sheep, pigs, and gardens; the women and children looking after the live stock, spinning, or working
in the gardens: a very different picture from that of the landless and ill-fed labourers elsewhere.
Other landlords, who, acting on their own initiative, or at the instance of their agents, helped their
cottagers by letting them land on which to keep cows were Lord Carrington and Lord Scarborough in
Lincolnshire, and Lord Egremont on his Yorkshire estates (Kent was his agent). Some who were
friendly to the allotments movement thought it a mistake to give allotments of arable land in districts
where pasture land was not available. Mr. Thompson, who writes the account of Lord Carrington's
cottagers with cows, thought that 'where cottagers occupy arable land, it is very rarely of advantage
to them, and generally a prejudice to the estate.'(92*) He seems, however, to have been thinking
more of small holdings than of allotments. 'The late Abel Smith, Esq., from motives of kindness to
several cottagers on his estates in Nottinghamshire, let to each of them a small piece of arable land.
I have rode over that estate with Lord Carrington several times since it descended to him, and I have
invariably observed that the tenants upon it, who occupy only eight or ten acres of arable land, are
poor, and their land in bad condition. They would thrive more and enjoy greater comfort with the
means of keeping two or three cows each than with three times their present quantity of arable land;
but it would be a greater mortification to them to be deprived of it than their landlord is disposed to
inflict.'(93*) On the other hand, a striking instance of successful arable allotments is described by a
Mr. Estcourt in the Reports of the Society for Bettering the Condition of the Poor.(94*) The scene
was the parish of Long Newnton in Wilts, which contained one hundred and forty poor persons,
chiefly agricultural labourers, distributed in thirty-two families, and the year was 1800. The price of
provisions was very high, and 'though all had a very liberal allowance from the poor rate, the whole
village was plunged in debt and misery. From this hopeless plight the parish was rescued by an
allotment scheme that Mr. Estcourt established and described. Each cottager who applied was
allowed to rent a small quantity of land at the rate of £1, 12s. an acre(95*) on a fourteen years'
lease: the quantity of land let to an applicant depended on the number in his family, with a maximum
of one and a half acres: the tenant was to forfeit his holding if he received poor relief other than
medical relief. The offer was greedily accepted, two widows with large families and four very old and
infirm persons being the only persons who did not apply for a lease. A loan of £44 was divided
among the tenants to free them from their debts and give them a fresh start. They were allowed a
third of their plot on Lady Day 1801, a second third on Lady Day 1802, and the remainder on Lady
Day 1803. The results as recorded in 1805 were astonishing. None of the tenants had received any
poor relief: all the conditions had been observed: the loan of £44 had long been repaid and the poor
rate had fallen from £212, 16s. to £12, 6s. 'They are so much beforehand with the world that it is
supposed that it must be some calamity still more severe than any they have ever been afflicted with
that could put them under the necessity of ever applying for relief to the parish again.... The farmers
of this parish allow that they never had their work better done, their servants more able, willing, civil,
and sober, and that their property was never so free from depredation as at present.'(96*)
Some philanthropists, full of the advantages to the poor of possessing live-stock, argued that it was
a good thing for cottagers to keep cows even in arable districts. Sir Henry Vavasour wrote an
account in 1801(97*) of one of his cottagers who managed to keep two cows and two pigs and
make a profit of £30 a year on three acres three perches of arable with a summer's gait for one of
his cows. The man, his wife, and his daughter of twelve worked on the land in their spare hours. The
Board of Agriculture offered gold medals in 1801 for the best report of how to keep one or two cows
on arable land, and Sir John Sinclair wrote an essay on the subject, reproduced in the account of
'Useful Projects' in the Annual Register.(98*) Sir John Sinclair urged that if the system was generally
adopted it would remove the popular objections to enclosure.
Other advocates of the policy of giving the labourers land pleaded only for gardens in arable
districts; 'a garden,' wrote Lord Winchilsea, 'may be allotted to them in almost every situation, and
will be found of infinite use to them. In countries, where it has never been the custom for labourers
to keep cows, it may be difficult to introduce it; but where no gardens have been annexed to the
cottages, it is sufficient to give the ground, and the labourer is sure to know what to do with it, and
will reap an immediate benefit from it. Of this I have had experience in several places, particularly in
two parishes near Newport Pagnell, Bucks, where there never have been any gardens annexed to
the labourers' houses, and where, upon land being allotted to them, they all, without a single
exception, have cultivated their gardens extremely well, and profess receiving the greatest benefits
from them.'(99*) 'A few roods of land, at a fair rent,' wrote a correspondent in the Annals of
Agriculture in 1796,(100*) 'would do a labourer as much good as wages almost doubled: there
would not, then, be an idle hand in his family, and the man himself would often go to work in his root
yard instead of going to the ale house.'(101*) The interesting report on the 'Inquiry into the General
State of the Poor' presented at the Epiphany General Quarter Sessions for Hampshire and
published in the Annals of Agriculture,(102*) a document which does not display too much
indulgence to the shortcomings of labourers, recommends the multiplication of cottages with small
pieces of ground annexed, so that labourers might live nearer their work, and spend the time often
wasted in going to and from their work, in cultivating their plot of ground at home. 'As it is chiefly this
practice which renders even the state of slavery in the West Indies tolerable, what an advantage
would it be to the state of free service here!'(103*)
The experiments in the provision of allotments of any kind were few, and they are chiefly interesting
for the light they reflect on the character of the labourer of the period. They show of what those men
and women were capable whose degradation in the morass of the Speenhamland system is the last
and blackest page in the history of the eighteenth century. Their rulers put a stone round their
necks, and it was not their character but their circumstances that dragged them into the mire. In
villages where allotments were tried the agricultural labourer is an upright and self-respecting figure.
The immediate moral effects were visible enough at the time. Sir Thomas Bernard's account of the
cottagers on Lord Winchilsea's estate contains the following reflections: 'I do not mean to assert that
the English cottager, narrowed as he now is in the means and habits of life, may be immediately
capable of taking that active and useful station in society, that is filled by those who are the subject
of this paper. To produce so great an improvement in character and circumstances of life, will
require time and attention. The cottager, however, of this part of the county of Rutland, is not of a
different species from other English cottagers; and if he had not been protected and encouraged by
his landlord, he would have been the same hopeless and comfortless creature that we see in some
other parts of England. The farmer (with the assistance of the steward) would have taken his land;
the creditor, his cow and pig; and the workhouse, his family.'(104*)
We have seen, in discussing enclosures, that the policy of securing allotments to the labourers in
enclosure Acts was defeated by the class interests of the landlords. Why, it may be asked, were
schemes such as those of Lord Winchilsea's adopted so rarely in villages already enclosed? These
arrangements benefited all parties. There was no doubt about the demand; 'in the greatest part of
this kingdom,' wrote one correspondent, 'the cottager would rejoice at being permitted to pay the
utmost value given by the farmers, for as much land as would keep a cow, if he could obtain it at
that price.'(105*) The steadiness and industry of the labourers, stimulated by this incentive, were an
advantage both to the landlords and to the farmers. Further. it was well known that in the villages
where the labourers had land, poor rates were light.(106*) Why was it that a policy with so many
recommendations never took root? Perhaps the best answer is given in the following story. Cobbett
proposed to the vestry of Bishops Walthams that they should 'ask the Bishop of Winchester to grant
an acre of waste land to every married labourer. All, however, but the village schoolmaster voted
against it, on the ground... that it would make the men "too saucy," that they would "breed more
children" and "want higher wages."'(107*)
The truth is that enclosures and the new system of farming had set up two classes in antagonism to
allotments, the large farmer, who disliked saucy labourers, and the shopkeeper, who knew that the
more food the labourer raised on his little estate the less would he buy at the village store. It had
been to the interest of a small farmer in the old common-field village to have a number of semi-
labourers, semi-owners who could help at the harvest: the large farmer wanted a permanent supply
of labour which was absolutely at his command. Moreover, the roundsman system maintained his
labourers for him when he did not want them. The strength of the hostility of the farmers to
allotments is seen in the language of those few landlords who were interested in this policy. Lord
Winchilsea and his friends were always urging philanthropists to proceed with caution, and to try to
reason the farmers out of their prejudices. The Report of the Poor Law Commission in 1834 showed
that these prejudices were as strong as ever. 'We can do little or nothing to prevent pauperism; the
farmers will have it: they prefer that the labourers should be slaves; they object to their having
gardens, saying 'The more they work for themselves, the less they work for us.'(108*) This was the
view of Boys, the writer in agricultural subjects, who, criticising Kent's declaration in favour of
allotments, remarks: 'If farmers in general were to accommodate their labourers with two acres of
land, a cow and two or three pigs, they would probably have more difficulty in getting their hard work
done -- as the cow, land, etc., would enable them to live with less earnings.'(109*) Arthur Young and
Nathaniel Kent made a great appeal to landlords and to landlords' wives to interest themselves in
their estates and the people who lived on them, but landlords' bailiffs did not like the trouble of
collecting a number of small rents, and most landlords preferred to leave their labourers to the
mercy of the farmers. There was, however, one form of allotment that the farmers themselves liked:
they would let strips of potato ground to labourers, sometimes at four times the rent they paid
themselves, getting the land manured and dug into the bargain.(110*)
The Select Vestry Act of 1819(111*) empowered parishes to buy or lease twenty acres of land, and
to set the indigent poor to work on it, or to lease it out to any poor and industrious inhabitant. A later
Act of 1831(112*) raised the limit from twenty to fifty acres, and empowered parishes to enclose fifty
acres of waste (with the consent of those who had rights on it ) and to lease it out for the same
purposes. Little use was made of these Acts, and perhaps the clearest light is thrown on the extent
of the allotment movement by a significant sentence that occurs in the Report of the Select
Committee on Allotments in 1843. 'It was not until 1830, when discontent had been so painfully
exhibited amongst the peasantry of the southern counties that this method of alleviating their
situation was much resorted to.' In other words, little was done till labourers desperate with hunger
had set the farmers' ricks blazing.
THE REMEDY ADOPTED. SPEENHAMLAND
The history has now been given of the several proposals made at this time that for one reason or
another fell to the ground. A minimum wage was not fixed, allotments were only sprinkled with a
sparing hand on an estate here and there, there was no revolution in diet, the problems of local
supply and distribution were left untouched, the reconstruction of the Poor Law was abandoned.
What means then did the governing class take to tranquillise a population made dangerous by
hunger? The answer is, of course, the Speenhamland Act. The Bcrkshire J.P.'s and some discreet
persons met at the Pelican Inn at Speenhamland(113*) on 6th May 1795, and there resolved on a
momentous policy which was gradually adopted in almost every part of England.
There is a strange irony in the story of this meeting which gave such a fatal impetus to the reduction
of wages. It was summoned in order to raise wages, and so make the labourer independent of
parish relief. At the General Quarter Sessions for Berkshire held at Newbury on the 14th April,
Charles Dundas, M.P.,(114*) in his charge to the Grand Jury(115*) dwelt on the miserable state of
the labourers and the necessity of increasing their wages to subsistence level, instead of leaving
them to resort to the parish officers for support for their families, as was the case when they worked
for a shilling a day. He quoted the Acts of Elizabeth and James with reference to the fixing of wages.
The Court, impressed by his speech, decided to convene a meeting for the rating of wages. The
advertisement of the meeting shows that this was the only object in view. 'At the General Quarter
Sessions of the Peace for this county held at Newbury, on Tuesday, the 14th instant, the Court,
having taken into consideration the great Inequality of Labourers' Wages, and the insufficiency of
the same for the necessary support of an industrious man and his family; and it being the opinion of
the Gentlemen assembled on the Grand Jury, that many parishes have not advanced their
labourers' weekly pay in proportion to the high price of corn and provisions, do (in pursuance of the
Acts of Parliament, enabling and requiring them so to do, either at the Easter Sessions, yearly, or
within six weeks next after) earnestly request the attendance of the Sheriff, and all the Magistrates
of this County, at a Meeting intended to be held at the Pelican Inn in Speenhamland, on
Wednesday, the sixth day of May next, at ten o'clock in the forenoon, for the purpose of consulting
together with such discreet persons as they shall think meet, and they will then, having respect to
the plenty and scarcity of the time, and other circumstances (if approved of) proceed to limit, direct,
and appoint the wages of day labourers.'(116*)
The meeting was duly held on 6th May.(117*) Mr. Charles Dundas was in the chair, and there were
seventeen other magistrates and discreet persons present, of whom seven were clergymen. It was
resolved unanimously 'that the present state of the poor does require further assistance than has
been generally given them.' Of the details of the discussion no records have come down to us, nor
do we know by what majority the second and fatal resolution rejecting the rating of wages and
substituting an allowance policy was adopted. According to Eden, the arguments in favour of
adopting the rating of wages were 'that by enforcing a payment for labour, from the employers, in
proportion to the price of bread, some encouragement would have been held out to the labourer, as
what he would have received, would have been payment for labour. He would have considered it as
his right, and not as charity.'(118*) But these arguments were rejected, and a pious
recommendation to employers to raise wages, coupled with detailed directions for supplementing
those wages from parish funds, adopted instead.(119*) The text of the second resolution runs thus:
'Resolved, that it is not expedient for the Magistrates to grant that assistance by regulating the
wages of day Labourers according to the directions of the Statutes of the 5th Elizabeth and 1st
James: But the Magistrates very earnestly recommend to the Farmers and others throughout the
county to increase the Pay of their Labourers in proportion to the present Price of Provisions; and
agreeable thereto the Magistrates now present have unanimously Resolved, That they will in their
several divisions, make the following calculations and allowances for the relief of all poor and
industrious men and their families, who, to the satisfaction of the Justices of their parish, shall
endeavour (as far as they can), for their own support and maintenance, that is to say, when the
gallon loaf of second flour, weighing 8 lbs. 11 oz. shall cost one shilling, then every poor and
industrious man shill have for his own support 3s. weekly, either produced by his own or his family's
labour or an allowance from the poor rates, and for the support of his wife and every other of his
family 1s. 6d. When the gallon loaf shall cost ls. 4d., then every poor and industrious man shall have
4s. weekly for his own, and 1s. 10d: for the support of every other of his family.
'And so in proportion as the price of bread rises or falls (that is to say), 3d. to the man and 1d. to
every other of the family, on every penny which the loaf rises above a shilling.'
In other words, it was estimated that the man must have three gallon loaves a week, and his wife
and each child one and a half.
It is interesting to notice that at this same famous Speenhamland meeting the justices 'wishing, as
much as possible, to alleviate the distresses of the Poor with as little burthen on the occupiers of the
Land as possible' recommended overseers to cultivate land for potatoes and to give the workers a
quarter of the crop, selling the rest at one shilling a bushel; overseers were also recommended to
purchase fuel and to retail it at a loss.
The Speenhamland policy was not a full-blown invention of that unhappy May morning in the
Pelican Inn. The principle had already been adopted elsewhere. At the Oxford quarter Sessions on
13th January 1795, the justices had resolved that the following incomes were 'absolutely necessary
for the support of the poor, industrious labourer, and that when the utmost industry of a family
cannot produce the undermentioned sums, it must be made up by the overseer, exclusive of rent,
viz.: --
'A single Man according to his labour.
'A Man and his Wife not less than 6s. a week.
'A Man and his Wife with one or two Small Children, not less than 7s. a week.
'And for every additional Child not less than 1s. a week.' This regulation was to be sent to all
overseers within the county.(120*)
But the Speenhamland magistrates had drawn up a table which became a convenient standard, and
other magistrates found it the simplest course to accept the table as it stood. The tables passed
rapidly from county to county. The allowance system spread like a fever, for while it is true to say
that the northern counties took it much later and in a milder form, there were only two counties still
free from it in 1834 -- Northumberland and Durham.
To complete our picture of the new system we must remember the results of Gilbert's Act. It had
been the practice in those parishes that adopted the Act to reserve the workhouse for the infirm and
to find work outside for the unemployed, the parish receiving the wages of such employment and
providing maintenance. This outside employment had spread to other parishes, and the way in
which it had been worked may be illustrated by cases mentioned by Eden, writing in the summer
and autumn of 1795. At Kibworth-Beauchamp in Leicestershire, 'in the winter, and at other times,
when a man is out of work, he applies to the overseer, who sends him from house to house to get
employ: the housekeeper, who employs him, is obliged to give him victuals, and 6d.; a day and the
parish adds 4d.; (total 10d. a day;) for the support of his family: persons working in this manner are
called rounds-men, from their going round the village or township for employ.'(121*) At Yardley
Goben, in Northamptonshire, every person who paid more than £20 rent was bound in his turn to
employ a man for a day and to pay him a shilling.(122*) At Maids Morton the roundsman got 6d.
from the employer and 6d. or 9d. from the parish.(123*) At Winslow in Bucks the system was more
fully developed. 'There seems to be here a great want of employment: most labourers are (as it is
termed,) on the Rounds; that is, they go to work from one house to another round the parish. In
winter, sometimes 40 persons are on the rounds. They are wholly paid by the parish, unless the
householders choose to employ them; and from these circumstances, labourers often become very
lazy, and imperious. Children, about ten years old, are put on the rounds, and receive from the
parish from 1s. 6d. to 3s. a week.'(124*) The Speenhamland systematised scale was easily grafted
on to these arrangements. 'During the late dear season, the Poor of the parish went in a body to the
Justices, to complain of their want of bread. The Magistrates sent orders to the parish officers to
raise the earnings of labourers, to certain weekly sums, according to the number of their children; a
circumstance that should invariably be attended to in apportioning parochial relief. These sums were
from 7s. to 19s.; and were to be reduced, proportionably with the price of bread.'(125*)
The Speenhamland system did not then spring Athene-like out of the heads of the justices and other
discreet persons whose place of meeting has given the system its name. Neither was the
unemployment policy thereafter adopted a sudden inspiration of the Parliament of 1796. The
importance of these years is that though the governing classes did not then introduce a new
principle, they applied to the normal case methods of relief and treatment that had hitherto been
reserved for the exceptions. The Poor Law which had once been the hospital became now the
prison of the poor. Designed to relieve his necessities, it was now his bondage. If a labourer was in
private employment, the difference between the wage his master chose to give him and the
recognised minimum was made up by the parish. Those labourers who could not find private
employment were either shared out among the ratepayers, or else their labour was sold by the
parish to employers, at a low rate, the parish contributing what was needed to bring the labourers'
receipts up to scale. Crabbe has described the roundsman system:
</poem>
'Alternate Masters now their Slave command,
Urge the weak efforts of his feeble hand,
And when his age attempts its task in vain,
With ruthless taunts, of lazy poor complain.'(126*)
</poem>
The meshes of the Poor Law were spread over the entire labour system. The labourers, stripped of
their ancient rights and their ancient possessions, refused a minimum wage and allotments, were
given instead a universal system of pauperism. This was the basis on which the governing class
rebuilt the English village. Many critics, Arthur Young and Malthus among them, assailed it, but it
endured for forty years, and it was not disestablished until Parliament itself had passed through a
revolution.
NOTES:
1. Eden, vol. i, p. 495.
2. Resolution of Privy Council, July 6, 1795, and Debate and Resolution in House of Commons.
Parliamentary Register, December 11, 1795, and Lord Sheffield in Annuals of Agriculture, vol. xxv,
p. 31.
3. See Senator for March 1, 1796, p. 1147.
4. See Wilberforce's speech, Parliamentary Register and Senator, February 18, 1800.
5. Eden, vol. ii, pp. 104-6.
6. Ibid., p. 15.
7. Ibid., p. 280.
8. Ibid., p. 426.
9. See Annals of Agriculture, vol. xxiv, pp. 63, 171, 177, 204, 285, 316, etc.
10. Annals of Agriculture, vol. xxv, p. 678.
11. Eden, vol. i, p. 533.
12. Perhaps the unpopularity of soup is partly explained by a letter published in the Annals of
Agriculture in December 1795, vol. xxvi, p. 215. The writer says it is the custom for most families in
the country 'to give their poor neighbours the pot liquor, that is, the liquour in which any meat has
been boiled, and to which they sometimes add the broken bread from the parlour and kitchen
tables: this,' he adds, 'makes but an indifferent mess.' The publications of the time contain
numerous recipes for cheap soups; 'the power of giving an increased effect to Christian
benevolence by these soups' (Reports on Poor, vol i, p. 167) was eagerly welcomed. Cf. Mrs
Shore's account of stewed ox's head for the poor, according to which, at the cost of 2s. 6d. with the
leavings of the family, a savoury mess for fifty-two persons could be prepared (Ibid., p. 60).
13. Davies, pp. 31-2.
14. Annals of Agriculture, vol. xxv, p. 455.
15. Parliamentary Register, November 2, 1795.
16. Eden, vol. iii, p. 769.
17. Ibid, vol. ii, p. 97.
18. Ibid, p. 621.
19. Ibid., p. 645.
20. In many budgets no milk is included.
21. Reports on Poor, vol. iv, p. 151.
22. Davies, p. 104.
23. Reports on Poor, vol. ii, p. 178.
24. Vol. ii, p. 587.
25. Reports on Poor, vol. i, p. 134; another reason for the dearth of milk was the growing
consumption of veal in the towns. Davies says (p. 19). 'Suckling is here so profitable (to furnish veal
for London) that the poor can seldom either buy or beg milk.'
26. p. 27.
27. See Annals of Agriculture, vol. xxv, pp. 367-8.
28. Davies, p. 37.
29. Ibid., p. 39.
30. Annals of Agriculture, vol. xxvi, p. 121.
31. The dearness of malt was another fact which helped the introduction of tea. Cf. Davies, p. 38:
'Time was when small beer was reckoned one of the necessaries of life, even in poor families.'
32. Lecky, History of England in Eighteenth Century, vol. ii, p. 318.
33. In connection with the dearth of milk it is important to notice the rise in the price of cheese. 'Poor
people,' says Davies (p. 19), 'reckon cheese the dearest article they can use' (cf. also p. 143), and in
his comparison of prices in the middle of the eighteenth century with those of 1787-94 he gives the
price of 112 lbs. of cheese at Reading Fair as from 17s. to 21s. in the first period, and 40s. to 46s. in
the second. Retail cheese of an inferior sort had risen from 2 1/2 d. or 3d. a lb. to 4 1/2 d. or 5d. (p.
65); cf. also correspondent in Annals of Agriculture, vol. ii, p. 442. 'Every inhabitant of Bath must be
sensible that butter and cheese have risen in price one-third, or more, within these twenty years.'
(Written in 1784).
34. Reports on Poor, vol. i, p. 129.
35. Ibid., vol. iii, p. 78.
36. Annual Register, 1806, p. 974; 'My local situation afforded me ample means of knowing how
greatly the lower orders suffered from being unable to procure a supply of milk; and I am fully
persuaded of the correctness of the statement that the labouring poor lose a number of their
children from the want of food so pre-eminently adapted to the their support;' cf. also Curwen's
Hints.
37. Eden, vol. i, p. 510.
38. Vol. iii, p. 96.
39. Eden, vol. iii, p. 694.
40. Cf., Reports on Poor, vol. i, p. 43; 'Where there are commons, the ideal advantage of cutting
flags, peat, or whins, often causes a poor man to spend more time in procuring such fuel, than, if he
reckoned his labour, would purchase for him double the quantity of good firing.'
41. Vol. iv, p. 496.
42. Vol. ii, p. 587.
43. Davies, p. 28.
44. Ibid., p. 118.
45. Eden, vol. iii, p. 805.
46. p. 179.
47. Cf. also Eden's description of a labourer's expenses, vol. iii, p. 797, where he says that whilst
hedging and ditching, they are allowed to take home a faggot every evening, whilst the work lasts,
'but this is by no means sufficient for his consumption; his children, therefore, are sent into the
fields, to collect wood where they can; and neither hedges nor trees are spared by the young
marauders, who are thus, in some degree, educated in the art of thieving.'
48. Vol. ii, p. 231.
49. Cf. also for the difficulties of the poor in getting fuel, the account by the Rev. Dr. Glasse; Reports
on Poor, vol. i, p. 58. 'Having long observed, that there is scarcely any article of life, in respect to
which the poor are under greater difficulties, or for the supply of which they have stronger
temptations to dishonest practices, than that of fuel,' he laid up in summer a store of coals in
Greenford (Middlesex), and Wanstead, and sold them rather under original cost price, carriage free,
in winter. 'The benefit arising from the relief afforded them in this article of coals, is obvious: they are
habituated to pay for what they have; whereas at the shop they ran in debt. When their credit was at
an end, they contrived to do without coals, by having recourse to wood-stealing; than which I know
no practise which tends more effectually to introduce into young minds a habit of dishonesty; it is
also very injurious to the farmer, and excites a degree of resentment in his breast, which, in many
instances, renders him averse to affording relief to the poor, even when real necessity calls loudly
for it.'
50. 20 George, II, c. 19.
51. Annuals of Agriculture, vol. xxv, p. 305 ff.
52. Annals of Agriculture, vol. xxv. p. 298.
53. Parliamentary Register, December 9, 1795.
54. Ibid., February 12, 1796.
55. Annals of Agriculture, vol. xxv. p. 345.
56. Ibid., p. 316.
57. An Examination of Mr Pitt's Speech in the House of Commons, February 12, 1796.
58. p. 106 ff.
59. Annuals of Agriculture, 1795, vol. xxv., p. 503.
60. Parliamentary Debates.
61. Printed in Parliamentary Papers for 1795-6.
62. The age was not filled up.
63. For report of debate see Parliamentary Register for that date.
64. See Parliamentary Register.
65. See Parliamentary Register, February 14, 1800.
66. Reports on Poor, vol. v. p. 23.
67. See p. 179.
68. Annals of Agriculture, vol. xxvi, p. 178.
69. 22 George III, c. 83.
70. In 1834 there were 924 comprised in 67 incorporations (Nicholls, vol. ii, p. 91).
71. 9 George I, c. 7.
72. Eden, vol. i, p. 269.
73. E.g., Oxford and Shrewsbury.
74. There is a significant entry in the Abstracts of Returns to the 1775 Poor Relief Committee in
reference to the building of that death-trap, the Bulcamp House of Industry. 'In the Expences for
Building is included £500 for building a Part which was pulled down by a Mob.'
75. An Heckingham in Norfolk a putrid fever, in 1774, killed 126 out of 220 inmates (Eden, vol. ii, p.
473, quoting Howlett); cf. also Ruggles, History of the Poor, vol. ii, p. 266.
76. 'The Village,' pp. 16 and 17.
77. Eden, vol. iii, p. 694 ff.
78. 36 George III, c. 23.
79. The last of these systems had been included in a Bill introduced by Sir William Young in 1788.
'In order to relieve agricultural labourers, who are often, during the winter, out of employment, the
vestry in every parish is empowered, by notice affixed to the church door, to settle a rate of wages to
be paid to labourers not of employ, from the 30th Nov to the 28th of Feb.; and to distribute and send
them round in rotation to the parishioners, proportionally as they pay to the Rates; to be paid by the
person employing them two-thirds of the wages so settled, and one-third by the parish-officers out of
the Rates.' -- Eden, vol. i, p. 397.
80. Parliamentary Register, February 12, 1796.
81. Ibid., December 22, 1796.
82. The Bill is printed in House of Commons Papers, 1796. The 'Heads of the Bill' as circulated
appear in the Annals of Agriculture, vol. xxvi, pp. 260 ff. and 359 ff. Eden gives in the form of
Appendices (1) the Heads of the Bill, (2) the Amendments introduced in Committee.
83. House of Commons Journal.
84. Parliamentary Register, February 11, 1800.
85. 35 George III, c. 101.
86. For Whitbread's proposals to amend the Law of Settlement in 1807 see next chapter. An
attempt was made in 1819 (59 George II, c. 50) to define and simplify the conditions under which
the hiring of a tenement of £10 annual value conferred the right to a settlement. The term of
residence was extended to a year, the nature of the tenement was defined, and it was laid down that
the rent must be £10 and paid for a whole year. But so unsuccessful was this piece of legislation
that it as found necessary to pass a second Act six years later (1826, 6 George IV, c. 57), and a
third Act in 1831 (I William IV, c. 18).
87. Senator, March 1800.
88. See Debates in Senator, March 31 and April 3, 1800, and Parliamentary Register. Cf. for
removals for temporary distress, Sir Thomas Bernard's Charge to Overseers in the Hundred of
Stoke. Bucks. Reports on Poor, vol. i, p. 260. 'With regard to the removal of labourers belonging to
other parishes, consider thoroughly what you may lose, and what the individual may suffer, by the
removal, before you apply to us on the subject. Where you have had, for a long time, the benefit of
their labour, and where all they want is a little temporary relief, reflect whether, after so many years
spent in your service, this is the moment and the cause, for removing them from the scene of their
daily labour to a distant parish, etc.' (1798).
89. Davies, pp. 102-4.
90. 15 George III c. 32.
91. Reports on Poor, vol. ii, p. 171.
92. Reports on Poor, vol. ii, p. 136.
93. Ibid., p. 137.
94. Ibid, vol. v, p. 66.
95. Mr Estcourt mentions that the land 'would let to a farmer at about 20s. per acre now.'
96. It is interesting to find that these allotments were still let out successfully in 1868. See p. 4145 of
the Report on the Employment of Children, Young Persons and Women in Agriculture, 1868.
97. Reports on Poor, vol. iii, p. 329.
98. 1803, p. 850.
99. Reports on Poor, vol. i, p. 100.
100. Vol. xxvi, p. 4.
101. The most distinguished advocate of this policy was William Marshall, the agricultural writer who
published a strong appeal for the labourers in his book On the Management of Landed Estates,
1806, p. 155; cf. also Curween's Hints, p. 239; 'A farther attention to the cottager's comfort is
attended with little cost; I mean giving him a small garden, and planting that as well as the walls of
his house with fruit trees.'
102. Vol. xxv. p. 349.
103. Ibid., p. 358.
104. Reports on Poor, vol. ii, p. 184.
105. Ibid., p. 134.
106. Cf. Poor Law Report, 1817, Appendix G. p. 4.
107. Capes, Rural Life in Hampshire, p. 282.
108. Poor Law Reports, 1834, p. 61; cf. ibid., p. 185.
109. Notes to Kent's Norfolk, p. 178.
110. See Poor Law Report, 1834, p. 181, and Allotments Committee, 1843, p. 108.
111. 59 George III, c. 12.
112. 1 and 2 William IV, c. 42.
113. Speenhamland is now part of Newbury. The Pelican Inn has disappeared, but the Pelican
Posting House survives.
114. Charles Dundas, afterwards Lord Amesbury, 1751-1832; Liberal, M.P. for Berkshire 1794-
1832, nominated by Sheridan for the Speakersip in 1802 but withdrew.
115. Reading Mercury, April 20, 1795.
116. Reading Mercury, April 20, 1795.
117. See Ibid., May 11, 1795.
118. Eden, vol. i, p. 578.
119. On the same day a 'respectable meeting' at Basingstoke, with the Mayor in the chair, was
advocating the fixing of labourers' wages in accordance with the price of wheat without any
reference to parish relief. -- Reading Mercury, May 11, 1795.
120. See Ipswich Journal, February 7, 1795, and Reading Mercury, July 6, 1795.
121. Eden, vol. ii, p. 384.
122. Ibid., p. 548.
123. Ibid., p. 27.
124. Eden, vol. ii, p. 29.
125. Ibid., p. 32.
126. 'The Village,' Book I.
Chapter Seven
After Speenhamland
The Speenhamland system is often spoken of as a piece of pardonable but disastrous
sentimentalism on the part of the upper classes. This view overlooks the predicament in which these
classes found themselves at the end of the eighteenth century. We will try to reconstruct the
situation and to reproduce their state of mind. Agriculture, which had hitherto provided most people
with a livelihood, but few people with vast fortunes, had become by the end of the century a great
capitalist and specialised industry. During the French War its profits were fabulous, and they were
due partly to enclosures, partly to the introduction of scientific methods, partly to the huge prices
caused by the War. It was producing thus a vast surplus over and above the product necessary for
maintenance and for wear and tear. Consequently, as students of Mr. Hobson's Industrial System
will perceive, there arose an important social problem of distribution, and the Poor Law was closely
involved with it.
This industry maintained, or helped to maintain, four principal interests: the landlords, the tithe-
owners, the farmers, and the labourers. Of these interests the first two were represented in the
governing class, and in considering the mind of that class we may merge them into one. The
sympathies of the farmers were rather with the landlords than with the labourers, but their interests
were not identical. The labourers were unrepresented either in the Government or in the voting
power of the nation. If the forces had been more equally matched, or if Parliament had represented
all classes, the surplus in come of agriculture would have gone to increase rents, tithes, profits, and
wages. It might, besides turning the landlords into great magnates like the cotton lords of
Lancashire, and throwing up a race of farmers with scarlet coats and jack boots, have raised
permanently the standard and character of the labouring class, have given them a decent wage and
decent 142 cottages. The village population whose condition, as Whitbread said, was compared by
supporters of the slave trade with that of the negroes in the West Indies, to its disadvantage, might
have been rehoused on its share of this tremendous revenue. In fact, the revenue went solely to
increase rent, tithes, and to some extent profits. The labourers al one had made no advance when
the halcyon days of the industry clouded over and prices fell. The rent receiver received more rent
than was needed to induce him to let his land, the farmer made larger profits than were necessary to
induce him to apply his capital and ability to farming, but the labourer received less than was
necessary to maintain him, the balance being made up out of the rates. Thus not only did the
labourer receive no share of this surplus; he did not even get his subsistence directly from the
product of his labour. Now let us suppose that instead of having his wages made up out of the rates
he had been paid a maintenance wage by the farmer. The extra cost would have come out of rent to
the same extent as did the subsidy from the rates. The landlord therefore made no sacrifice in
introducing the Speenhamland system, for though the farmers thought that they could obtain a
reduction of rent more easily if they could plead high rates than if they pleaded the high price of
labour,(1*) it is obvious that the same conditions which produced a reduction of rents in the one
case must ultimately have produced a reduction in the other. As it was, none of this surplus went to
labour, and the proportion in which it was divided between landlord and farmer was not affected by
the fact that the labourer was kept alive partly from the rates and not wholly from wages.(2*)
Now the governing class which was confronted with the situation that we have described in a
previous chapter consisted of two classes who had both contrived to slip off their obligations to the
State. They were both essentially privileged classes. The landlords were not in the eye of history
absolute owners; they had held their land on several conditions, one of which was the liability to
provide military services for the Crown, and this obligation they had commuted into a tax on the
nation. Neither were the tithe-owners absolute owners in the eye of history. In early days all Church
property was regarded as the patrimony of the poor, and the clergy were bidden to use it non quasi
suis sed quasi commendatis, Dryden, in drawing the character of the Good Parson, had described
their obligations:
<poem>
'True priests, he said, and preachers of the Word
Were only stewards of their sovereign Lord:
Nothing was theirs but all the public store,
Intrusted riches to relieve the poor,'
</poem>
It was recognised, as late as the reign of Henry IV, that tithes were designed among other objects
for the relief of the poor. An Act of that reign confirmed an earlier Act of Richard II. (15 Rich. II. c. 6),
which laid down that on the appropriation of any parish church, money was to be paid yearly of the
fruits and profits of the said church to the poor parishioners. After this time the claims of the poor
fade from view. Of course, great masses of tithe property had passed, by the time we are
considering, into secular hands. The monasteries appropriated about a third of the livings of
England, and the tithes in these parishes passed at the Reformation to the Crown, whence they
passed in grants to private persons. No responsibility for the poor troubled either the lay or spiritual
owners of tithes, and though they used the name of God freely in defending their claims, they were
stewards of God in much the same sense as George IV was the defender of the faith. The
landowners and tithe-owners had their differences when it came to an Enclosure Bill, but these
classes had the same interests in the disposal of the surplus profits of agriculture; and both alike
were in a vulnerable position if the origin and history of their property came under too fierce a
discussion.
There was a special reason why the classes that had suddenly become very much richer should
dread too searching a discontent at this moment. They had seen tithes, and all seignorial dues
abolished almost at a single stroke across the Channel, and they were at this time associating
constantly with the emigrant nobility of France, whose prospect of recovering their estates seemed
to fade into a more doubtful distance with every battle that was fought between the France who had
given the poor peasant such a position as the peasant enjoyed nowhere else, and her powerful
neighbour who had made her landlords the richest and proudest class in Europe. The French
Convention had passed a decree (November 1792), declaring that 'wherever French armies shall
come, all taxes, tithes, and privileges of rank are to be abolished, all existing authorities cancelled,
and provisional administrations elected by universal suffrage. The property of the fallen
Government, of the privileged classes and their adherents to be placed under French protection.'
This last sentence had an unpleasant ring about it; it sounded like a terse paraphrase of non quasi
suis sed quasi comemndatis. In point of fact there was not yet any violent criticism of the basis of
the social position of the privileged classes in England. Even Paine, when he suggested a scheme
of Old Age Pensions for all over fifty, and a dowry for every one on reaching the age of twenty-one,
had proposed to finance it by death duties. Thelwall, who wrote with a not unnatural bitterness about
the great growth of ostentatious wealth at a time when the poor were becoming steadily poorer, told
a story which illustrated very well the significance of the philanthropy of the rich. 'I remember I was
once talking to a friend of the charity and benevolence exhibited in this country, when stopping me
with a sarcastic sneer, "Yes," says he, "we steal the goose, and we give back the giblets." "No," said
a third person who was standing by, "giblets are much too dainty for the common herd, we give
them only the pen feathers."'(3*) But the literature of Radicalism was not inflammatory, and the
demands of the dispossessed were for something a good deal less than their strict due. The richer
classes, however, were naturally anxious to soothe and pacify the poor before discontent spread
any further, and the Speenhamland system turned out, from their point of view, a very admirable
means to that end, for it provided a maintenance for the poor by a method which sapped their spirit
and disarmed their independence. They were anxious that the labourers should not get into the way
of expecting a larger share in the profits of agriculture, and at the same time they wanted to make
them contented. Thelwall(4*) stated that when he was in the Isle of Wight, the farmers came to a
resolution to raise the price of labour, and that they were dissuaded by one of the greatest
proprietors in the island, who called a meeting and warned the farmers that they would make the
common people insolent and would never be able to reduce their wages again.
An account of the introduction of the system into Warwickshire and Worcestershire illustrates very
well the state of mind in which this policy had its origin. 'In Warwickshire, the year 1797 was
mentioned as the date of its commencement in that county, and the scales of relief giving it authority
were published in each of these counties previously to the year 1800. It was apprehended by many
at that time, that either the wages of labour would rise to a height from which it would be difficult to
reduce them when the cause for it had ceased, or that during the high prices the labourers might
have had to endure privations to which it would be unsafe to expose them. To meet the emergency
of the time, various schemes are said to have been adopted, such as weekly distributions of flour,
prodding families with clothes, or maintaining entirely a portion of their families, until at length the
practice became general, and a right distinctly admitted by the magistrates was claimed by the
labourer to parish relief, on the ground of inadequate wages and number in family. I was informed
that the consequences of the system were not wholly unforeseen at the time, as affording a
probable inducement to early marriages and large families; but at this period there was but little
apprehension on that ground. A prevalent opinion, supported by high authority, that population was
in itself a source of wealth, precluded all alarm. The demands for the public service were thought to
endure a sufficient draught for any surplus people; and it was deemed wise by many persons at this
time to present the Poor Laws to the lower classes, as an institution for their advantage, peculiar to
this country; and to encourage an opinion among them, that by this means their own share in the
property of the kingdom was recognised.'(5*) To the landlords the Speenhamland system was a
safety-valve in two ways. The farmers got cheap labour, and the labourers got a maintenance, and it
was hoped thus to reconcile both classes to high rents and the great social splendour of their rulers.
There was no encroachment on the surplus profits of agriculture, and landlords and tithe-owners
basked in the sunshine of prosperity. It would be a mistake to represent the landlords as deliberately
treating the farmers and the labourers on the principle which Caesar boasted that he had applied
with such success, when he borrowed money from his officers to give it to his soldiers, and thus
contrived to attach both classes to his interest; but that was in effect the result and the significance
of the Speenhamland system.
This wrong application of those surplus profits was one element in the violent oscillations of trade
during the generation after the war. A long war adding enormously to the expenditure of
Government must disorganise industry seriously in any case, and in this case the demoralisation
was increased by a bad currency system. The governing class, which was continually meditating on
the subject of agricultural distress, holding inquiries, and appointing committees, never conceived
the problem as one of distribution. The Select Committee of 1833 on Agriculture, for example,
expressly disclaims any interest in the question of rents and wages, treating these as determined by
a law of Nature, and assuming that the only question for a Government was the question of
steadying prices by protection. What they did not realise was that a bad distribution of profits was
itself a cause of disturbance. The most instructive speech on the course of agriculture during the
French war was that in which Brougham showed in the House of Commons, on 9th April 1816, how
the country had suffered from over-production during the wild elation of high prices, and how a
tremendous system of speculative farming had been built up, entangling a variety of interests in this
gamble. If those days had been employed to raise the standard of life among the labourers and to
increase their powers of consumption, the subsequent fall would have been broken. The economists
of the time looked on the millions of labourers as an item of cost, to be regarded like the price of raw
material, whereas it is clear that they ought to have been regarded also as affording the best and
most stable of markets. The landlord or the banker who put his surplus profits into the improvement
and cultivation of land, only productive under conditions that could not last and could not return, was
increasing unemployment in the future, whereas if the same profits had been distributed in wages
among the labourers, they would have permanently increased consumption and steadied the
vicissitudes of trade. Further, employment would have been more regular in another respect, for the
landowner spent his surplus on luxuries, and the labourer spent his wages on necessaries.
Now labour might have received its share of these profits either in an increase of wages, or in the
expenditure of part of the revenue in a way that was specially beneficial to it. Wages did not rise,
and it was a felony to use any pressure to raise them. What was the case of the poor in regard to
taxation and expenditure? Taxation was overwhelming. A Herefordshire farmer stated that in 1815
the rates and taxes on a farm of three hundred acres in that county were: --
£ s. d.
Property tax, landlord and tenant... 95 16 10
Great tithes....... 64 17 6
Lesser tithes....... 29 15 0
Land tax........ 14 0 0
Window lights..... 24 1 6
Poor rates, landlord...... 10 0 0
Poor rates, tenant...., 40 0 0
Cart-horse duty, landlord, 3 horses.,. 2 11 0
Two saddle horses, landlord.... 9 0 0
Gig........ 6 6 0
Cart-horse duty, tenant..... 7 2 0
One saddle horse, tenant..... 2 13 6
Landlord's malt duty on 60 bushels of barley. 21 0 0
Tenant's duty for making 120 bushels of barley into malt....... 42 0 0
New rate for building shire hall, paid by landlord........ 9 0 0
New rate for building shire hall, paid by tenant. 3 0 0
Surcharge....... 2 8 0
£383 11 4(6*)
The Agricultural and Industrial Magazine, a periodical published by a philanthropical society in 1833,
gave the following analysis of the taxation of a labourer earning £22, 10s.
a year: --
£ s. d.
1. Malt...... 4 11 3
2. Sugar...... 0 17 4
3. Tea and Coffee..... 1 4 0
4. Soap...... 0 13 0
5. Housing...... 0 12 0
6. Food..... 3 0 0
7. Clothes.,.,.. 0 10 0
£11 7 7
But in the expenditure from this taxation was there a single item in which the poor had a special
interest? The great mass of the expenditure was war expenditure, and that was not expenditure in
which the poor were more interested than the rest. Indeed, much of it was expenditure which could
not be associated directly or indirectly with their interests, such as the huge subsidies to the courts
of Europe. Nearly fifty millions went in these subventions, and if some of them were strategical
others were purely political. Did the English labourer receive any profit from the two and a half
millions that Pitt threw to the King of Prussia, a subsidy that was employed for crushing Kosciusko
and Poland, or from the millions that he gave to Austria, in return for which Austria ceded Venice to
Napoleon? Did he receive any benefit from the million spent every year on the german legion, which
helped to keep him in order in his own country? Did he receive any benefit from the million and a
half which, on the confession of the Finance Committee of the House of Commons in 1810, went
every year in absolute sinecures? Did he receive any benefit from the interest on the loans to the
great bankers and contractors, who made huge profits out of the war and were patriotic enough to
lend money to the Government to keep it going? Did he receive any benefit from the expenditure on
crimping boys or pressing seamen, or transporting and imprisoning poachers and throwing their
families by thousands on the rates? Pitt's brilliant idea of buying up a cheap debt out of money
raised by a dear one cost the nation twenty millions, and though Pitt considered the Sinking Fund
his best title to honour, nobody will pretend that the poor of England gained anything from this
display of his originality.(7*) In these years government was raising by taxation or loans over a
hundred millions, but not a single penny went to the education of the labourer's children, or to any
purpose that made the perils and difficulties of his life more easy to be borne. If the sinecures had
been reduced by a half, or if the great money-lenders had been treated as if their claims to the last
penny were not sacrosanct, and had been made to take their share of the losses of the time, it
would have been possible to set up the English cottager with allotments on the modest plan
proposed by Young or Cobbett, side by side with the great estates with which that expenditure
endowed the bankers and the dealers in scrip.
Now, so long as prices kept up, the condition of the labourer was masked by the general prosperity
of the times. The governing class had found a method which checked the demand for higher wages
and the danger that the labourer might claim a share in the bounding wealth of the time. The wolf
was at the door, it is true, but he was chained, and the chain was the Speenhamland system.
Consequently, though we hear complaints from the labourers, who contended that they were
receiving in a patronising and degrading form what they were entitled to have as their direct wages,
the note of rebellion was smothered for the moment. At this time it was a profitable proceeding to
grow corn on almost any soil, and it is still possible to trace on the unharvested downs of Dartmoor
the print of the plough that turned even that wild moorland into gold, in the days when Napoleon was
massing his armies for invasion. During these years parishes did not mind giving aid from the rates
on the Speenhamland scale, and, though under this mischievous system population was advancing
wildly, there was such a demand for labour that this abundance did not seem, as it seemed later, a
plague of locusts, but a source of strength and wealth. The opinion of the day was all in favour of a
heavy birth rate, and it was generally agreed, as we have seen, that Pitt's escapades in the West
Indies and elsewhere would draw off the surplus population fast enough to remove all difficulties.
But although the large farmers prayed incessantly to heaven to preserve Pitt and to keep up religion
and prices, the day came when it did not pay to plough the downs or the sands, and tumbling prices
brought ruin to the farmers whose rents and whole manner of living were fixed on the assumption
that there was no serious danger of peace, and that England was to live in a perpetual heyday of
famine prices.
With the fall in prices, the facts of the labourer's condition were disclosed. Doctors tell us that in
some cases of heart disease there is a state described as compensation, which may postpone
failure for many years. With the fall in 1814 compensation ceased, and the disease which it
obscured declared itself. For it was now no longer possible to absorb the redundant population in
the wasteful roundsman system, and the maintenance standard tended to fall with the growing
pressure on the resources from which the labourer was kept. By this time all labour had been
swamped in the system. The ordinary village did not contain a mass of decently paid labourers and
a surplus of labourers, from time to time redundant, for whom the parish had to provide as best it
could. It contained a mass of labourers, all of them underpaid, whom the parish had to keep alive in
the way most convenient to the farmers. Bishop Berkeley once said that it was doubtful whether the
prosperity that preceded, or the calamities that succeeded, the South Sea Bubble had been the
more disastrous to Great Britain: that saying would very well apply to the position of the agricultural
labourer in regard to the rise and the fall of prices. With the rise of prices the last patch of common
agriculture had been seized by the landlords, and the labourer had been robbed even of his garden;
(8*) with the fall, the great mass of labourers were thrown into destitution and misery. We may add
that if that prosperity had been briefer, the superstition that an artificial encouragement of population
was needed -- the superstition of the rich for which the poor paid the penalty would have had a
shorter life. As it was, at the end of the great prosperity the landlords were enormously rich; rents
had in some cases increased five-fold between 1790 and 1812;(9*) the large farmers had in many
cases climbed into a style of life which meant a crash as soon as prices fell; the financiers had
made great and sudden fortunes; the only class for whom a rise in the standard of existence was
essential to the nation, had merely become more dependent on the pleasure of other classes and
the accidents of the markets. The purchasing power of the labourer's wages had gone down.
The first sign of the strain is the rioting of 1816. In that year the spirit which the governing class had
tried to send to sleep by the Speenhamland system, burst out in the first of two peasants' revolts.
Let us remember what their position was. They were not the only people overwhelmed by the fall in
prices. Some landlords, who had been so reckless and extravagant as to live up to the enormous
revenue they were receiving, had to surrender their estates to the new class of bankers and money-
lenders that had been made powerful by the war. Many farmers, who had taken to keeping liveried
servants and to copying the pomp of their landlords, and who had staked everything on the
permanence of prices, were now submerged. Small farmers too, as the answers sent to the
questions issued this year by the Board of Agriculture show, became paupers. The labourer was not
the only sufferer. But he differed from the other victims of distress in that he had not benefited, but,
as we have seen, had lost, by the prosperity of the days when the plough turned a golden furrow.
His housing had not been improved; his dependence had not been made less abject or less
absolute; his wages had not risen; and in many cases his garden had disappeared. When the storm
broke over agriculture his condition became desperate. In February 1816 the Board of Agriculture
sent out a series of questions, one of which asked for an account of the state of the poor, and out of
273 replies 237 reported want of employment and distress, and 25 reported that there was not
unemployment or distress.(10*) One of the correspondents explained that in his district the overseer
called a meeting every Saturday, when he put up each labourer by name to auction, and they were
let generally at from 1s. 6d. to 2s. per week and their provisions, their families being supported by
the parish.(11*)
In 1816 the labourers were suffering both from unemployment and from high prices. In 1815, as the
Annual Register(12*) puts it, 'much distress was undergone in the latter part of the year by the
trading portion of the community. This source of private calamity was unfortunately coincident with
an extraordinary decline in agricultural prosperity, immediately proceeding from the greatly reduced
price of corn and other products, which bore no adequate proportion to the exorbitant rents and
other heavy burdens pressing upon the farmer.' At the beginning of 1816 there were gloomy
anticipations of a fall in prices, and Western(13*) moved a series of resolutions designed to prevent
the importation of corn. But as the year advanced it became evident that the danger that threatened
England was not the danger of abundance but the danger of scarcity. A bitterly cold summer was
followed by so meagre a harvest that the price of corn rose rapidly beyond the point at which the
ports were open for importation. But high prices which brought bidders at once for farms that had
been unlet made bread and meat dear to the agricultural labourer, Without bringing him more
employment or an advance of wages, and the riots of 1816 were the result of the misery due to this
combination of misfortunes.
The riots broke out in May of that year, and the counties affected were Norfolk, Suffolk, Huntingdon
and Cambridgeshire. Nightly assemblies were held, threatening letters were sent, and houses,
barns and ricks were set on fire. These fires were a prelude to a more determined agitation, which
had such an effect on the authorities that the Sheriff Suffolk and Mr. Willet, a banker of Brandon
near Bury, hastened to London to inform the Home Secretary and to ask for the help of the
government in restoring tranquillity. Mr. Willet's special interest in the proceedings is explained in a
naive sentence in the Annual Register: 'A reduction in the price of bread and meat was the avowed
object of the rioters. They had fixed a maximum for the price of both. They insisted that the lowest
price of wheat must be half a crown a bushel, and that of prime joints of beef fourpence per pound.
Mr. Willet, a butcher at Brandon, was a marked object of their ill-will, in which Mr. Willet, the banker,
was, from the similarity of his name, in danger of sharing. This circumstance, and a laudable anxiety
to preserve the public peace, induced him to take an active part and exert all his influence for that
purpose.'(14*) The rioters numbered some fifteen hundred, and they broke up into separate parties,
scattering into different towns and villages. In the course of their depredations the house of the right
Mr. Willet was levelled to the ground, after which the wrong Mr. Willet, it is to be hoped, was less
restless.(15*) 'They were armed with long, heavy sticks, the ends of which, to the extent of several
inches, were studded with short iron spikes, sharp at the sides and point. Their flag was. inscribed
"Bread or Blood!" and they threatened to march to London.'(16*)
During the next few days there were encounters between insurgent mobs in Norwich and Bury and
the yeomanry, the dragoons, and the West Norfolk Militia. No lives seem to have been lost, but a
good deal of property was destroyed, and a number of rioters were taken into custody. The Times of
25th May says, in an article on these riots, that wages had been reduced to a rate lower than the
magistrates thought reasonable, for the magistrates, after suppressing a riot near Downham,
acquiesced in the propriety of raising wages, and released the offenders who had been arrested
with a suitable remonstrance. There was a much more serious battle at Littleport in the Isle of Ely,
when the old fighting spirit of the fens seems to have inspired the rioters. They began by driving
from his house a clergyman magistrate of the name of Vachel, after which they attacked several
houses and extorted money. They then made for Ely, where they carried out the same programme.
This state of anarchy, after two or three days, ended in a battle in Littleport in which two rioters were
killed, and seventy-five taken prisoners. The prisoners were tried next month by a Special
Commission: twenty-four were capitally convicted; of these five were hung, five were transported for
life, one was transported for fourteen years, three for seven years, and ten were imprisoned for
twelve months in Ely gaol.(17*) The spirit in which one of the judges, Mr. Christian, the Chief Justice
of the Isle of Ely, conducted the proceedings may be gathered from his closing speech, in which he
said that the rioters were receiving 'great wages' and that 'any change in the price of provisions
could only lessen that superfluity, which, I fear, they too frequently wasted in drunkenness.'(18*)
The pressure of the changed conditions of the nation on this system of maintenance out of the rates
is seen, not only in the behaviour of the labourers, but also in the growing anxiety of the upper
classes to control the system, and in the tenacity with which the parishes contested settlement
claims. This is the great period of Poor Law litigation. Parish authorities kept a stricter watch than
ever on immigrants. In 1816, for example, the Board of Agriculture reported that according to a
correspondent 'a late legal decision, determining that keeping a cow gained a settlement, has
deprived many cottagers of that comfort, as it is properly called.'(19*) This decision was remedied
by the 1819 Act(20*) to amend the Settlement Laws as regards renting tenements, and the Report
on the Poor Law in 1819 states that in consequence there 'will no longer be an obstacle to the
accommodation which may be afforded in some instances to a poor family, by renting the pasturage
of a cow, or some other temporary profit from the occupation of land.'(21*) Lawsuits between
parishes were incessant, and in 1815 the money spent on litigation and the removal of paupers
reached the gigantic figure of £287,000.
In Parliament, too, the question of Poor Law Reform was seen to be urgent, but the problem
assumed a particular and very limited shape. The significance of this development can be illustrated
by comparing the character and the fate of a measure Whitbread had introduced in 1807 with the
character and the fate of the legislation after Waterloo.
Whitbread's scheme had aimed at (1) improving and humanising the Law of Settlement; (2)
reforming the administration of the Poor Law as such in such a way as to give greater
encouragement to economy and a fairer distribution of burdens; (3) stimulating thrift and penalising
idleness in the labourers; (4) reforming unemployment policy.
The proposals under the first head provided that settlement might be gained by five years' residence
as a householder, if the householder had not become chargeable or been convicted of crime, or
been absent for more than six weeks in a year. Two Justices of the Peace were to have power on
complaint of the parish authorities to adjudicate on the settlement of any person likely to become
chargeable, subject to an appeal to quarter Sessions.
The proposals under the second head aimed partly at vestry reform and partly at rating reform. In
those parishes where there was an open vestry, all ratepayers were still equal as voters, but
Whitbread proposed to give extra voting power at vestry meetings in proportion to assessment.(22*)
He wished to reform rating, by making stock in trade and personal property (except farming stock),
which produced profit liable to assessment, by authorising the vestry to exempt such occupiers of
cottages as they should think fit, and by giving power to the Justices of the Peace to strike out of the
rate any person occupying a cottage not exceeding five pounds in yearly value, who should make
application to them, such exemptions not to be considered parochial relief. He also proposed that
the county rate should be charged in every parish in proportion to the assessed property in the
parish, and that any parish whose poor rate was for three years more than double the average of the
parish rate in the county, should have power to apply to Quarter Sessions for relief out of county
stock.
Whitbread's proposals for stimulating thrift and penalising idleness were a strange medley of
enlightenment and childishness. He proposed to give the parish officers power to build cottages
which were to be let at the best rents that were to be obtained: but the parish officers might with the
consent of the vestry allow persons who could not pay rent to occupy them rent free, or at a reduced
rent. He proposed also to create a National Bank, something of the nature of a Post Office Savings
Bank, to be employed both as a savings bank and an insurance system for the poor. With these two
excellent schemes he combined a ridiculous system of prizes and punishments for the thrifty and
the irresponsible. Magistrates were to be empowered to give rewards (up to a maximum of £20) with
a badge of good conduct, to labourers who had brought up large families without parish help, and to
punish any man who appeared to have become chargeable from idleness or misconduct, and to
brand him with the words, 'criminal Poor.'
In his unemployment policy Whitbread committed the fatal mistake, common to almost all the
proposals of the time, of mixing up poor relief with wages in a way to depress and demoralise the
labour market. The able-bodied unemployed, men, youths, or single women, were to be hired out by
parish officers at the best price to be obtained. The wages were to be paid to the worker. If the
worker was a single man or woman, or a widower with no children dependent on him, his or her
earnings were to be made up by the parish to a sum necessary to his or her subsistence. If he or
she had children, they were to be made up to three-quarters, or four-fifths, or the full average rate,
according to the number of children. No single man or woman was to be hired out for more than a
year, and no man or woman with dependent children for more than a month.
The proposals were attacked vigorously by two critics who were not often found in company,
Cobbett and Malthus. Cobbett criticised the introduction of plural voting at vestry meetings in an
excellent passage in the Political Register.(23*) 'Many of those who pay rates are but a step Or two
from pauperism themselves; and they are the most likely persons to consider duly the important
duty of doing, in case of relief, what they would be done unto. "But," Mr. Whitbread will say, "is it
right for these persons to give away the money of others." It is not the money of others, any more
than the amount of tithes is the farmer's money. The maintenance of the poor is a charge upon the
land, a charge duly considered in every purchase and in every lease. Besides, as the law now
stands, though every parishioner has a vote in vestry, must it not be evident, to every man who
reflects, that a man of large property and superior understanding will have weight in proportion?
That he will, in fact, have many votes? If he play the tyrant, even little men will rise against him, and
it is right they should have the power of so doing; but, while he conducts himself with moderation
and humanity, while he behaves as he ought to do to those who are beneath him in point of
property, there is no fear but he will have a sufficiency of weight at every vestry. The votes of the
inferior persons in the parish are, in reality, dormant, unless in cases where some innovation, or
some act of tyranny, is attempted. They are, like the sting of the bee, weapons merely of defence.'
Malthus' criticisms were of a very different nature.(24*) He objected particularly to the public building
of cottages, and the assessment of personal property to the rates. He argued that the scarcity of
houses was the chief reason 'why the Poor Laws had not been so extensive and prejudicial in their
effects as might have been expected.' If a stimulus was given to the building of cottages there would
be no check on the increase of population. A similar tendency he ascribed to the rating of personal
property. The employers of labour had an interest in the increase of population, and therefore in the
building of cottages. This instinct was at present held in check by consideration of the burden of the
rates. If, however, they could distribute that burden more widely, this consideration would have
much less weight. Population would increase and wages would consequently go down. 'It has been
observed by Dr. Adam Smith that no efforts of the legislature had been able to raise the salary of
curates to that price which seemed necessary for their decent maintenance: and the reason which
he justly assigns is that the bounties held out to the profession by the scholarships and fellowships
of the universities always occasioned a redundant supply. In the same manner, if a more than usual
supply of labour were encouraged by the premiums of small tenements, nothing could prevent a
great and general fall in its price.'
The Bill was introduced in 1807, before the fall of the Whig Ministry, and it went to a Committee. But
the Tory Parliament elected that year to support Portland and his anti-Catholic Government was
unfriendly, and the county magistrates to whom the draft of the Bill was sent for criticisms were also
hostile. Whitbread accordingly proceeded no further. At this time the Speenhamland system
seemed to be working without serious inconvenience, and there was therefore no driving power
behind such proposals. But after 1815 the conditions had changed, and the apathy of 1807 had
melted away. The ruling class was no longer passive and indifferent about the growth of the
Speenhamland system: both Houses of Parliament set inquiries on foot, schemes of emigration
were invited and discussed, and measures of Vestry Reform were carried. But the problem was no
longer the problem that Whitbread had set out to solve. Whitbread had proposed to increase the
share of property in the control of the poor rates, but he had also brought forward a constructive
scheme of social improvement. The Vestry Reformers of this period were merely interested in
reducing the rates: the rest of Whitbread's programme was forgotten.
In 1818 an Act(25*) was passed which established plural voting in vestries, every ratepayer whose
rateable value was £50 and over being allowed a vote for every £25 of rateable property. In the
following year an Act(26*) was passed which allowed parishes to set up a select vestry, and
ordained that in these parishes the overseers should give such relief as was ordered by the Select
Vestry, and further allowed the appointment of salaried assistant overseers. These changes
affected the administration of the Speenhamland system very considerably; and the salaried
overseers made themselves hated in many parishes by the Draconian régime which they
introduced. The parish cart, or the cart to which in some parishes men and women who asked for
relief were harnessed, was one of the innovations of this period. The administrative methods that
were adopted in these parishes are frustrated by a fact mentioned by a clerk to the magistrates in
Kent, in October 1830.(27*) The writer says that there was a severe overseer at Ash, who had
among other applicants for relief an unemployed shepherd, with a wife and five children living at
Margate, thirteen miles away. The shepherd was given 9s. a week, but the overseer made him walk
to Ash every day except Sunday for his eighteen pence. The shepherd walked his twenty-six miles a
day on such food as he could obtain out of his share of the 9s. for nine weeks, and then his strength
could hold out no longer. The writer remarked that the shepherd was an industrious and honest
man, out of work through no fault of his own. It was by such methods that the salaried overseers
tried to break the poor of the habit of asking for relief, and it is not surprising that such methods
rankled in the memories of the labourers. In this neighbourhood the writer attributed the fires of
1830 more to this cause than to any other.
These attempts to relieve the ratepayer did nothing to relieve the labourer from the incubus of the
system. His plight grew steadily worse. A Committee on Agricultural Wages, of which Lord John
Russell was chairman, reported in 1824 that whereas in certain northern counties, where the
Speenhamland system had not yet taken root, wages were 12s. to 15s., in the south they varied
from 8s. or 9s. a week to 3s. for a single man and 4s. 6d. for a married man.(28*) In one part of Kent
the lowest wages in one parish were 6d. a day, and in the majority of parishes 1s. a day. The wages
of an unmarried man in Buckinghamshire in 1828, according to a clergyman who gave evidence
before the Committee of that year on the Poor Laws, were 3s. a week, and the wages of a married
man were 6s. a week. In one parish in his neighbourhood the farmers had lately reduced the wages
of able-bodied married men to 4s. a week. Thus the Speenhamland system had been effective
enough in keeping wages low, but as a means of preserving a minimum livelihood it was breaking
down by this time on all sides. We have seen from the history of Merton in Oxfordshire(29*) what
happened in one parish long before the adversities of agriculture had become acute. It is easy from
this case to imagine what happened when the decline in employment and agriculture threw a
steadily increasing burden on the system of maintenance from the rates. In some places, as the
Commissioners of 1834 reported, the labourers were able by intimidation to keep the system in
force, but though parishes did not as a rule dare to abandon or reform the system, they steadily
reduced their scale.
The most direct and graphic demonstration of this fact, which has not apparently ever been noticed
in any of the voluminous discussions of the old Poor Law system, is to be seen in the comparison of
the standards of life adopted at the time the system was introduced with the standards that were
adopted later. In 1795, as we have seen, the magistrates at Speenhamland recommended an
allowance of three gallon loaves for each labourer, and a gallon loaf and a half for his wife and for
each additional member of his family. This scale, it must be remembered, was not peculiar to
Berkshire. It was the authoritative standard in many counties. We are able to compare this with
some later scales, and the comparison yields some startling results. In Northamptonshire in 1816
the magistrates fixed a single man's allowance at 5s., and the allowance for a man and his wife at
6s., the price of wheat the quartern loaf being 11 1/2d.(30*) On this scale a man is supposed to
need a little over two and a half gallon loaves, and a man and his wife a little more than three gallon
loaves, or barely more than a single man was supposed to need in 1795. This is a grave reduction,
but the maintenance standard fell very much lower before 1832. For though we have scales for
Cambridgeshire and Essex for 1821 published in the Report of the Poor Law Commission of 1834,
(31*) which agree roughly with the Northamptonshire scale (two gallon loaves for a man, and one
and a half for a woman), in Wiltshire, according to the complicated scale adopted at Hindon in 1817,
a man was allowed one and three-fifths gallon loaves, and a woman one and one-tenth.(32*) A
Hampshire scale, drawn up in 1822 by eight magistrates, of whom five were parsons, allowed only
one gallon loaf a head, with 4d. a week per head in addition to a family of four persons, the extra
allowance being reduced by a penny in cases where there were six in the family, and by twopence
in cases where there were more than six.(33*) The Dorsetshire magistrates in 1826 allowed a man
the equivalent of one and a half gallon loaves and a penny over, and a woman or child over fourteen
one and one-sixth.(34*) We have a general statement as to the scales in force towards the end of
our period in a passage in M'Culloch's Political Economy quoted in the Edinburgh Review for
January 1831 (p. 353): 'The allowance scales now issued from time to time by the magistrates are
usually framed on the principle that every labourer should have a gallon loaf of standard wheaten
bread weekly for every member of his family and one over: that is four loaves for three persons, five
for four, six for five, and so on.' That is, a family of four persons would have had seven and a half
gallon loaves in 1795, and only five gallon loaves in 1831.
Now the Speenhamland scale did not represent some easy and luxurious standard of living; it
represented the minimum on which it was supposed that a man employed in agriculture could
support life. In thirty-five years the standard had dropped, according to M'Culloch's statement, as
much as a third, and this not because of war or famine, for in 1826 England had had eleven years of
peace, but in the ordinary course of the life of the nation. Is such a decline in the standard of life
recorded anywhere else in history?
How did the labourers live at all under these conditions? Their life was, of course, wretched and
squalid in the extreme. Cobbett describes a group of women labourers whom he met by the
roadside in Hampshire as 'such an assemblage of rags as I never saw before even amongst the
hoppers at Farnham.' Of the labourers near Cricklade he said: 'Their dwellings are little better than
pig-beds, and their looks indicate that their food is not nearly equal to that of a pig. These wretched
hovels are stuck upon little beds of ground on the roadside where the space has been wider than
the road demanded. In many places they have not two rods to a hovel. It seems as if they had been
swept off the fields by a hurricane, and had dropped and found shelter under the banks on the
roadside. Yesterday morning was a sharp frost, and this had set the poor creatures to digging up
their little plots of potatoes. In my whole life I never saw human wretchedness equal to this; no, not
even amongst the free negroes in America who, on an average, do not work one day out of
four.'(35*) The labourers' cottages in Leicestershire he found were 'hovels made of mud and straw,
bits of glass or of old cast-off windows, without frames or hinges frequently, and merely stuck in the
mud wall. Enter them and look at the bits of chairs or stools, the wretched boards tacked together to
serve for a table, the floor of pebble broken or of the bare ground; look at the thing called a bed, and
survey the rags on the backs of the inhabitants.'(36*) A Dorsetshire clergyman, a witness before the
Committee on Wages in 1824, said that the labourers lived almost entirely on tea and potatoes; a
Bedfordshire labourer said that he and his family lived mainly on bread and cheese and water, and
that sometimes for a month together he never tasted meat; a Suffolk magistrate described how a
labourer out of work, convicted of stealing wood, begged to be sent at once to a House of
Correction, where he hoped to find food and employment. if Davies had written an account of the
labouring classes in 1820 or 1830, the picture he drew in 1795 would have seemed bright in
comparison. But even this kind of life could not be supported on such provision as was made by the
parish. How, then, did the labourers maintain any kind of existence when society ceased to piece
together a minimum livelihood out of rates and wages?
For the answer to this question we must turn to the history of crime and punishment; to the Reports
of the Parliamentary Committees on Labourers' Wages (1824), on the Game Laws (1823 and
1828), on Emigration (1826 and 1827), on Criminal Commitments and Convictions and Secondary
Punishments (1827, 1828, 1831, and 1832), and the evidence of those who were in touch with this
side of village life. From these sources we learn that, rate aid not being sufficient to bring wages to
the maintenance level, poaching, smuggling, and ultimately thieving were called in to rehabilitate the
labourer's economic position.(37*) He was driven to the wages of crime. The history of the
agricultural labourer in this generation is written in the code of the Game Laws, the growing brutality
of the Criminal Law, and the preoccupation of the rich with the efficacy of punishment.
We know from Fielding with what sort of justice the magistrates treated persons accused of
poaching in the reign of George III's grandfather, but when he wrote his account of Squire Western,
and when Blackstone wrote that the Game Laws had raised up a little Nimrod in every manor, the
blood of men and boys had not yet been spilt for the pleasures of the rich. it is only after Fielding
and Blackstone were both in their graves that this page of history became crimson, and that the
gentlemen of England took to guarding their special amusements by methods of which a Member of
Parliament declared that the nobles of France had not ventured on their like in the days of their most
splendid arrogance. The little Nimrods who made and applied. their code were a small and select
class. They were the persons qualified under the law of Charles II to shoot game, i.e., persons who
possessed a freehold estate of at least £100 a year, or a leasehold estate of at least £150 a year, or
the son or heir-apparent of an esquire or person of higher degree. The legislation that occupies so
much of English history during a period of misery and famine is devoted to the protection of the
monopoly of this class, comprising less than one in ten thousand of the people of England. A
Member of Parliament named Warburton said in the House of Commons that the only parallel to this
monopoly was to be found in Mariner's account of the Tonga Islands, where rats were preserved as
game. Anybody might eat rats there, but nobody was allowed to kill them except persons descended
from gods or kings.
With the general growth of upper-class riches and luxury there came over shooting a change
corresponding with the change that turned hunting into a magnificent and extravagant spectacle.
The habit set in of preserving game in great masses, of organising the battue, of maintaining armies
of keepers. In many parts of the country, pheasants were now introduCed for the first time. Whereas
game had hitherto kept something of the wildness, and vagrancy, and careless freedom of Nature,
the woods were now packed with tame and docile birds, whose gay feathers sparkled among the
trees, before the eyes of the half-starved labourers breaking stones on the road at half a crown a
week. The change is described by witnesses such as Sir James Graham and Sir Thomas Baring,
magistrates respectively in Cumberland and Hampshire, before the Select Committee on Criminal
Commitments and Convictions in 1827. England was, in fact, passing through a process precisely
opposite to that which had taken place in France: the sport of the rich was becoming more and more
of an elaborate system, and more of a vested interest. This development was marked by the growth
of an offensive combination among game preservers; in some parts of the country game
associations were formed, for the express purpose of paying the costs of prosecutions, so that the
poacher had against him not merely a bench of game preservers, but a ring of squires, a sort of
Holy Alliance for the punishment of social rebels, which drew its meshes not round a parish but
round a county. Simultaneously, as we have seen, a general change was coming over the
circumstances and position of the poor. The mass of the people were losing their rights and
independence; they were being forced into an absolute dependence on wages, and were living on
the brink of famine. These two developments must be kept in mind in watching the building up of the
game code in the last phase of the ancient régime.
The Acts for protecting game passed after the accession of George III are in a crescendo of
fierceness. The first important Act was passed in 1770. Under this Act any one who killed game of
any kind between sunsetting and sunrising, or used any gun, or dog, snare, net, or other engine for
destroying game at night, was, on conviction by one witness before one Justice of the Peace, to be
punished with imprisonment for not less than three months or more than six. For a subsequent
offence he was to be imprisoned for not more than twelve months or less than six, and to be
whipped publicly between the hours of twelve and one o'clock. This was light punishment compared
with the measures that were to follow. In the year 1800, the year of Marengo, when all England was
braced up for its great duel with the common enemy of freedom and order, and the labourers were
told every day that they would be the first to suffer if Napoleon landed in England, the English
Parliament found time to pass another Act to punish poachers, and to teach justice to mend her
slow pace. By this Act when two or more persons were found in any forest, chase, park, wood,
plantation, paddock, field, meadow, or other open or enclosed ground, having any gun, net, engine,
or other instrument, with the intent to destroy, take, or kill game, they were to be seized by keepers
or servants, and on conviction before a J.P., they were to be treated as rogues and vagabonds
under the Act of 1744, i.e., they were to be punished by imprisonment with hard labour; an
incorrigible rogue, i.e., a second offender, was to be imprisoned for two years with whipping.
Further, if the offender was over twelve years of age, the magistrates might sentence him to serve in
the army or navy. If an incorrigible rogue escaped from the House of Correction he was to be liable
to transportation for seven years.
Two consequences followed from this Act. Now that punishment was made so severe, the poacher
had a strong reason for violence: surrender meant service in a condemned regiment, and he
therefore took the risks of resistance. The second consequence was the practice of poaching in
large groups. The organisation of poaching gangs was not a natural development of the industry; it
was adopted in self-defence.(38*) This Act led inevitably to those battles between gamekeepers and
labourers that became so conspicuous a feature of English life at this time, and in 1803 Lord
Ellenborough passed an Act which provided that any persons who presented a gun or tried, to stab
or cut 'with intent to obstruct, resist, or prevent the lawful apprehension or detainer of the person or
persons so stabbing or cutting, or the lawful apprehension or detainer of any of his, her, or their
accomplices for any offences for which he, she, or they may respectively be liable by law to be
apprehended, imprisoned, or detained,' should suffer death as a felon. In 1816, when peace and the
fall of prices were bringing new problems in their train, there went through Parliament, without a
syllable of debate, a Bill of which Romilly said that no parallel to it could be found in the laws of any
country in the world. By that Act a person who was found at night unarmed, but with a net for
poaching, in any forest, chase, or park was to be punished by transportation for seven years. This
Act Romilly induced Parliament to repeal in the following year, but the Act that took its place only
softened the law to the extent of withdrawing this punishment from persons found with nets, but
without guns or bludgeons: it enacted that any person so found, armed with gun, crossbow,
firearms, bludgeon, or any other offensive weapon, was to be tried at Quarter Sessions, and if
convicted, to be sentenced to transportation for seven years: if such offender were to return to Great
Britain before his time was over, he was to be transported for the rest of his life.(39*)
This savage Act, though by no means a dead letter, as Parliamentary Returns show, seems to have
defeated its own end, for in 1828 it was repealed, because, as Lord Wharncliffe told the House of
Lords, there was a certain reluctance on the part of juries to convict a prisoner, when they knew that
conviction would be followed by transportation. The new Act of 1828, which allowed a person to be
convicted before two magistrates, reserved transportation for the third offence, punishing the first
offence by three months', and the second by six months' imprisonment. But the convicted person
had to find sureties after his release, or else go back to hard labour for another six months if it was a
first offence, or another twelve months if it was his second. Further, if three men were found in a
wood and one of them carried a gun or bludgeon, all three were liable to be transported for fourteen
years.(40*) Althorp's Bill of 1831 which abolished the qualifications of the Act of Charles II, gave the
right to shoot to every landowner who took out a certificate, and made the sale of game legal,
proposed in its original form to alter these punishments, making that for the first and second
offences rather more severe (four and eight months), and that for the third, two years' imprisonment.
In Committee in the House of Commons the two years were reduced to one year on the proposal of
Orator Hunt. The House of Lords, however, restored the punishments of the Act of 1828.
These were the main Acts for punishing poachers that were passed during the last phase of the
ancient régime. How large a part they played in English life may be imagined from a fact mentioned
by the duke of Richmond in 1831.(41*) In the three years between 1827 and 1830 one in seven of
all the criminal convictions in the country were convictions under the Game Code. The number of
persons so convicted was 8502, many of them being under eighteen. Some of them had been
transported for life, and some for seven or fourteen years. In some years the proportion was still
higher.(42*) We must remember, too, what kind of judges had tried many of these men and boys.
'There is not a worse-constituted tribunal on the face of the earth,' said Brougham in 1828, 'not even
that of the Turkish Cadi, than that at which summary convictions on the Game Laws constantly take
place; I mean a bench or a brace of sporting justices. I am far from saying that, on such subjects,
they are actuated by corrupt motives; but they are undoubtedly instigated by their abhorrence of that
caput lupinum, that hostis humani generis, as an Honourable Friend of mine once called him in his
place, that fera naturae -- a poacher. From their decisions on those points, where their passions are
the most likely to mislead them, no appeal in reality lies to a more calm and unprejudiced tribunal;
for, unless they set out any matter illegal on the face of the conviction, you remove the record in
vain.'(43*)
The close relation of this great increase of crime to the general distress was universally recognised.
Cobbett tells us that a gentleman in Surrey asked a young man, who was cracking stones on the
roadside, how he could live upon half a crown a week. 'I don't live upon it,' said he. 'How do you live
then?' 'Why,' said he, 'I poach: it is better to be hanged than to be starved to death.'(44*) This story
receives illustration after illustration in the evidence taken by Parliamentary Committees. The visiting
Justices of the Prisons in Bedfordshire reported in 1827 that the great increase in commitments, and
particularly the number of commitments for offences against the Game Laws, called for an inquiry.
More than a third of the commitments during the last quarter had been for such offences. The
Report continues:--
'In many parishes in this county the wages given to young unmarried agricultural labourers, in the
full strength and vigour of life, seldom exceed 3s. or 3s. 6d. a week, paid to them, generally, under
the description of roundsmen, by the overseers out of the poor rates; and often in the immediate
vicinity of the dwellings of such half-starved labourers there are abundantly-stocked preserves of
game, in which, during a single night, these dissatisfied young men can obtain a rich booty by
snaring hares and taking or killing pheasants... offences which they cannot be brought to
acknowledge to be any violation of private property. Detection generally leads to their imprisonment,
and imprisonment introduces these youths to familiarity with criminals of other descriptions, and
thus they become rapidly abandoned to unlawful pursuits and a life of crime.'(45*) Mr. Orridge,
Governor of the Gaol of Bury St. Edmunds, gave to the Committee on Commitments and
Convictions(46*) the following figures of prisoners committed to the House of Correction for certain
years: --
1805, 221 1815, 387 1824, 457
1806, 192 1816, 476 1825, 439
1807, 173 1817, 430 1826, 573.
He stated that the great increase in the number of commitments began in the year 1815 with the
depression of agriculture and the great dearth of employment: that men were employed on the
roads at very low rates: that the commitments under the Game Laws which in 1810 were five, in
1811 four, and in 1812 two, were seventy-five in 1822, a year of great agricultural distress, sixty in
1823, sixty-one in 1824, and seventy-one in 1825. Some men were poachers from the love of sport,
but the majority from distress. Mr. Pym, a magistrate in Cambridgeshire, and Sir Thomas Baring, a
magistrate for Hampshire, gave similar evidence as to the cause of the increase of crime, and
particularly of poaching, in these counties. Mr. Bishop, a Bow Street officer, whose business it was
to mix with the poachers in public-houses and learn their secrets, told the Committee on the Game
Laws in 1823 that there had not been employment for the labouring poor in most of the places he
had visited. Perhaps the most graphic picture of the relation of distress to crime is given in a
pamphlet, Thoughts and Suggestions on the Present Condition of the Country, published in 1830 by
Mr. Potter Macqueen, late M.P. for Bedford.
'In January 1829, there were ninety-six prisoners for trial in Bedford Gaol, of whom seventy-six were
able-bodied men, in the prime of life, and, chiefly, of general good character, who were driven to
crime by sheer want, and who would have been valuable subjects had they been placed in a
situation, where, by the exercise of their health and strength, they could have earned a subsistence.
There were in this number eighteen poachers, awaiting trial for the capital offence of using arms in
self-defence when attacked by game-keepers; of these eighteen men, one only was not a parish
pauper, and he was the agent of the London poulterers, who, passing under the apparent vocation
of a rat-catcher, paid these poor creatures more in one night than they could obtain from the
overseer for a week's labour. I conversed with each of these men singly, and made minutes of their
mode of life. The two first I will mention are the two brothers, the Lilleys, in custody under a charge
of firing on and wounding a keeper, who endeavoured to apprehend them whilst poaching. They
were two remarkably fine young men, and very respectably connected. The elder, twenty-eight
years of age, married, with two small children. When I inquired how he could lend himself to such a
wretched course of life, the poor fellow replied: 'Sir, I had a pregnant wife, with one infant at her
knee, and another at her breast; I was anxious to obtain work, I offered myself in all directions, but
without success; if I went to a distance, I was told to go back to my parish, and when I did so, I was
allowed.... What? Why, for myself, my babes, and my wife, in a condition requiring more than
common support, and unable to labour, I was allowed 7s. a week for all; for which I was expected to
work on the roads from light to dark, and to pay three guineas a year for the hovel which sheltered
us.' The other brother, aged twenty-two, unmarried, received 6d. a day. These men were hanged at
the spring assizes. Of the others, ten were single men, their ages varying from seventeen to twenty-
seven. Many had never been in gaol before, and were considered of good character. Six of them
were on the roads at 6d. per day. Two could not obtain even this pittance. One had been refused
relief on the ground that he had shortly previous obtained a profitable piece of jobwork, and one had
existed on 1s. 6d. during the fortnight before he joined the gang in question. Of five married men,
two with wife and two children received 7s., two with wife and one child 6s., and one with wife and
four small children 11s.'(47*)
If we wish to obtain a complete picture of the social life of the time, it is not enough to study the
construction of this vindictive code. We must remember that a sort of civil war was going on
between the labourers and the gamekeepers. The woods in which Tom Jones fought his great fight
with Thwackum and Blifil to cover the flight of Molly Seagrim now echoed on a still and moonless
night with the din of a different sort of battle: the noise of gunshots and blows from bludgeons, and
broken curses from men who knew that, if they were taken, they would never see the English dawn
rise over their homes again: a battle which ended perhaps in the death or wounding of a keeper or
poacher, and the hanging or transportation of some of the favourite Don Quixotes of the village. A
witness before the Committee on the Game Laws said that the poachers preferred a quiet night.
Crabbe, in the poacher poem (Book XXI of Tales of the Hall) which he wrote at the suggestion of
Romilly, takes what would seem to be the more probable view that poachers liked a noisy night:
<poem>
'It was a night such bold desires to move
Strong winds and wintry torrents filled the grove;
The crackling boughs that in the forest fell,
The cawing rooks, the cur's affrighted yell;
The scenes above the wood, the floods below,
Were mix'd, and none the singie sound could know.
"Loud blow the blasts," they cried, "and call us as they blow."'
</poem>
Such an encounter is put into cold arithmetic in an official return like this:(48*) --
'An account of the nineteen persons committed to Warwick Gaol for trial at the Lent Assizes 1829
for shooting and wounding John Slinn at Combe Fields in the County of Warwick whilst
endeavouring to apprehend them for destroying game in the night with the result thereof: --
Above 14 and under 20 years of age 11
Above 20 years of age 8
Capitally convicted and repreived with --
Transportation for life 7
Transportation for 14 years 9
Imprisonment with hard labour
in House of Correction for 2 years 1
Admitted to Evidence 2
Seven peasants exiled for life, nine exiled for fourteen years, and two condemned to the worst exile
of all. In that village at any rate there were many homes that had reason to remember the day when
the pleasures of the rich became the most sacred thing in England.
But the warfare was not conducted only by these methods. For the gentlemen of England, as for the
genius who fought Michael and Gabriel in the great battle in the sixth book of Paradise Lost, science
did not spread her light in vain. There was a certain joy of adventure in a night skirmish, and a man
who saw his wife and children slowly starving, to whom one of those golden birds that was sleeping
on its perch the other side of the hedge, night after night, till the day when it should please the
squire to send a shot through its purple head, meant comfort and even riches for a week, was not
very much afraid of trusting his life and his freedom to his quick ear, his light foot, or at the worst his
powerful arm. So the game preservers invented a cold and terrible demon: they strewed their woods
with spring guns, that dealt death without warning, death without the excitement of battle, death that
could catch the nimblest as he slipped and scrambled through the hiding bracken. The man who fell
in an affray fell fighting, his comrades by his side; it was a grim and uncomforted fate to go out
slowly and alone, lying desolate in the stained bushes, beneath the unheeding sky. It is not clear
when these diabolical engines, as Lord Holland called them, were first introduced, but they were
evidently common by 1817, when Curwen made a passionate protest in the House of Commons,
and declared, 'Better the whole race of game was extinct than that it should owe its preservation to
such cruel expedients.'(49*) Fortunately for England the spring guns, though they scattered murder
and wounds.freely enough (Peel spoke in 1827 of 'daily accidents and misfortunes'), did not choose
their victims with so nice an eye as a Justice of the Peace, and it was often a gamekeeper or a farm
servant who was suddenly tripped up by this lurking death. By 1827 this state of things had become
such a scandal that Parliament intervened and passed an Act, introduced in the Lords by Lord
Suffield, who had made a previous attempt in 1825, to make the setting of spring guns a
misdemeanour.(50*)
The Bill did not pass without considerable opposition. Tennyson, who introduced it in the Commons,
declared that the feudal nobility in ancient France had never possessed a privilege comparable with
this right of killing and maiming, and he said that the fact that Coke of Norfolk(51*) and Lord
Suffield, both large game preservers, refused to employ them showed that they were not necessary.
Members of both Houses of Parliament complained bitterly of the 'morbid sensibility' that inspired
the proposal, and some of them defended spring guns as a labour-saving machine, speaking of
them with the enthusiasm that a manufacturer might bestow on the invention of an Arkwright or a
Crompton. One member of the House of Commons, a Colonel French, opposed the Bill with the
argument that the honest English country gentleman formed 'the very subject and essence of the
English character,' while Lord Ellenborough opposed it in the other House on the ground that it was
contrary to the principles of the English law, which gave a man protection for his property in
proportion to the difficulty with which it could be defended by ordinary means.
The crime for which men were maimed or killed by these engines or torn from their homes by
summary and heartless justice was, it must be remembered, no crime at all in the eyes of the great
majority of their countrymen. At this time the sale of game was prohibited under stern penalties, and
yet every rich man in London, from the Lord Mayor downwards, entertained his guests with game
that he had bought from a poulterer. How had the poulterer bought it? There was no secret about
the business. It was explained to two Select Committees, the first of the House of Commons in
1823, and the second of the House of Lords in 1828, by poulterers who lived by these transactions,
and by police officers who did nothing to interfere with them. Daniel Bishop, for example, one of the
chief Bow Street officers, described the arrangements to the Committee in 1823.(52*)
'Can you state to the Committee, how the Game is brought from the poachers up to London, or
other market?... The poachers generally meet the coachman or guards of the mails or vans, and
deliver it to them after they are out of a town, they do not deliver it in a town; then it is brought up to
London, sometimes to their agents; but the coachmen and guards mostly have their friends in
London where they know how to dispose of it, and they have their contracts made at so much a
brace.... There is no intermediate person between the poacher and the coachman or guard that
conveys it to. town?... Very seldom; generally the head of the gang pays the rest of the men, and he
sends off the Game.... When the game arrives in London, how is it disposed of?... They have their
agents, the bookkeepers at most of the inns, the porters who go out with the carts; any persons they
know may go and get what quantity they like, by sending an order a day or two before; there are
great quantities come up to Leadenhall and Newgate markets.' Nobody in London thought the worse
of a poulterer for buying poached game; and nobody in the country thought any the worse of the
poacher who supplied it. A witness before the Committee in 1823 said that in one village the whole
of the village were poachers, 'the constable of the village, the shoemaker and other inhabitants of
the village.' Another witness before the Lords in 1828 said that occupiers and unqualified proprietors
agreed with the labourers in thinking that poaching was an innocent practice.
Those who wished to reform the Game Laws argued that if the sale of game were legalised, and if
the anomalous qualifications were abolished, the poacher's prize would become much less
valuable, and the temptation would be correspondingly diminished.. This view was corroborated by
the evidence given to the Select Committees. But all such proposals were bitterly attacked by the
great majority of game preservers. Lord Londonderry urged against this reform in 1827 'that it would
deprive the sportsman of his highest gratification... the pleasure of fishing his friends with presents
of game: nobody would care for a present which everybody could give!'(53*) Other game preservers
argued that it was sport that made the English gentlemen such good officers, on which the
Edinburgh Review remarked: 'The hunting which Xenophon and Cicero praise as the best discipline
for forming great generals from its being war in miniature must have been very unlike pheasant
shooting.'(54*) Lord Deerhurst declared, when the proposal was made fourteen years earlier, that
this was not the time to disgust resident gentlemen. The English aristocracy, like the French, would
only consent to live in the country on their own terms. When the squires threatened to turn émigrés
if anybody else was allowed to kill a rabbit, or if a poacher was not put to risk of life and limb,
Sydney Smith gave an answer that would have scandalised the House of Commons, 'If gentlemen
cannot breathe fresh air without injustice, let them putrefy in Cranbourne Court.'
But what about the justice of the laws against poachers? To most members of Parliament there
would have been an element of paradox in such a question. From the discussions on the subject of
the Game Laws a modern reader might suppose that poachers were not men of flesh and blood, but
some kind of vermin. There were a few exceptions. In 1782, when Coke of Norfolk, acting at the
instance of the magistrates of that county, proposed to make the Game Laws more stringent,
Turner, the member for York, made a spirited reply; he 'exclaimed against those laws as cruel and
oppressive on the poor: he said it was a shame that the House should always be enacting laws for
the safety of gentlemen; he wished they would make a few for the good of the poor.... For his own
part, he was convinced, that if he had been a common man, he would have been a poacher, in spite
of all the laws; and he was equally sure that the too great severity of the laws was the cause that the
number of poachers had increased so much.'(55*) Fox (29th April 1796) protested with vigour
against the morality that condemned poachers without mercy, and condoned all the vices of the rich,
but he, with Sheridan, Curwen, Romilly, and a few others were an infinitesimal minority.
The aristocracy had set up a code, under which a man or boy who had offended against the laws,
but had done nothing for which any of his fellows imputed discredit to him, was snatched from his
home, thrown into gaol with thieves and criminals, and perhaps flung to the other side of the world,
leaving his family either to go upon the rates or to pick up a living by such dishonesties as they
could contrive. This last penalty probably meant final separation. Mr. T. G. B. Estcourt, M.P., stated
in evidence before the Select Committee on Secondary Punishments in 1831(56*) that as men who
had been transported were not brought back at the public expense, they scarcely ever returned,
(57*) that agricultural labourers specially dreaded transportation, because it meant 'entire
separation' from 'former associates, relations, and friends,' and that since he and his brother
magistrates in Wiltshire had taken to transporting more freely, committals had decreased. The
special misery that transportation inflicted on men of this class is illustrated in Marcus Clarke's
famous novel, For the Term of His Natural Life. In the passage describing the barracoon on the
transport ship, Clarke throws on the screen all the different types of character -- forgers,
housebreakers, cracksmen, footpads -- penned up in that poisonous prison. 'The poacher grimly
thinking of his sick wife and children would start as the night-house ruffian clapped him on the
shoulder and bade him with a curse to take good heart and be a man.' Readers of Mr. Hudson's
character sketches of the modern Wiltshire labourer can imagine the scene. To the lad who had
never been outside his own village such a society must have been unspeakably alien and terrible: a
ring of callous and mocking faces, hardened, by crime and wrong and base punishment, to make
bitter ridicule of all the memories of home and boyhood and innocence that were surging and
breaking round his simple heart.
The growing brutality of the Game Laws, if it is the chief, is not the only illustration of the extent to
which the pressure of poverty was driving the labourers to press upon law and order, and the kind of
measures that the ruling class took to protect its property. Another illustration is the Malicious
Trespass Act.
In 1820 Parliament passed an Act which provided that any person convicted before a single J.P.
within four months of the act of doing any malicious injury to any building, hedge, fence, tree, wood,
or underwood was to pay damage not exceeding £5, and if he was unable to pay these damages he
was to be sent to hard labour in a common gaol or House of Correction for three months. The law
before the passing of this Act was as it is to-day, i.e., the remedy lay in an action at law against the
trespasser, and the trespasser under the Act of William and Mary had to pay damages. The Act of
1820 was passed without any debate that is reported in Hansard, but it is not unreasonable to
assume that it was demanded for the protection of enclosures and game preserves.(58*) This Act
exempted one set of persons entirely, 'persons engaged in hunting, and qualified persons in pursuit
of game.' These privileged gentlemen could do as much injury as they pleased.
One clause provided that every male offender under sixteen who did not pay damages, and all costs
and charges and expenses forthwith, might be sent by the magistrate to hard labour in the House of
Correction for six weeks. Thus a child who broke a bough from a tree by the roadside might be sent
by the magistrate, who would in many cases be the owner of the tree, to the House of Correction,
there to learn the ways of criminals at an age when the magistrate's own children were about half-
way through their luxurious education. This was no brutum fulmen. Children were sent to prison in
great numbers.(59*) Brougham said in 1828: 'There was a Bill introduced by the Rt. Hon.
Gentleman opposite for extending the payment of expenses of witnesses and prosecutors out of the
county rates. It is not to be doubted that it has greatly increased the number of Commitments, and
has been the cause of many persons being brought to trial, who ought to have been discharged by
the Magistrates. The habit of committing, from this and other causes, has grievously increased
everywhere of late, and especially of boys. Eighteen hundred and odd, many of them mere children,
have been committed in the Warwick district during the last seven years.'(60*) The Governor of the
House of Correction in Coldbath Fields, giving evidence before the Committee on Secondary
Punishments in 1831, said that he had under his charge a boy of ten years old who had been in
prison eight times. Capper, the Superintendent of the Convict Establishment, told the same
Committee that some of the boy convicts were so young that they could scarcely put on their
clothes, and that they had to be dressed. Richard Potter's diary for 1813 contains this. entry. 'Oct.
13. -- I was attending to give evidence against a man. Afterwards, two boys, John and Thomas
Clough, aged 12 and 10 years, were tried and found guilty of stealing some Irish linen out of Joseph
Thorley's warehouse during the dinner hour. The Chairman sentenced them to seven years'
transportation. On its being pronounced, the Mother of those unfortunate boys came to the Bar to
her children, and with them was in great agony, imploring mercy of the Bench. With difficulty the
children were removed. The scene was so horrifying I could remain no longer in court.'(61*)
Parliament put these tremendous weapons into the hands of men who believed in using them, who
administered the law on the principle by which Sir William Dyott regulated his conduct as a
magistrate, that 'nothing but the terror of human suffering can avail to prevent crime.'
The class that had, in Goldsmith's words, hung round 'our paltriest possessions with gibbetts' never
doubted its power to do full justice to the helpless creatures who tumbled into the net of the law.
Until 1836 a man accused of a felony was not allowed to employ counsel to make his defence in the
Court. His counsel (if he could afford to have one) could examine and cross-examine witnesses,
and that was all; the prisoner, whatever his condition of mind, or his condition of body, had to
answer the speech of the prosecuting counsel himself. In nine cases out of ten he was quite an
unlearned man; he was swept into the glare of the Court blinking from long months of imprisonment
in dark cells; the case against him was woven into a complete and perfect story by the skilled
fingers of a lawyer, and it was left to this rude and illiterate man, by the aid of his own memory and
his own imagination, his life on the razor's edge, his mind bewildered by his strange and terrible
surroundings, to pick that story to pieces, to expose what was mere and doubtful inference, to put a
different completion on a long and tangled set of events, to show how a turn here or a turn there in
the narrative would change black into white and apparent guilt into manifest innocence. Sydney
Smith, whose opinions on the importance of giving the poor a fair trial were as enlightened as his
opinions on their proper treatment in prison were backward, has described the scene.
<ex>
'It is a most affecting moment in a Court of Justice, when the evidence has all been heard, and the
Judge asks the prisoner what he has to say in his defence. The prisoner who has (by great
exertions, perhaps of his friends) saved up money enough to procure Counsel, says to the Judge
"that he leaves his defence to his Counsel." We have often blushed for English humanity to hear the
reply. "Your Counsel cannot speak for you, you must speak for yourself;" and this is the reply given
to a poor girl of eighteen -- to a foreigner -- to a deaf man -- to a stammerer -- to the sick to the
feeble -- to the old -- to the most abject and ignorant of human beings!... How often have we seen a
poor wretch, struggling against the agonies of his spirit, and the rudeness of his conceptions, and
his awe of better-dressed men and better-taught men, and the shame which the accusation has
brought upon his head, and the sight of his parents and children gazing at him in the Court, for the
last time perhaps, and after a long absence!'(62*)
</ex>
Brougham said in the House of Commons that there was no man who visited the Criminal Courts
who did not see the fearful odds against the prisoner. This anomaly was peculiar to England, and in
England it was peculiar to cases of felony. Men tried for misdemeanours, or for treason, or before
the House of Lords could answer by the mouth of counsel. It was only in those cases where the
prisoners were almost always poor and uneducated men and women, as Lord Althorp pointed out in
an admirable speech in the House of Commons, that the accused was left to shift for himself. Twice,
in 1824 and in 1826, the House of Commons refused leave to bring in a Bill to redress this flagrant
injustice, encouraged in that refusal not only by Canning, but, what is much more surprising, by
Peel.
The favorite argument against this reform, taking precedence of the arguments that to allow persons
the aid of counsel in putting their statement of fact would make justice slower, more expensive, and
more theatrical, was the contention that the judge did, in point of fact, represent the interest of the
prisoner: a confused plea which it did not require any very highly developed gift of penetration to
dissect. But how far, in point of fact, were the judges able to enter into the poor prisoner's mind?
They had the power of sentencing to death for hundreds of trivial offences. It was the custom to
pass the brutal sentence which the law allowed to be inflicted for felonies. and then to commute it in
all except a few cases. By what considerations did judges decide when to be severe? Lord
Ellenborough told Lauderdale that he had left a man to be hanged at the Worcester Assizes
because he lolled out his tongue and pretended to be an idiot, on which Lauderdale asked the Chief
Justice what law there was to punish that particular offence with death. We learn from Romilly's
Memoirs(63*) that one judge left three men to be hanged for thefts at the Maidstone Assizes
because none of them could bring a witness to his character.
The same disposition to trust to the discretion of the judge, which Camden described as the law of
tyrants, explains the vitality of the system of prescribing death as the punishment for hundreds of
paltry offences. During the last fifty years the energy of Parliament in passing Enclosure Acts had
been only rivalled by its energy in creating capital offences. The result was a penal code which had
been condemned by almost every Englishman of repute of the most various opinions, from
Blackstone, Johnson, and Goldsmith to Burke and Bentham. This system made the poor man the
prey of his rich neighbours. The most furious punishments were held in terrorem over the heads of
prisoners, and the wretched man who was caught in the net was exposed to all the animosities that
he might have provoked in his ordinary life. Dr. Parr put this point writing to Romilly in 1811.
'There is, indeed, one consideration in the case of bad men which ought to have a greater weight
than it usually has in the minds of the Judges, dislike from party, quarrels with servants or
neighbours, offence justly or unjustly taken in a quarrel, jealousy about game, and twenty other
matters of the same sort, frequently induce men to wish to get rid of a convicted person: and well
does it behove every Judge to be sure that the person who recommends the execution of the
sentence is a man of veracity, of sense, of impartiality and kindness of nature in the habitual
character of his mind. I remember hearing from Sergeant Whitaker that, while he was trying a man
for a capital offence at Norwich, a person brought him a message from the late Lord Suffield, "that
the prisoner was a good-for-nothing fellow, and he hoped the Judge would look to him;" and the
Sergeant kindled with indignation, and exclaimed, in the hearing of the Court, "Zounds! would Sir
Harbord Harbord have me condemn the man before I have tried. him?" What Sir Harbord did during
the trial, many squires and justices of the peace, upon other occasions, do after it; and were I a
Judge, I should listen with great caution to all unfavourable representations. The rich, the proud, the
irascible, and the vindictive are very unfit to estimate the value of life to their inferiors.'(64*)
We can see how the squires and the justices would close in round a man of whom they wanted, with
the best intentions in the world, to rid their parish, woods, and warrens, when the punishment he
was to receive turned on his reputation as it was estimated by the gentlemen of his neighbourhood.
Was Sir Harbord Harbord very far removed from the state of mind described in the Sixth Satire of
Juvenal?
<poem>
'"Pone crucem servo." "Meruit quo crimine servus.
Supplicium? quis testis adest? quis detulit? Audi:
Nulla unquam de morte hominis cunctatio longa est."
"O demens, ita servus homo est? nil fecerit, esto:
Hoc volo, sic jubeo, sit pro ratione voluntas,"'
</poem>
And Sir Harbord Harbord had in hundreds of cases what he had not in this case, the power to wreak
his anger on 'a good-for-nothing fellow.'
When Romilly entered on his noble crusade and tried very cautiously to persuade Parliament to
repeal the death penalty in cases in which it was rarely carried out, he found the chief obstacle in his
way was the fear that became common among the governing class at this time, the fear that existing
methods of punishment were ceasing to be deterrent. In 1810 he carried his Bill, for abolishing this
penalty for the crime of stealing privately to the amount of five shillings in a shop, through the House
of Commons, and the Bill was introduced in the House of Lords by Lord Holland. There it was
rejected by twenty-one to eleven, the majority including the Archbishop of Canterbury and six other
bishops.(65*) The chief speeches against the Bill were made by Eldon and Ellenborough.
Ellenborough argued that transportation was regarded, and justly regarded, by those who violated
the law as 'a summer airing by an easy migration to a milder climate.'
The nightmare that punishment was growing gentle and attractive to the poor came to haunt the
mind of the governing class. It was founded on the belief that as human wretchedness was
increasing, there was a sort of law of Malthus, by which human endurance tended to outgrow the
resources of repression. The agricultural labourers were sinking into such a deplorable plight that
some of them found it a relief to be committed to the House of Correction, where, at least, they
obtained food and employment, and the magistrates began to fear in consequence that ordinary
punishments could no longer be regarded as deterrent, and to reason that some condition had yet to
be discovered which would be more miserable than the general existence of the poor. The justices
who punished Wiltshire poachers found such an El Dorado of unhappiness in transportation. But
disturbing rumours came to the ears of the authorities that transportation was not thought a very
terrible punishment after all, and the Government sent out to Sir George Arthur, the Governor of Van
Diemen's Land, certain complaints of this kind. The answer which the Governor returned is
published with the Report of the Committee on Secondary Punishments, and the complete
correspondence forms a very remarkable set of Parliamentary Papers. The Governor pointed out
that these complaints, which made such an impression on Lord Melbourne, came from employers in
Australia, who wanted to have greater control over their servants. Arthur was no sentimentalist; his
sympathies had been drilled in two hard schools, the army and the government of prisoners; his
account of his own methods shows that in describing the life of a convict he was in no danger of
falling into the exaggerations or the rhetoric of pity. In these letters he made it very clear that nobody
who knew what transportation meant could ever make the mistake of thinking it a light punishment.
The ordinary convict was assigned to a settler. 'Deprived of liberty, exposed to all the caprice of the
family to whose service he may happen to be assigned, and subject to the most summary laws, the
condition of a convict in no respect differs from that of a slave, except that his master cannot apply
corporal punishment by his own hands or those of his overseer, and has a property in him for a
limited period only.' Further, 'idleness and insolence of expression, or even of looks, anything
betraying the insurgent spirit, subjects him to the chain-gang, or the triangle, or to hard labour on the
roads.'(66*) We can imagine what the life of an ordinary convict might become. In earlier days every
convict who went out began as an assigned servant, and it was only for misconduct in the colony or
on the way thither that he was sent to a Penal Settlement, but the growing alarm of the ruling class
on the subject of punishment led to a demand for more drastic sentences, and shortly after the close
of our period Lord Melbourne introduced a new system, under which convicts might be sentenced
from home to the Penal Settlement, and any judge who thought badly of a prisoner might add this
hideous punishment to transportation.
The life of these Settlements has been described in one of the most vivid and terrible books ever
written. Nobody can read Marcus Clarke's great novel without feeling that the methods of barbarism
had done their worst and most devilish in Macquarie Harbour and Port Arthur. The lot of the
prisoners in Resurrection is by comparison a paradise. Not a single feature that can revolt and
stupefy the imagination is wanting to the picture. Children of ten committing suicide, men murdering
each other by compact aS an escape from a hell they could no longer bear, prisoners receiving a
death sentence with ecstasies of delight, punishments inflicted that are indistinguishable from
torture, men stealing into the parched bush in groups, in the horrible hope that one or two of them
might make their way to freedom by devouring their comrades -- an atmosphere in which the last
faint glimmer of self-respect and human feeling was extinguished by incessant and degrading
cruelty. Few books have been written in any language more terrible to read. Yet not a single incident
or feature is imaginary: the whole picture is drawn from the cold facts of the official reports.(67*) And
this system was not the invention of some Nero or Caligula; it was the system imposed by men of
gentle and refined manners, who talked to each other in Virgil and Lucan of liberty and justice, who
would have died without a murmur to save a French princess from an hour's pain or shame, who put
down the abominations of the Slave Trade, and allowed Clive and Warren Hastings to be indicted at
the bar of public opinion as monsters of inhumanity; and it was imposed by them from the belief that
as the poor were becoming poorer, only a system of punishment that was becoming more brutal
could deter them from crime.
If we want to understand how completely all their natural feelings were lost in this absorbing fear, we
must turn to the picture given by an observer who was outside their world; an observer who could
enter into the misery of the punished, and could describe what transportation meant to boys of nine
and ten, exposed to the most brutal appetites of savage men; to chained convicts, packed for the
night in boxes so narrow that they could only lie on one side; to crushed and broken men, whose
only prayer it was to die. From him we learn how these scenes and surroundings impressed a mind
that could look upon a convict settlement as a society of living men and boys, and not merely as the
Cloaca Maxima of property and order.(68*)
NOTES:
1. Poor Law Report, 1834, p. 60.
2. The big landlord under this method shared the privilege of paying the labourer's wages with the
small farmers.
3. Tribune, vol. ii, p. 317.
4. Ibid., p. 339.
5. Poor Law Commission Report, of 1834, p. 126.
6. See Curtler's Short History of Agriculture, p. 249.
7. Smart, Economic Annals, p. 36.
8. 'It was during the war that the cottagers of England were chiefly deprived of the little pieces of
land and garden, and made solely dependent for subsistence on the wages of their daily labour, or
the poor rates. Land, and the produce of it, had become so valuable, that the labourer was envied
the occupation of the smallest piece of ground which he possessed: and even "the bare-worn
common" was denied.' Kentish Chronicle, December 14, 1830.
9. Curtler, p. 243.
10. Agricultural State of the Kingdom, Board of Agriculture, 1816, p. 7.
11. Ibid., pp. 250-1.
12. p. 144.
13. C.C. Western (1767-1844); whig M.P., 1790-1832; chief representative of agricultural interests;
made peer in 1833.
14. Annual Register, 1816, Chron. p. 67.
15. The disturbances at Brandon ceased immediately on the concession of the demands of rioters;
flour was reduced to 2s. 6d. a stone, and wages were raised for two weeks to 2s. a head. The
rioters were contented, and peace was restored. -- Times, May 23, 1816.
16. Annual Register, 1816, Chron., p. 67.
17. Cambridge Chronicle, June 28, 1816.
18. Times, June 26. A curious irony has placed side by side with the account in the Annual Register
of the execution of the five men who were hung for their share in this spasm of starvation and
despair, the report of a meeting, with the inevitable Wilberforce in the chair, for raising a subscription
for rebuilding the Protestant Church at Copenhagen, which had been destroyed by the British Fleet
at the bombardment of Copenhagen in 1807.
19. Agricultural State of the Kingdom, p. 13.
20. 59 George III, c. 50.
21. See Annual Register, 1819, p. 320.
22. Those assessed at £100 were to have two votes, those at £150 three votes, and those at £400
four votes. Whitbread did not propose to copy the provision of Gilbert's Act, which withdrew all
voting power in vestries in parishes that adopted that Act from persons assessed at less than £5.
23. Political Register, August 29, 1807, p. 329.
24. Letter to Samuel Whitbread, M. P., on his proposed Bill for the Amendment of the Poor Laws,
1807.
25. 58 George III, c. 69.
26. 59 George III, c. 12.
27. H.O. Papers, Municipal and Provincial.
28. Of course the system was only one of the causes of this difference in wages.
29. p. 99.
30. See Agricultural State of the Kingdom, Board of Agriculture, p. 231, and Cobbett, Political
Register, October 5, 1816.
31. pp. 21 and 23.
32. The table is given in the Report of the Committee on the Poor Laws, 1828.
33. Cobbett, Political Register, September 21, 1822. Cobbett wrote one of his liveliest articles on
this scale, setting out the number of livings held by the five parsons, and various circumstances
connected with their families.
34. Ibid., September 9, 1826.
35. Rural Rides, p. 17.
36. Ibid., p. 609.
37. The farmers were usually sympathetic to poaching as a habit, but it was not so much from a
perception of its economic tendencies, as from a general resentment against the Game Laws.
38. See Cobbett; Letters to Peel; Political Register; and Dr Hunt's evidence before the Select
Committee on Criminal Commitments and Convictions, 1827.
39. A manifesto was published in a Bath paper in reply to this Act; it is quoted by Sydney Smith,
Essays, p. 263: 'Take Notice. -- We have lately heard and seen that there is an act passed, and
whatever poacher is caught destroying the game is to be transported for seven years -- This is
English Liberty!
'Now we do swear to each other that the first of our company that this law is inflicted on, that there
shall not be one gentleman's seat in our country escape the rage of fire. The first that impeaches
shall be shot. We have sworn not to impeach. You may think it a treat, but they will find it a reality.
The Game Laws were too severe before. The Lord of all men sent these animals for the peasants
as well as for the prince. God will not let his people be oppressed. He will assist us in our
undertaking, and we will execute it with caution.'
40. The Archbishop of Canterbury prosecuted a man under this Act in January 1831, for rescuing a
poacher from a gameskeeper without violence, on the ground that he thought it his duty to enforce
the provisions of the Act.
41. House of Lords, September 19, 1831.
42. A magistrate wrote to Sir R. Peel in 1827 to say that many magistrates sent in very imperfect
returns of convictions, and that the true number far exceeded the records. -- Webb, Parish and
Country, p. 598 note.
43. Brougham Speeches, vol. ii, p. 373.
44. Political Register, March 29, 1823, vol. xxiv., p. 796.
45. Select Committee on Criminal Committee and Convictions, 1827, p. 30.
46. Ibid., p. 39.
47. Quoted in Times, September 18, 1830.
48. Return of Convictions under the Game Laws from 1827 to 1830. Ordered by the House of
Commons to be printed, February 14, 1831, p. 4.
49. Hansard, June 9, 1817.
50. Scotland was exempted from the operation of this statute, for whilst the Bill was going through
Parliament, a case raised in a Scottish Court ended in a unanimous decision by the six Judges of
the High Court of Justiciary that killing by a spring gun was murder. Hence the milder provisions of
this Act were not required. See Annual Register, 1827, p. 185, and Chron. p. 116.
51. That Coke of Norfolk did not err on the side of mercy towards poachers is clear from this record.
His biographer (Mrs Stirling) states that one of his first efforts in Parliament was to introduce a Bill to
punish night poaching.
52. p. 29 ff.
53. Annual Register, 1827, p. 184.
54. Edinburgh Review, December 1831.
55. Parliamentary Register, February 25, 1782.
56. p. 42.
57. 'Speaking now of country and agricultural parishes, I do not know above one instance in all my
experience.'
58. Some Enclosure Acts prescribe special penalties for the breaking of fences. See cases of Haute
Huntre and Croydon in Appendix.
59. See Mr Estcourt's evidence before Select Committee on Secondary Punishments, 1831, p. 41.
60. Present State of the Law, p. 41.
61. From Ploughshares to Parliament, p. 186; the Annual Register for 1791 records the execution of
two boys at Newport for stealing, one aged fourteen and the other fifteen.
62. Sydney Smith, Essays, p. 487.
63. Vol. ii, p. 153.
64. Romilly, Memoirs, vol. ii, p. 181.
65. It was again rejected in 1813 by twenty to fifteen, the majority including five bishops.
66. Correspondence on the Subject of Secondary Punishments, 1834, p. 22.
67. See Select Committee on Secondary Punishments, 1831, and Select Committee on
Transportation, 1838.
68. See evidence of Dr. Ullathorne, Roman Catholic Vicar-General of New Holland and Van
Diemen's Land, before the 1838 Committee on Transportation.
Chapter Eight
The Isolation of the Poor
The upper classes, to whom the fact that the labourers were more wretched in 1830 than they had,
been in 1795 was a reason for making punishment more severe, were not deliberately callous and
cruel in their neglect of all this growing misery and hunger. Most of those who thought seriously
about it had learnt a reasoned insensibility from the stern Sibyl of the political economy in fashion,
that strange and partial interpretation of Adam Smith, Malthus and Ricardo which was then in full
power. This political economy had robbed poverty of its sting for the rich by representing it as
Nature's medicine, bitter indeed, but less bitter than any medicine that man could prescribe. If
poverty was sharper at one time than another, this only meant that society was more than ever in
need of this medicine. But the governing class as a whole did not think out any such scheme or
order of society, or master the new science of misery and vice. They thought of the poor not in
relation to the mysterious forces of Nature, but in relation to the privileges of their own class in which
they saw no mystery at all. Their state of mind is presented in a passage in Bolingbroke's Idea of a
Patriot King. 'As men are apt to make themselves the measure of all being, so they make
themselves the final cause of all creation. Thus the reputed orthodox philosophers in all ages have
taught that the world was made for man, the earth for him to inhabit, and all the luminous bodies in
the immense expanse around us for him to gaze at. Kings do no more, nay not so much, when they
imagine themselves the final cause for which societies were formed and governments instituted.' If
we read 'the aristocracy' for 'kings' we shall have a complete analysis of the social philosophy of the
ruling class. It was from this centre that they looked out upon the world. When the misery of the poor
reacted on their own comfort, as in the case of poaching or crime or the pressure on the rates, they
were aware of it and took measures to protect their property, but of any social problem outside these
relations they were entirely unconscious. Their philosophy and their religion taught them that it was
the duty of the rich to be benevolent, and of the poor to be patient and industrious. The rich were
ready to do their part, and all they asked of the poor was that they should learn to bear their lot with
resignation. Burke had laid down the true and full philosophy of social life once and for all. 'Good
order is the foundation of all good things. To be enabled to acquire, the people, without being
servile, must be tractable and obedient. The magistrate must have his reverence, the laws their
authority. The body of the people must not find the principles of natural subordination by art rooted
out of their minds. They must respect that property of which they cannot partake. They must labour
to obtain what by labour can be obtained; and when they find, as they commonly do, the success
disproportioned to the endeavour, they must be taught their consolation in the final proportions of
eternal justice.'(1*)
The upper classes, looking upon the world in this way, considered that it was the duty of the poor
man to adapt himself, his tastes, his habits, and his ambitions, to the arrangements of a society
which it had pleased Providence to organise on this interesting plan. We have in the pages of Eden
the portrait of the ideal poor woman, whose life showed what could be done if poverty were faced in
the proper spirit. 'Anne Hurst was born at Witley in Surrey: there she lived the whole period of a long
life, and there she died. As soon as she was thought able to work, she went to service: there, before
she was twenty, she married James Strudwick, who, like her own father, was a day labourer. With
this husband she lived, a prolific, hardworking, contented wife, somewhat more than fifty years. He
worked more than threescore years on one farm, and his wages, summer and winter, were regularly
a shilling a day. He never asked more nor was never offered less. They had between them seven
children:. and lived to see six daughters married and three the mothers of sixteen children: all of
whom were brought up, or are bringing up, to be day labourers. Strudwick continued to work till
within seven weeks of the day of his death, and at the age of four score, in 1787, he closed, in
peace, a not inglorious life; for, to the day of his death, he never received a farthing in the way of
parochial aid. His wife saved him about seven years, and though bent with age and infirmities, and
little able to work, excepting as a weeder in a gentleman's garden, she also was too proud to ask or
receive any relief from the parish. For six or seven of the last years of her life, she received twenty
shillings a year from the person who favoured me with this account, which he drew up from her own
mouth. With all her virtue, and all her merit, she yet was not much liked in her neighbourhood;
people in affluence thought her haughty, and the Paupers of the parish, seeing, as they could not
help seeing, that her life was a reproach to theirs, aggravated all her little failings. Yet, the worst
thing they had to say of her was, that she was proud; which, they said, was manifested by the way in
which she buried her husband. Resolute, as she owned she was, to have the funeral, and
everything that related to it, what she called decent, nothing could dissuade her from having handles
to his coffin and a plate on it, mentioning his age. She was also charged with having behaved
herself crossly and peevishly towards one of her sons-in-law, who was a mason and went regularly
every Saturday evening to the ale house as he said just to drink a pot of beer. James Strudwick in
all his life, as she often told this ungracious son-in-law, never spent five shillings in any idleness:
luckily (as she was sure to add) he had it not to spend. A more serious charge against her was that,
living to a great age, and but little able to work, she grew to be seriously afraid, that, at last, she
might become chargeable to the parish (the heaviest, in her estimation, of all human calamities),
and that thus alarmed she did suffer herself more than once, during the exacerbations of a fit of
distempered despondency, peevishly (and perhaps petulantly) to exclaim that God Almighty, by
suffering her to remain so long upon earth, seemed actually to have forgotten her.' 'Such,' concludes
Eden, 'are the simple annals of Dame Strudwick: and her historian, partial to his subject, closes it
with lamenting that such village memoirs have not oftener been sought for and recorded.'(2*) This
was the ideal character for the cottage. How Eden or anybody else would have hated this poor
woman in whom every kindly feeling had been starved to death if she had been in his own class!
We know from Creevey what his friends thought of 'the stingy kip' Lambton when they found
themselves under his roof, where 'a round of beef at a side table was run at with as much keenness
as a banker's shop before a stoppage.' A little peevishness or even petulance with God Almighty
would not have seemed the most serious charge that could be brought against such a neighbour.
But if every villager had had Dame Strudwick's hard and narrow virtues, and had crushed all other
tastes and interests in the passion for living on a shilling a day in a cold and bitter independence,
the problem of preserving the monopolies of the few without disorder or trouble would have been
greatly simplified. There would have been little danger, as Burke would have said, that the fruits of
successful industry and the accumulations of fortune would be exposed to 'the plunder of the
negligent, the disappointed, and the unprosperous.'
The way in which the ruling class regarded the poor is illustrated in the tone of the discussions when
the problem of poverty had become acute at the end of the eighteenth century. When Pitt, who had
been pestered by Eden to read his book, handed a volume to Canning, then his secretary, that
brilliant young politician spent his time writing a parody on the grotesque names to he found in the
Appendix, and it will be recollected that Pitt excused himself for abandoning his scheme for
reforming the Poor Law, on the ground that he was inexperienced in the condition of the poor. It was
no shame to a politician to be ignorant of such subjects. The poor were happy or unhappy in the
view of the ruling class according to the sympathy the rich bestowed on them. If there were
occasional misgivings they were easily dispelled. Thus one philosopher pointed out that though the
position of the poor man might seem wanting in dignity or independence, it should be remembered
by way of consolation that he could play the tyrant over his wife and children as much as he liked.
(3*) Another train of soothing reflections was started by such papers as that published in the Annals
of Agriculture in 1797, under the title 'On the Comforts enjoyed by the Cottagers compared to those
of the ancient Barons.' In such a society a sentiment like that expressed by Fox when supporting
Whitbread's Bill in 1795, that 'it was not fitting in a free country that the great body of the people
should depend on the charity of the rich,' seemed a challenging paradox. Eden thought this an
extraordinary way of looking at the problem, and retorted that it was gratifying to see how ready the
rich were to bestow their benevolent attentions. This was the point of view of Pitt and of almost all
the speakers in the debate that followed Fox's outburst, Buxton going so far as to say that owing to
those attentions the condition of the poor had never been 'so eligible.' Just as the boisterous captain
in Evelina thought it was an honour to a wretched Frenchwoman to be rolled in British mud, so the
English House of Commons thought that poverty was turned into a positive blessing by the kindness
of the rich.
Writing towards the end of the ancient régime, Cobbett maintained that in his own lifetime the tone
and language of society about the poor had changed very greatly for the worse, that the old name of
'the commons of England' had given way to such names as 'the lower orders,' 'the peasantry,' and
'the population,' and that when the poor met together to demand their rights they were invariably
spoken of by such contumelious terms as 'the populace' or 'the mob.' 'In short, by degrees
beginning about fifty years ago the industrious Part of the community, particularly those who create
every useful thing by their labour, have been spoken of by everyone possessing the power to
oppress them in any degree in just the same manner in which we speak of the animals which
compose the stock upon a farm. This is not the manner in which the forefathers of us, the common
people, were treated.'(4*) Such language, Cobbett said, was to be heard not only from ' tax-
devourers, bankers, brewers, monopolists of every sort, but also from their clerks, from the very
shopkeepers and waiters, and from the fribbles stuck up behind the counter to do the business that
ought to be done by a girl.' This is perhaps only another way of saying that the isolation of the poor
was becoming a more and more conspicuous feature of English society.
Many causes combined to destroy the companionship of classes, and most of all the break-up of the
old village which followed on the enclosures and the consolidation of farms. In the old village,
labourers and cottagers and small farmers were neighbours. They knew each other and lived much
the same kind of life. The small farmer was a farmer one day of the week and a labourer another; he
married, according to Cobbett, the domestic servant of the gentry, a fact that explains the remark of
Sophia Western's maid to the landlady of the inn, 'and let me have the bacon cut very nice and thin,
for I can't endure anything that's gross. Prythee try if you can't do a little tolerably for once; and don't
think you have a farmer's wife or some of those creatures in the house.' The new farmer lived in a
different latitude. He married a young lady from the boarding school. He often occupied the old
manor house.(5*) He was divided from the labourer by his tastes, his interests, his ambitions, his
display and whole manner of life. The change that came over the English village in consequence
was apparent to all observers with social insight. When Goldsmith wanted to describe a happy
village he was careful to choose a village of the old kind, with the farmers 'strangers alike to
opulence and to poverty,' and Crabbe, to whose sincere and realist pen we owe much of our
knowledge of the social life of the time, gives a particularly poignant impression of the cold and
friendless atmosphere that surrounded the poor:
<poem>
'Where Plenty smiles, alas! she smiles for few,
And those who taste not, yet behold her store,
Are as the slaves that dig the golden ore,
The wealth around them makes them doubly poor.'(6*)
</poem>
Perhaps the most vivid account of the change is given in a letter from Cobbett in the <ex>Political
Register</ex> for 17th March 1821,(7*) addressed to Mr. Gooch: --
<ex>
'I hold a return to small farms to be absOlutely necessary to a restoration to anything like an English
community; and I am quite sure, that the ruin of the present race of farmers, generally, is a
necessary preliminary to this.... The life of the husbandman cannot be that of a gentleman without
injury to society at large. When farmers become gentlemen their labourers become slaves. A
Virginian farmer, as he is called, very much resembles a great farmer in England; but then, the
Virginian's work is done by slaves. It is in those States of America, where the farmer is only the first
labourer that all the domestic virtues are to be found, and all that public-spirit and that valour, which
are the safeguards of American independence, freedom, and happiness. You, Sir, with others,
complain of the increase of the poor-rates. But, you seem to forget, that, in the destruction of the
small farms, as separate farms, small-farmers have become mere hired labourers.... Take England
throughout three farms have been turned into one within fifty years, and the far greater part of the
change has taken place within the last thirty years; that is to say, since the commencement of the
deadly system of Pitt. Instead of families of small farmers with all their exertions, all their decency of
dress and of manners, and all their scrupulousness as to character, we have families of paupers,
with all the improvidence and wrecklessness belonging to an irrevocable sentence of poverty for life.
Mr. Curwen in his Hints on Agriculture, observes that he saw some where in Norfolk, I believe it
was, two hundred farmers worth from five to ten thousand pounds each; and exclaims "What a
glorious sight!" In commenting on this passage in the Register, in the year 1810, I observed " Mr.
Curwen only saw the outside of the sepulchre; if he had seen the two or three thousand half-starved
labourers of these two hundred farmers, and the five or six thousand ragged wives and children of
those labourers; if the farmers had brought those with them, the sight would not have been so
glorious."'
</ex>
A practice referred to in the same letter of Cobbett's that tended to widen the gulf between the
farmer and the labourer was the introduction of bailiffs: 'Along with enormous prices for corn came
in the employment of Bailiffs by farmers, a natural consequence of large farms; and to what a
degree of insolent folly the system was leading, may be guessed from an observation of Mr. Arthur
Young, who recommended, that the Bailiff should have a good horse to ride, and a bottle of port
wine every day at his dinner: while in the same work, Mr. Young gives great numbers of rules for
saving labour upon a farm. A pretty sort of farm where the bailiff was to have a bottle of port wine at
his dinner! The custom was, too, to bring bailiffs from some distant part, in order to prevent them
from having any feeling of compassion for the labourers. Scotch bailiffs above all, were preferred, as
being thought harder than any others that could be obtained; and thus (with shame I write the
words!) the farms of England, like those of Jamaica, were supplied with drivers from Scotland!...
Never was a truer saying, than that of the common people, that a Scotchman makes a "good sole,
but a d----d bad upper leather."'(8*) Bamford, speaking of 1745, says: 'Gentlemen then lived as they
ought to live: as real gentlemen will ever be found living: in kindliness with their neighbours; in
openhanded charity towards the poor, and in hospitality towards all friendly comers. There were no
grinding bailiffs and land stewards in those days to stand betwixt the gentleman and his labourer or
his tenant: to screw up rents and screw down livings, and to invent and transact all little
meannesses for so much per annum.'(9*) Cobbett's prejudice against Scotsmen, the race of
'feelosofers,' blinded him to virtues which were notoriously theirs, as in his round declaration that all
the hard work of agriculture was done by Englishmen and Irishmen, and that the Scotsmen chose
such tasks as 'peeping into melon frames.' But that his remarks upon the subject of the introduction
of Scottish bailiffs reflected a general feeling may be seen from a passage in Miss Austen's Emma,
'Mr. Graham intends to have a Scotch bailiff for his new estate. Will it answer? Will not the old
prejudice be too strong?'
The change in the status of the farmer came at a time of a general growth of luxury. All classes
above the poor adopted a more extravagant and ostentatious style and scale of living. This was
true, for example, of sporting England. Fox-hunting dates from this century. Before the eighteenth
century the amusement of the aristocracy was hunting the stag, and that of the country squire was
hunting the hare. It was because Walpole kept beagles at Richmond and used to hunt once a week
that the House of Commons has always made Saturday a holiday. In the Peninsular War,
Wellington kept a pack of hounds at headquarters, but they were fox-hounds. In its early days fox-
hunting had continued the simpler traditions of hare-hunting, and each small squire kept a few
couple of hounds and brought them to the meet. Gray has described his uncle's establishment at
Burnham, where every chair in the house was taken up by a dog. But as the century advanced the
sport was organised on a grander scale: the old buck-hounds and slow horses were superseded by
more expensive breeds, and far greater distances were covered. Foxhunting became the
amusement both of the aristocracy and of the squires, and it resembled rather the pomp and state of
stag-hunting than the modest pleasures of Walpole and his friends. In all other directions there was
a general increase of magnificence in life. The eighteenth century was the century of great
mansions, and some of the most splendid palaces of the aristocracy were built during the distress
and famine of the French war. The ambitions of the aristocracy became the ambitions of the classes
that admired them, as we know from Smollett, and Sir William Scott in 1802, speaking in favour of
the non-residence of the clergy, 'expressly said that they and their families ought to appear at
watering-places, and that this was amongst the means of making them respected by their
flocks!'(10*)
The rich and the poor were thus growing further and further apart, and there was nobody in the
English village to interpret these two worlds to each other. M. Babeau has pointed out that in
France, under the ancient régime, the lawyers represented and defended in some degree the rights
of the peasants. This was one consequence of the constant litigation between peasants and
seigneurs over communal property. The lawyers who took the side of the peasants lived at their
expense it is true, but they rendered public services, they presented the peasants' case before
public opinion, and they understood their ideas and difficulties. This explains a striking feature of the
French Revolution, the large number of local lawyers who became prominent as champions of
revolutionary ideas. One of Burke's chief complaints of the Constituent Assembly was that it
contained so many country attorneys and notaries, 'the fomenters and conductors of the petty war of
village vexation.'(11*) In England the lawyers never occupied this position, and it is impossible to
imagine such a development taking place there. The lawyers who interested themselves in the poor
were enlisted not in the defence of the rights of the commoners but in the defence of the purses of
the parishes. For them the all-important question was not what rights the peasant had against his
lord, but on which parish he had a claim for maintenance.
The causes of litigation were endless: if a man rented a tenement of the annual value of £10 he
acquired a settlement. But his rental might not have represented the annual value, and so the
further question would come up, Was the annual value actually £10? 'If it may be really not far from
that sum, and the family of the pauper be numerous, the interests of the contending parishes,
supported by the conflicting opinions of their respective surveyors, leads to the utmost expense and
extremity of litigation.'(12*) If the annual value were not in dispute there might be nice and intricate
questions about the kind of tenement and the nature of the tenure: if the settlement was claimed in
virtue of a contract of hiring, was the contract 'general, special, customary, retrospective,
conditional, personal' or what not?(13*) If the settlement was claimed in virtue of apprenticeship,
(14*) what was the nature of the indentures and so on. If claimed for an estate of £30, was the
estate really worth £30, and how was it acquired? These are a few of the questions in dispute, and
to add to the confusion 'on no branch of the law have the judgments of the superior court been so
contradictory.'(15*)
Thus the principal occupation of those lawyers whose business brought them into the world of the
poor was of a nature to draw their sympathies and interests to the side of the possessing classes,
and whereas peasants' ideas were acclimatised outside their own class in France as a
consequence of the character of rural litigation and of rural lawyers, the English villager came before
the lawyer, not as a client, but as a danger; not as a person whose rights and interests had to be
explored and studied, but as a person whose claims on the parish had to be parried or evaded. It is
not surprising, therefore, to find that both Fielding and Smollett lay great stress on the reputation of
lawyers for harshness and extortion in their treatment of the poor, regarding them, like Carlyle, as
'attorneys and law beagles who hunt ravenous on the earth.' Readers of the adventures of Sir
Launcelot Greaves will remember Tom Clarke 'whose goodness of heart even the exercise of his
profession had not been able to corrupt. Before strangers he never owned himself an attorney
without blushing, though he had no reason to blush for his own practice, for he constantly refused to
engage in the cause of any client whose character was equivocal, and was never known to act with
such industry as when concerned for the widow and orphan or any other object that sued in forma
pauperis.' Fielding speaks in a foot-note to Tom Jones of the oppression of the poor by attorneys, as
a scandal to the law, the nation, Christianity, and even human nature itself.
There was another class that might, under different circumstances, have helped to soothe and
soften the isolation of the poor, but the position and the sympathies of the English Church made this
impossible. This was seen very clearly by Adam Smith, who was troubled by the fear that
'enthusiasm,' the religious force so dreaded by the men of science and reason, would spread
among the poor, because the clergy who should have controlled and counteracted it were so little in
touch with the mass of the people. Under the government of the Anglican Church, as set up by the
Reformation, he pointed out, 'the clergy naturally endeavour to recommend themselves to the
sovereign, to the court, and to the nobility and gentry of the country, by whose influence they chiefly
expect to obtain preferment.'(16*) He added that such a clergy are very apt to neglect altogether the
means of maintaining their influence and authority with the lower ranks of life. The association of the
Anglican Church with the governing class has never been more intimate and binding than it was
during the eighteenth century. This was true alike of bishops and of clergy. The English bishop was
not a gay Voltairean like the French, but he was just as zealous a member of the privileged orders,
and the system over which he presided and which he defended was a faint copy of the gloriously
coloured scandals of the French Church. The prelates who lived upon those scandals were
described by Robespierre, with a humour that he did not often indulge, as treating the deity in the
same way as the mayor of the palace used to treat the French kings. 'Ils l'ont traité comme iadis les
maires du palais traitèrent les descendants de Clovis pour, regner sous son nom et se mettre à sa
place. Ils l'ont relégué dans le ciel comme dans un palais, et ne l'ont appelé sur la terre que pour
demander a leur profit des dîmes, des richesses, des honneurs, des plaisirs et de la puissance.'
When Archbishop Dillon declared against the civil constitution he said that he and his colleagues
acted as gentlemen and not as theologians. The Archbishop of Aix spoke of tithes as a voluntary
offering from the piety of the faithful. 'As to that,' said the Duke de la Rochefoucault, 'there are now
forty thousand cases in the Courts.' Both these archbishops would have found themselves quite at
home among the spiritual peers in the House of Lords, where the same decorous hypocrisies
mingled with the same class atmosphere. For the English bishops, though they were not libertines
like the French, never learnt so to be Christians as to forget to be aristocrats, and their religious
duties were never allowed to interfere with the demands of scholarship or of pleasure. Perhaps the
most distinguished product of this régime was Bishop Watson of Llandaff, who invented an
improved gunpowder and defended Christianity against Paine and Gibbon. These were his
diversions; his main business was carried on at his magnificent country scat on the banks of
Windermere. He was bishop for thirty-four years, and during the whole of that time he never lived
within his diocese, preferring to play the part of the grand seigneur planting trees in Westmorland.
He has left a sympathetic and charming account of what he modestly calls his retirement from public
life, an event not to be confused with abdication of his see, and of how he built the palace where he
spent the emoluments of Llandaff and the long autumn of his life.
It was natural to men who lived in this atmosphere to see politics through the spectacles of the
aristocracy. To understand how strongly the view that the Church existed to serve the aristocracy,
and the rest of the State through the aristocracy, was fixed in the minds of the higher clergy, we
have only to look at the case of a reformer like Bishop Horsley. The bishop is chiefly known as a
preacher, a controversialist, and the author of the celebrated dictum that the poor had nothing to do
with the laws except to obey them. His battle with Priestley has been compared to the encounter of
Bentley and Collins, a comparison that may not give Horsley more, but certainly gives Priestley less
than his due. When he preached before the House of Lords on the death of Louis XVI his audience
rose and stood in silent reverence during his peroration. The cynical may feel that it was not difficult
to inspire emotion and awe in such a congregation on such a subject at such a time, but we know
from De Quincey that Horsley's reputation as a preacher stood remarkably high. He was one of the
leaders of the Church in politics; for our purposes it is more important to note that he was one of the
reforming bishops. Among other scandals he attacked the scandal of non-residence, and he may be
taken as setting in this regard the strictest standard of his time; yet he did not scruple to go and live
in Oxford for some years as tutor to Lord Guernsey, during the time that he was Rector of
Newington, as plain a confession as we could want that in the estimation of the most public-spirited
of the clergy the nobility had the first claims on the Church. These social sympathies were confirmed
by common political interests. The privileges of the aristocracy and of the bishops were in fact
bound up together, and both bishops and aristocracy had good reason to shrink from breaking a
thread anywhere. Perhaps the malicious would find the most complete and piquant illustration of the
relations of the Church and the governing class in the letter written by Dr. Goodenough to
Addington, who had just made him dean of Rochester, when the clerkship of the Pells, worth £3000
a year, was about to become vacant. 'I understand that Colonel Barré is in a very precarious state. I
hope you will have the fortitude to nominate Harry to be his successor.' Harry, Addington's son, was
a boy at Winchester. The father's fortitude rose to the emergency: the dean blossomed a little later
into a bishop.
But if the French and the English bishops both belonged to the aristocracy in feelings and in habits,
a great difference distinguishes the rank and file of the clergy in the two countries. The French priest
belonged by circumstances and by sympathy to the peasant class. The bishop regarded the country
curé as un vilain sentant le fumier, and treated him with about as much consideration as the
seigneur showed to his dependants. The priest's quarrel with the bishop was like the peasant's
quarrel with the seigneur: for both priest and peasant smarted under the arrogant airs of their
respective superiors, and the bishop swallowed up the tithes as the seigneur swallowed up the
feudal dues. Sometimes the curé put himself at the head of a local rebellion. In the reign of Louis XV
the priests round Saint-Germain led out their flocks to destroy the game which devoured their crops,
the campaign being announced and sanctified from the pulpit. In the Revolution the common clergy
were largely on the side of the peasants. Such a development was inconceivable in England. As.the
curé's windows looked to the village, the parson's windows looked to the hall. When the parson's
circumstances enabled him to live like the squire, he rode to hounds, for though, as Blackstone tells
us, Roman Canon Law, under the influence of the tradition that St. Jerome had once observed that
the saints had eschewed such diversions, had interdicted venationes et sylvaticas vagationes cum
canibus et accipitribus to all clergymen, this early severity of life had vanished long before the
eighteenth century. He treated the calls of his profession as trifling accidents interrupting his normal
life of vigorous pleasure. On becoming Bishop of Chester, Dr. Blomfield astonished the diocese by
refusing to license a curate until he had promised to abstain from hunting, and by the pain and
surprise with which he saw one of his clergy carried away drunk from a visitation dinner. One rector,
whom he rebuked for drunkenness, replied with an injured manner that he was never drunk on duty.
There were, it is true, clergymen of great public spirit and devoted lives, and such men figure in
these pages, but the Church, as a whole, was an easy-going society, careful of its pleasures and
comforts, living with the moral ideas and as far as possible in the manner of the rich. The rivalry of
the Methodist movement had given a certain stimulus to zeal, and the Vicar of Corsley in Wilts,(17*)
for example, added a second service to the duties of the Sunday, though guarding himself expressly
against the admission of any obligation to make it permanent. But it was found impossible to
eradicate from the system certain of the vices that belong to a society which is primarily a class.
Some of the bishops set themselves to reduce the practice of non-residence. Porteus, Bishop of
London, devoted a great part of his charge to his clergy in 1790 to this subject, and though he
pleaded passionately for reform he cannot be said to have shut his eyes to the difficulties of the
clergy. 'There are, indeed, two impediments to constant residence which cannot easily be
surmounted; the first is (what fortunately prevails in some parts of this diocese) unwholesomeness
of situation; the other is the possession of a second benefice. Yet even these will not justify a total
and perpetual absence from your cures. The unhealthiness of many places is of late years by
various improvements greatly abated, and there are now few so circumstanced as not to admit of
residence there in some part of the year without any danger to the constitution.' Thus even Bishop
Porteus, who in this very charge reminded the clergy that they were called by the titles of stewards,
watchmen, shepherds, and labourers, never went the length of thinking that the Church was to be
expected to minister to the poor in all weathers and in all climates.
The exertions of the reforming bishops did not achieve a conspicuous success, for the second of the
difficulties touched on by Porteus was insurmountable. In his Legacy to Parsons, Cobbett, quoting
from the Clerical Guide, showed that 332 parsons shared the revenues of 1496 parishes, and 500
more shared those of 1524. Among the pluralists were Lord Walsingham, who besides enjoying a
pension of £700 a year, was Archdeacon of Surrey, Prebendary of Winchester, Rector of
Calbourne, Rector of Fawley, perpetual Curate of Exbury, and Rector of Merton; the Earl of
Guildford, Rector of Old Alresford, Rector of New Alresford, perpetual Curate of Medsted, Rector of
St. Mary, Southampton, including the great parish of South Stoneham, Master of St. Cross Hospital,
with the revenue of the parish of St. Faith along with it. There were three Pretymans dividing fifteen
benefices, and Wellington's brother was Prebendary of Durham, Rector of Bishopwearmouth,
Rector of Chelsea, and Rector of Therfield. This method of treating the parson's profession as a
comfortable career was so closely entangled in the system of aristocracy, that no Government which
represented those interests would ever dream of touching it. Parliament intervened indeed, but
intervened to protect those who lived on these abuses. For before 1801 there were Acts of
Parliament on the Statute Book (21 Henry VIII. c. 13, and 13 Elizabeth c. 20), which provided certain
penalties for non-residence. In 1799 a certain Mr. Williams laid informations against hundreds of the
clergy for offences against these Acts. Parliament replied by passing a series of Acts to stay
proceedings, and finally in 1803 Sir William Scott, member for the University of Oxford, passed an
Act which allowed the bishops to authorise parsons to reside out of their parishes. It is not surprising
to find that in 1812, out of ten thousand incumbents, nearly six thousand were non-resident.
In the parishes where the incumbent was non-resident, if there was a clergyman at all in the place, it
was generally a curate on a miserable pittance. Bishop Porteus, in the charge already mentioned,
gives some interesting information about the salaries of curates: 'It is also highly to the honour of
this diocese that in general the stipends allowed to the curates are more liberal than in many other
parts of the kingdom. In several instances I find that the stipend for one church only is £50 a year;
for two £60 and the use of a parsonage; and in the unwholesome parts of the diocese £70 and even
£80 (that is £40 for each church), with the same indulgence of a house to reside in.' Many of the
parishes did not see much of the curate assigned to them. 'A man must have travelled very little in
the kingdom,' said Arthur Young in 1798, 'who does not know that country towns abound with
curates who never see the parishes they serve, but when they are absolutely forced to it by
duty.'(18*) But the ill-paid curate, even when he was resident and conscientious, as he often was,
moved like the pluralist rector in the orbit of the rich. He was in that world though not of it. All his
hopes hung on the squire. To have taken the side of the poor against him would have meant ruin,
and the English Church was not a nursery of this kind of heroism. It is significant that almost every
eighteenth-century novelist puts at least one sycophantic parson in his or her gallery of portraits.
(19*)
In addition to the social ties that drew the clergy to the aristocracy, there was a powerful economic
hindrance to their friendship with the poor. De Tocqueville thought that the tithe system brought the
French priest into interesting and touching relations with the peasant: a view that has seemed
fanciful to later historians, who are more impressed by the quarrels that resulted. But de Tocqueville
himself could scarcely argue that the tithe system helped to warm the heart of the labourer to the
Church of England in cases such as those recorded in the Parliamentary Paper issued in 1833, in
which parson magistrates sent working men to prison for refusing to pay tithes to their rector. Day
labouring men had originally been exempted from liability to pay tithes, but just as the French
Church brought more and more of the property and industry of the State within her confiscating
grasp, so the English Parliament, from the reign of William III, had been drawing the parson's net
more closely round the labourer. Moreover, as we shall see in a later chapter, the question of tithes
was in the very centre of the social agitations that ended in the rising of 1830 and its terrible
punishment. In this particular quarrel the farmers and labourers were on the same side, and the
parsons as a body stood out for their own property with as much determination as the landlords.
In one respect the Church took an active part in oppressing the village poor, for Wilberforce and his
friends started, just before the French Revolution, a Society for the Reformation of Manners, which
aimed at enforcing the observance of Sunday, forbidding any kind of social dissipation, and
repressing freedom of speech and of thought whenever they refused to conform to the superstitions
of the morose religion that was then in fashion. This campaign was directed against the license of
the poor alone. There were no stocks for the Sabbath-breakers of Brooks's: a Gibbon might take
what liberties he pleased with religion: the wildest Methodist never tried to shackle the loose
tongues or the loose lives of the gay rich. The attitude of the Church to the excesses of this class is
well depicted in Fielding's account of Parson Supple, who never remonstrated with Squire Western
for swearing, but preached so vigorously in the pulpit against the habit that the authorities put the
laws very severely in execution against others, 'and the magistrate was the only person in the parish
who could swear with impunity.' This description might seem to border on burlesque, but there is an
entry in Wilberforce's diary that reveals a state of mind which even Fielding would have found it
impossible to caricature. Wilberforce was staying at Brighton, and this is his description of an
evening he spent at the Pavilion with the first gentleman of Europe: 'The Prince and Duke of
Clarence too very civil. Prince showed he had read Cobbett. Spoke strongly of the blasphemy of his
late papers and most justly.'(20*) We can only hope that Sheridan was there to enjoy the scene, and
that the Prince was able for once to do justice to his strong feelings in language that would not
shock Wilberforce's ears.
Men like Wilberforce and the magistrates whom he inspired did not punish the rich for their dissolute
behaviour; they only found in that behaviour another argument for coercing the poor. As they
watched the dishevelled lives of men like George Selwyn their one idea of action was to punish a
village labourer, for neglecting church on Sunday morning. We have seen how the cottagers paid in
Enclosure Bills for their lords' adventures at play. They paid also for their lords' dissipations in the
loss of innocent pleasures that might have brought some colour into their grey lives. The more
boisterous the fun at Almack's, the deeper the gloom thrown over the village. The Select Committee
on Allotments that reported in 1843 found one of the chief causes of crime in the lack of recreations.
Sheridan at one time and Cobbett at another tried to revive village sports, but social circumstances
were too strong for them. In this respect the French peasant had the advantage. Babeau's picture of
his gay and sociable Sunday may be overdrawn, but a comparison of Crabbe's description of the
English Sunday with contemporary descriptions of Sunday as it was spent in a French village,
shows that the spirit of common gaiety, killed in England by Puritanism and by the destruction of the
natural and easy-going relations of the village community, survived in France through all the
tribulations of poverty and famine. The eighteenth-century French village still bore a resemblance in
fact to the medieval English village, and Goldsmith has recorded in The Traveller his impressions of
'mirth and social ease.' Babeau gives an account of a great variety of village games, from the violent
contests in Brittany for the 'choule,' in one of which fourteen players were drowned, to the gentler
dances and the children's romps that were general in other parts of France, and Arthur Young was
very much struck by the agility and the grace that the heavy peasants displayed in dancing on the
village green. Windham, speaking in a bad cause, the defence of bull-baiting in 1800, laid stress on
the contrast: 'In the south of Fiance and in Spain, at the end of the day's labour, and in the cool of
the evening's shade, the poor dance in mirthful festivity on the green, to the sound of the guitar. But
in this country no such source of amusement presents itself. If they dance, it must be often in a
marsh, or in the rain, for the pleasure of catching cold. But there is a substitute in this country well
known by the name of Hops. We all know the alarm which the very word inspires, and the sound of
the fiddle calls forth the magistrate to dissolve the meeting. Men bred in ignorance of the world, and
having no opportunity of mixing in its scenes or observing its manners, may be much worse
employed than in learning something of its customs from theatrical representations; but if a
company of strolling players make their appearance in a village, they are hunted immediately from it
as a nuisance, except, perhaps, there be a few people of greater wealth in the neighbourhood,
whose wives and daughters patronize them.'(21*) Thus all the influences of the time conspired to
isolate the poor, and the changes, destructive of their freedom and happiness, that were taking
place in their social and economic surroundings, were aggravated by a revival of Puritanism which
helped to rob village life of all its natural melody and colour.
NOTES:
1. Reflections on the Revolution in France (fourth edition), p. 359.
2. Eden, vol. i, p. 579.
3. Reports on Poor, vol. ii, p. 325.
4. Political Register, vol. lxxviii, p. 710.
5. Hasbach, p. 131.
6. 'Village,' Book i.
7. Vol. xxxviii, p. 750 ff.
8. Cobbet's Political Register, March 17, 1821, p. 779.
9. Bamford, Passages in the Life of a Radical, p. 38.
10. Rural Rides, p. 460.
11. Reflections, p. 61.
12. Poor Law Report, 1817.
13. Cf. Ibid., 1834, p. 161.
14. Cf. case of apprentice, Annual Register, 1819, p. 195.
15. Poor Law Report, 1817; in some cases there were amicable arrangements to keep down legal
expenses; e.g., at Halifax (Eden), the overseer formed a society of the officers of adjoining parishes.
Cases were referred to them, and the decision of the majority was accepted.
16. Wealth of Nations, vol. iii, p. 234.
17. Life in an English Village, by Maude F. Davies, p. 58.
18. Inquiry into the State of the Public Mind among the Lower Classes, p. 27.
19. The parsons under Squire Allworthy's roof, the parson to whom Pamela appealed in vain, and,
most striking of all, Mr Collins in Pride and Prejudice.
20. Life, vol. iv, p. 277.
21. Parliamentary Register, April 18, 1800.
Chapter Nine
The Village in 1830
We have described the growing misery of the labourer, the increasing rigours of the criminal law,
and the insensibility of the upper classes, due to the isolation of the poor. What kind of a community
was created by the Speenhamland system after it had been in force for a generation? We have,
fortunately, a very full picture given in a Parliamentary Report that is generally regarded as one of
the landmarks of English history. We cannot do better than set out the main features of the Report
of the Poor Law Commissioners of 1834, and the several effects they traced to this system.
The first effect is one that everybody could have anticipated: the destruction of all motives for effort
and ambition. Under this system 'the most worthless were sure of something, while the prudent, the
industrious, and the sober, with all their care and pains, obtained only something; and even that
scanty pittance was doled out to them by the overseer.'(1*) All labourers were condemned to live on
the brink of starvation, for no effort of will or character could improve their position. The effect on the
imagination was well summed up in a rhetorical question from a labourer who gave evidence to a
Commissioner. 'When a man has his spirit broken what is he good for?'(2*) The Poor Law
Commissioners looked at it from a different point of view: 'The labourer feels that the existing
system, though it generally gives him low wages, always gives him work. It gives him also, strange
as it may appear, what he values more, a sort of independence. He need not bestir himself to seek
work; he need not study to please his master; he need not put any restraint upon his temper; he
need not ask relief as a favour. He has all a slave's security for subsistence, without his liability to
punishment.... All the other classes of society are exposed to the vicissitudes of hope and fear; he
alone has nothing to lose or to gain.'(3*)
But it is understating the result of the system on individual enterprise to say that it destroyed
incentives to ambition; for in some parishes it actually proscribed independence and punished the
labourer who owned some small property. Wages under these conditions were so low that a man
with a little property or a few savings could not keep himself alive without help from the parish, but if
a man was convicted of possessing anything he was refused parish help. It was dangerous even to
look tidy or neat, 'ragged clothes are kept by the poor, for the express purpose of coming to the
vestry in them.'(4*) The Report of the Commissioners on this subject recalls Rousseau's description
of the French peasant with whom he stayed in the course of his travels, who, when his suspicions
had been soothed, and his hospitable instincts had been warmed by friendly conversation, produced
stores of food from the secret place where they had been hidden to escape the eye of the tax-
collector. A man who had saved anything was ruined. A Mr. Hickson, a Northampton manufacturer
and landowner in Kent, gave an illustration of this.
'The case of a man who has worked for me will show the effect of the parish system in preventing
frugal habits. This is a hard-working, industrious man, named William Williams. He is married, and
had saved some money, to the amount of about £70, and had two cows; he had also a sow and ten
pigs. He had got a cottage well furnished; he was a member of a benefit club at Meopham, from
which he received 8s. a week when he was ill. He was beginning to learn to read and write, and sent
his children to the Sunday School. He had a legacy of about £46, but he got his other money
together by saving from his fair wages as a waggoner. Some circumstances occurred which obliged
me to part with him. The consequence of this labouring man having been frugal and saved money,
and got the cows, was that no one would employ him, although his superior character as a workman
was well known in the parish. He told me at the time I was obliged to part with him: "Whilst I have
these things I shall get no work; I must part with them all; I must be reduced to a state of beggary
before any one will employ me." I was compelled to part with him at Michaelmas; he has not yet got
work, and he has no chance of getting any until he has become a pauper; for until then the paupers
will be preferred to him. He cannot get work in his own parish, and he will not be allowed to get any
in other parishes. Another instance of the same kind occurred amongst my workmen. Thomas
Hardy, the brother-in-law of the same man, was an excellent workman, discharged under similar
circumstances; he has a very industrious wife. They have got two cows, a well-furnished cottage,
and a pig and fowls. Now he cannot get work, because he has property. The pauper will be
preferred to him, and he can qualify himself for it only by becoming a pauper. If he attempts to get
work elsewhere, he is told that they do not want to fix him on the parish. Both these are fine young
men, and as excellent labourers as I could wish to have. The latter labouring man mentioned
another instance of a labouring man in another parish (Henstead), who had once had more property
than he, but was obliged to consume it all, and is now working on the roads.'(5*) This effect of the
Speenhamland arrangements was dwelt on in the evidence before the Committee on Agricultural
Labourers' Wages in 1824. Labourers had to give up their cottages in a Dorsetshire village because
they could not become pensioners if they possessed a cottage, and farmers would only give
employment to village pensioners. Thus these cottagers who had not been evicted by enclosure
were evicted by the Speenhamland system.
It is not surprising that in the case of another man of independent nature in Cambridgeshire, who
had saved money and so could get no work, we are told that the young men pointed at him, and
called him a fool for not spending his money at the public-house, 'adding that then he would get
work.'(6*) The statesmen who condemned the labourer to this fate had rejected the proposal for a
minimum wage, on the ground that it would destroy emulation.
There was one slight alleviation of this vicious system, which the Poor Law Commissioners
considered in the very different light of an aggravation. If society was to be reorganised on such a
basis as this, it was at any rate better that the men who were made to live on public money should
not be grateful to the ratepayers. The Commissioners were pained by the insolence of the paupers.
'The parish money' said a Sussex labourer, 'is now chucked to us like as to a dog,'(7*) but the
labourers did not lick the hand that thew it. All though the Report we read complaints of the 'insolent,
discontented, surly pauper,' who talks of 'right' and 'income,' and who will soon fight for these
supposed rights and income 'unless some step is taken to arrest his progress to open violence.' The
poor emphasised this view by the terms they applied to their rate subsidies, which they sometimes
called 'their reglars,' sometimes 'the county allowance,' and sometimes 'The Act of Parliament
allowance.' Old dusty rentbooks of receipts and old dirty indentures of apprenticeship were handed
down from father to son with as much care as if they had been deeds of freehold property, as
documentary evidence to their right to a share in the rates of a particular parish.(8*) Of course there
was not a uniform administration, and the Commissioners reported that whilst in some districts men
were disqualified for relief if they had any wages, in others there was no inquiry into circumstances,
and non-necessitous persons dipped like the rest into the till. In many cases only the wages
received during the last week or fortnight were taken into account, and thus the allowance would be
paid to some persons who at particular periods received wages in excess of the scale. This
accounts for the fact stated by Thorold Rogers from his own experience that there were labourers
who actually saved considerable sums out of the system.
The most obvious and immediate effect was the effect which had been foreseen without misgiving in
Warwickshire and Worcestershire. The married man was employed in preference to the bachelor,
and his income rose with the birth of each child. But there was one thing better than to marry and
have a family, and that was to marry a mother of bastards, for bastards were more profitable than
legitimate children, since the parish guaranteed the contribution for which the putative father was
legally liable. It was easier to manage with a family than with a single child. As one young woman of
twenty-four with four bastard children put it, 'If she had one more she should be very
comfortable.'(9*) Women with bastard children were thus very eligible wives. The effect of the whole
system on village morals was striking and widespread, and a witness from a parish which was
overwhelmed with this sudden deluge of population said to the Commission, 'the eighteen-penny
children will eat up this parish in ten years more, unless some relief be afforded us.'(10*) Before this
period, if we are to believe Cobbett, it had been rare for a woman to be with child at the time of her
marriage; in these days of demoralisation and distress it became the habit.
The effects produced by this system on the recipients of relief were all of them such as might have
been anticipated, and in this respect the Report of the Commissioners contained no surprises. It
merely illustrated the generalisations that had been made by all Poor Law Reformers during the last
fifteen years. But the discovery of the extent of the corruption which the system had bred in local
government and administration was probably a revelation to most people. It demoralised not only
those who received but those who gave. A network of tangled interests spread over local life, and
employers and tradesmen were faced with innumerable temptations and opportunities for fraud. To
take the case of the overseer first. Suppose him to be a tradesman: he was liable to suffer in his
custom if he refused to relieve the friends, or it might be the workmen of his customers. It would
require a man of almost superhuman rigidity of principle to be willing not only to lose time and
money in serving a troublesome and unprofitable office, but to lose custom as well.(11*) From the
resolve not to lose custom he might gradually slip down to the determination to reimburse himself
for 'the vexatious demands' on his time, till a state of affairs like that in Slaugham came about.
'Population, 740. Expenditure, £1706. The above large sum of money is expended principally in
orders on the village shops for flour, clothes, butter, cheese, etc.: the tradesmen serve the office of
overseer by turns; the two last could neither read nor write.'(12*)
If the overseer were a farmer there were temptations to pay part of the wages of his own and his
friends' labourers out of parish money, or to supply the workhouse with his own produce. The same
temptations beset the members of vestries, whether they were open or select. 'Each vestryman, so
far as he is an immediate employer of labour, is interested in keeping down the rate of wages, and
in throwing part of their payment on others, and, above all, on the principal object of parochial fraud,
the tithe-owner: if he is the owner of cottages, he endeavours to get their rent paid by the parish; if
he keeps a shop, he struggles to get allowance for his customers or debtors; if he deals in articles
used in the workhouse, he tries to increase the workhouse consumption; if he is in humble
circumstances, his own relations or friends may be among the applicants.'(13*) Mr. Drummond, a
magistrate for Hants and Surrey, said to the Committee on Laborers' Wages in 1824, that part of the
poor-rate expenditure was returned to farmers and landowners in exorbitant cottage rents, and that
the farmers always opposed a poor man who wished to build himself a cottage on the waste.
In the case of what was known as the 'labor rate' system, the members of one class combined
together to impose the burden of maintaining the poor on the shoulders of the other classes. By this
system, instead of the laborer's wages being made up to a fixed amount by the parish, each
ratepayer was bound to employ, and to pay at a certain rate, a certain number of laborers, whether
he wanted them or not. The number depended sometimes on his assessment to the poor rate,
sometimes on the amount of acres he occupied (of the use to which the land was put no notice was
taken, a sheep-walk counting for as much as arable fields): when the occupiers of land had
employed a fixed number of laborers, the surplus labourers were divided amongst all the ratepayers
according to their rental. This plan was superficially fair, but as a matter of fact it worked out to the
advantage of the big farmers with much arable land, and pressed hard on the small ones who
cultivated their holdings by their own and their children's labor, and, in cases where they were liable
to the rate, on the tradesmen who had no employment at which to set an agricultural laborer. After
1832 (2 and 3 William IV. c. 96) the agreement of three-fourths of the ratepayers to such a system
was binding on all, and the large farmers often banded together to impose it on their fellow
ratepayers by intimidation or other equally unscrupulous means: thus at Kelvedon in Essex we read:
'There was no occasion in this parish, nor would it have been done but for a junto of powerful
landholders, putting down opposition by exempting a sufficient number, to give themselves the
means of a majority.'(14*)
Landlords in some cases resorted to Machiavellian tactics in order to escape their burdens.
'Several instances have been mentioned to us, of parishes nearly depopulated, in which almost all
the labour is performed by persons settled in the neighboring villages or towns; drawing from them,
as allowance, the greater part of their subsistence.'(15*) This method is described more at length in
the following passage: --
' When a parish is in the hands of only one proprietor, or of proprietors so few in number as to be
able to act, and to compel their tenants to act, in unison, and adjoins to parishes in which property is
much divided, they may pull down every cottage as it becomes vacant, and prevent the building of
new ones. By a small immediate outlay they may enable and induce a considerable portion of those
who have settlements in their parish to obtain settlements in the adjoining parishes: by hiring their
laborers for periods less than a year, they may prevent the acquisition of new settlements in their
own. They may thus depopulate their own estates, and cultivate them by means of the surplus
population of the surrounding district.'(16*) A clergyman in Reading(17*) said that he had between
ten and twenty families living in his parish and working for the farmers in their original parish, whose
cottages had been pulled down over their heads. Occasionally a big proprietor of parish A, in order
to lessen the poor rates, would, with unscrupulous ingenuity, take a farm in parish B, and there hire
for the year a batch of labourers from A: these at the end of their term he would turn off on to the
mercies of parish B which was now responsible for them, whilst he sent for a fresh consignment
from parish A.(18*)
The Report of the Commission is a remarkable and searching picture of the general demoralisation
produced by the Speenhamland system, and from that point of view it is most graphic and
instructive. But nobody who has followed the history of the agricultural labourer can fail to be struck
by its capital omission. The Commissioners, in their simple analysis of that system, could not take
their eyes off the Speenhamland goblin, and instead of dealing with that system as a wrong and
disastrous answer to certain difficult questions, they treated the system itself as the one and original
source of all evils. They sighed for the days when 'the paupers were a small disreputable minority,
whose resentment was not to be feared, and whose favour was of no value,' and 'all other classes
were anxious to diminish the number of applicants, and to reduce the expenses of their
maintenance.'(19*) They did not realise that the governing class had not created a Frankenstein
monster for the mere pleasure of its creation; that they had not set out to draw up an ideal
constitution, as Rousseau had done for the Poles. In 1795 there was a fear of revolution, and the
upper classes threw the Speenhamland system over the villages as a wet blanket over sparks. The
Commissioners merely isolated the consequences of Speenhamland and treated them as if they
were the entire problem, and consequently, though their report served to extinguish that system, it
did nothing to rehabilitate the position of the labourer, or to restore the rights and status he had lost.
The new Poor Law was the only gift of the Reformed Parliament to the agricultural labourer; it was
an improvement on the old, but only in the sense that the east wind is better than the sirocco.
What would have happened if either of the other two remedies had been adopted for the problem to
which the Speenhamland system was applied, it is impossible to say. But it is easy to see that the
position of the agricultural labourer, which could not have been worse, might have been very much
better, and that the nation, as apart from the landlords and money-lords, would have come out of
this whirlpool much stronger and much richer. This was clear to one correspondent of the Poor Law
Commission, whose memorandum, printed in an Appendix,(20*) is more interesting and profound
than any contribution to the subject made by the Commissioners themselves. M. Chateauvieux set
out an alternative policy to Speenhamland, which, if the governing class of 1795 or the governing
class of 1834 had been enlightened enough to follow it, would have set up a very different labouring
class in the villages from the helpless proletariat that was created by the enclosures.
'Mais si au lieu d'opérer le partage des biens communaux, l'administration de la commune s'était
bornée à louer pour quelques années des parcelles des terres qu'elle possède en vaine pâture, et
cela à très bas prix, aux journaliers domiciliés sur son territoire, il en serait resulté:
'(1) Que le capital de ces terres n'aurait point été aliéné et absorbé dans la propriété particulière.
'(2) Que ce capital aurait été néanmoins utilisé pour la reproduction.
'(3) Qu'il aurait servi à l'amélioration du sort des pauvres qui l'auraient défriché, de toute la
différence entre le prix du loyer qu'ils en auraient payé, et le montant du revenu qu'ils auraient
obtenu de sa recolte.
'(4) Que la commune aurait encaissé le montant de ses loyers, et aurait augmenté d'autant les
moyens dont elle dispose pour le soulagement de ces pauvres.'
M. Chateauvieux understood better than any of the Commissioners, dominated as they were by the
extreme individualist economy of the time, the meaning of Bolingbroke's maxim that a wise minister
considers his administration as a single day in the great year of Government; but as a day that is
affected by those which went before and must affect those which are to come after. A Government
of enclosing landowners was perhaps not to be expected to understand all that the State was in
danger of losing in the reckless alienation of common property.
What of the prospects of the other remedy that was proposed? At first sight it seems natural to
argue that had Whitbread's Minimum Wage Bill become an Act of Parliament it would have
remained a dead letter. The administration depended on the magistrates and the magistrates
represented the rent-receiving and employing classes. A closer scrutiny warrants a different
conclusion. At the time that the Speenhamland plan was adopted there were many magistrates in
favour of setting a minimum scale. The Suffolk magistrates, for example, put pressure on the county
members to vote for Whitbread's Bill, and those members, together with Grey and Sheridan, were
its backers. The Parliamentary support for the Bill was enough to show that it was not only in Suffolk
that it would have been adopted; there were men like Lechmere and Whitbread scattered about the
country, and though they were men of far more enlightened views than the average J. P., they were
not without influence in their own neighbourhoods. It is pretty certain, therefore, that if the Bill had
been carried, it would have been administered in some parts of the country. The public opinion in
support of the Act would have been powerfully reinforced by the pressure of the labourers, and this
would have meant a more considerable stimulus than might at first be supposed, for the Report of
the Poor Law Commissioners shows that the pressure of the labourers was a very important factor
in the retention of the allowance system in parishes where the overseers wished to abandon it, and
if the labourers could coerce the local authorities into continuing the Speenhamland system, they
could have coerced the magistrates into making an assessment of wages. The labourers were able
by a show of violence to raise wages and to reduce prices temporarily, as is clear from the history of
1816 and 1830. It is not too much to suppose that they could have exercised enough influence in
1795 to induce magistrates in many places to carry out a law that was on the Statute Book. Further,
it is not unreasonable to suppose that agricultural labourers' unions to enforce the execution of the
law would have escaped the monstrous Combination Law of 1799 and 1800, for even in 1808 the
Glasgow and Lancashire cotton-weavers were permitted openly to combine for the purpose of
seeking a legal fixing of wages.(21*)
If assessment had once become the practice, the real struggle would have arisen when the great
prosperity of agriculture began to decline; at the time, that is, when the Speenhamland system
began to show those symptoms of strain that we have described. Would the customary wage,
established under the more favourable conditions of 1795, have stood against that pressure? Would
the labourers have been able to keep up wages, as critics of the Whitbread Bill had feared that they
would? In considering the answers to that question, we have to reckon with a force that the debaters
of 1795 could not have foreseen. In 1795 Cobbett was engaged in the politics and polemics of
America, and if any member of the House of Commons knew his name, he knew it as the name of a
fierce champion of English institutions, and a fierce enemy of revolutionary ideas; a hero of the Anti-
Jacobin itself. In 1810 Cobbett was rapidly making himself the most powerful tribune that the
English poor have ever known. Cobbett's faults are plain enough, for they are all on the surface. His
egotism sometimes seduced his judgment; he had a strongly perverse element in his nature; his
opinion of any proposals not his own was apt to be petulant and peevish, and it might perhaps be
said of him that he generally had a wasp in his bonnet. These qualities earned for him his title of the
Contentious Man. They would have been seriously disabling in a Cabinet Minister, but they did not
affect his power of collecting and mobilising and leading the spasmodic forces of the poor.
Let us recall his career in order to understand what his influence would have been if the labourers
had won their customary wage in 1795, and had been fighting to maintain it fifteen or twenty years
later. His adventures began early. When he was thirteen his imagination was fired by stories the
gardener at Farnham told him of the glories of Kew. He ran away from home, and made so good an
impression on the Kew gardener that he was given work there. His last coppers on that journey
were spent in buying Swift's Tale of a Tub. He returned home, but his restless dreams drove him
again into the world. He tried to become a sailor, and ultimately became a soldier. He left the army,
where he had made his mark and received rapid promotion, in order to expose a financial scandal in
his regiment, but on discovering that the interests involved in the countenance of military abuses
were far more powerful than he had supposed, he abandoned his attempt and fled to France. A few
months later he crossed to America, and settled down to earn a living by teaching English to French
refugees. This peaceful occupation he relinquished for the congenial excitements of polemical
journalism, and he was soon the fiercest pamphleteer on the side of the Federals, who took the part
of England, in their controversies with the democrats, who took the part of the Revolution. So far as
the warfare of pamphlets went, Cobbett turned the scale. The democrats could not match his wit, his
sarcasm, his graphic and pointed invectives, his power of clever and sparkling analysis and ridicule.
This warfare occupied him for nearly ten years, and he returned to England in time to have his
windows broken for refusing to illuminate his house in celebration of the Peace of Amiens. In 1802
he started the Political Register. At that time he was still a Tory, but a closer study of English life
changed his opinions, and four years later he threw himself into the Radical movement. The effect
of his descent on English politics can only be compared to the shock that was given to the mind of
Italy by the French methods of warfare, when Charles VIII led his armies into her plains to fight
pitched battles without any of the etiquette or polite conventions that had graced the combats of the
condottieri. He gave to the Reform agitation an uncompromising reality and daring, and a movement
which had become the dying echo of a smothered struggle broke into storm and thunder. Hazlitt
scarcely exaggerated his daemonic powers when he said of him that he formed a fourth estate of
himself.
Now Cobbett may be said to have spent twenty years of his life in the effort to save the labourers
from degradation and ruin. He was the only man of his generation who regarded politics from this
standpoint. This motive is the key to his career. He saw in 1816 that the nation had to choose
between its sinecures, its extravagant army, its rulers' mad scheme of borrowing at a higher rate to
extinguish debt, for which it was paying interest at a low rate, its huge Civil List and privileged
establishments, the interests of the fundholders and contractors on the one hand, and its labourers
on the other. In that conflict of forces the labourer could not hold his own. Later, Cobbett saw that
there were other interests, the interests of landowners and of tithe-holders, which the State would
have to subordinate to national claims if the labourer was to be saved. In that conflict, too, the
labourer was beaten. He was unrepresented in Parliament, whereas the opposing interests were
massed there. Cobbett wanted Parliamentary Reform, not like the traditional Radicals as a
philosophy of rights, but as an avalanche of social power. Parliamentary Reform was never an end
to him, nor the means to anything short of the emancipation of the labourer. In this, his main
mission, Cobbett failed. The upper classes winced under his ruthless manners, and they trembled
before his Berserker rage, but it is the sad truth of English history that they beat him. Now if, instead
of throwing himself against this world of privilege and vested interests in the hopes of wringing a
pittance of justice for a sinking class, it had been his task to maintain a position already held, he
would have fought under very different conditions. If, when prices began to fall, there had been a
customary wage in most English villages, the question would not have been whether the ruling class
was to maintain its privileges and surplus profits by letting the labourer sink deeper into the morass,
but whether it was to maintain these privileges and profits by taking something openly from him. It is
easier to prevent a dog from stealing a bone than to take the bone out of his mouth. Cobbett was
not strong enough to break the power of the governing class, but he might have been strong enough
to defend the customary rights of the labouring class. As it was, the governing class was on the
defensive at every point. The rent receivers, the tithe owners, the mortgagers, the lenders to the
Government and the contractors all clung to their gains, and the food allowance of the labourer
slowly and steadily declined.
There was this great difference between the Speenhamland system and a fixed standard of wages.
The Speenhamland system after 1812 was not applied so as to maintain an equilibrium between the
income and expenditure of the labourer: it was applied to maintain an equilibrium between social
forces. The scale fell not with the fall of prices to the labourer, but with the fall of profits to the
possessing classes. The minimum was not the minimum on which the labourer could live, but the
minimum below which rebellion was certain. This was the way in which wages found their own level.
They gravitated lower and lower with the growing weakness of the wage-earner. If Cobbett had
been at the head of a movement for preserving to the labourer a right bestowed on him by Act of
Parliament, either he would have succeeded, or the disease would have come to a crisis in 1816,
instead of taking the form of a lingering and wasting illness. Either, that is, other classes would have
had to make the economies necessary to keep the labourers' wages at the customary point, or the
labourers would have made their last throw before they had been desolated and weakened by
another fifteen years of famine.
There is another respect in which the minimum wage policy would have profoundly altered the
character of village society. It would have given the village labourers a bond of union before they
had lost the memories and the habits of their more independent life; it would have made them an
organised force, something like the organised forces that have built up a standard of life for
industrial workmen. An important passage in Fielding's Tom Jones shows that there was material for
such combination in the commoners of the old village. Fielding is talking of his borrowings from the
classics and he defends himself with this analogy; 'The ancients may be considered as a rich
common, where every person who hath the smallest tenement in Parnassus hath a free right to
batten his muse: or, to place it in a clearer light, we moderns are to the ancients what the poor are to
the rich. By the poor here I mean that large and venerable body which in English we call the mob.
Now whoever hath had the honour to be admitted to any degree of intimacy with this mob must well
know, that it is one of their established maims to plunder and pillage their rich neighbours without
any reluctance: and that this is held to be neither sin nor crime among them. And so constantly do
they abide and act by this maxim, that in every parish almost in the kingdom there is a kind of
confederacy ever carrying on against a certain person of opulence called the squire whose property
is considered as free booty by all his poor neighbours; who, as they conclude that there is no
manner of guilt in such depredations, look upon it as a point of honour and moral obligation to
conceal and to preserve each other from punishment on all such occasions. In like manner are the
ancients such as Homer, Virgil, Horace, Cicero and the rest to be esteemed among us writers as so
many wealthy squires from whom we, the poor of Parnassus, claim an immemorial custom of taking
whatever we can come at.'(22*)
It would not have been possible to create a great labourers' union before the Combination Laws
were repealed in 1824, but if the labourers had been organised to defend their standard wage, they
would have established a tradition of permanent association in each village. The want of this was
their fatal weakness. All the circumstances make the spirit of combination falter in the country. In
towns men are face to face with the brutal realities of their lives, unsoftened by any of the assuaging
influences of brook and glade and valley. Men and women who work in the fields breathe something
of the resignation and peace of Nature; they bear trouble and wrong with a dangerous patience.
Discontent moves, but it moves slowly, and whereas storms blow up in the towns, they beat up in
the country. That is one reason why the history of the anguish of the English agricultural labourer so
rarely breaks into violence. Castlereagh's Select Committee in 1817 rejoiced in the discovery that
'notwithstanding the alarming progress which has been made in extending disaffection, its success
has been confined to the principal manufacturing districts, and that scarcely any of the agricultural
population have lent themselves to these violent projects.' There is a Russian saying that the
peasant must 'be boiled in the factory pot' before a revolution can succeed. And if it is difficult in the
nature of things to make rural labourers as formidable to their masters as industrial workers, there is
another reason why the English labourer rebelled so reluctantly and so tardily against what Sir
Spencer Walpole called, in the true spirit of a classical politician, 'his inevitable and hereditary lot.'
Village society was constantly losing its best and bravest blood. Bamford's description of the
poacher who nearly killed a gamekeeper's understrapper in a quarrel in a public-house, and then
hearing from Dr. Healey that his man was only stunned, promised the doctor that if there was but
one single hare on Lord Suffield's estates, that hare should be in the doctor's stew-pot next Sunday,
reminds us of the loss a village suffered when its poachers were snapped up by a game-preserving
bench, and tossed to the other side of the world. During the years between Waterloo and the
Reform Bill the governing class was decimating the village populations on the principle of the Greek
tyrant who flicked off the heads of the tallest blades in his field; the Game Laws, summary
jurisdiction, special commissions, drove men of spirit and enterprise, the natural leaders of their
fellows, from the villages where they might have troubled the peace of their masters. The village
Hampdens of that generation sleep by the shores of Botany Bay. Those who blame the supine
character of the English labourer forget that his race, before it had quite lost the memories and the
habits of the days of its independence and its share in the commons, was passed through this sieve.
The scenes we shall describe in the next chapter show that the labourers were capable of great
mutual fidelity when once they were driven into rebellion. If they had had a right to defend and a
comradeship to foster from the first, Cobbett, who spent his superb strength in a magnificent
onslaught on the governing class, might have made of the race whose wrongs he pitied as his own,
an army no less resolute and disciplined than the army O'Connell made of the broken peasants of
the West.
NOTES:
1. Report of the Poor Law Commission, 1834, p. 243.
2. Ibid., p. 84.
3. Ibid., pp. 56-7.
4. Report of the Poor Law Commission, 1834, p. 244.
5. Report of the Poor Law Commission, 1834, pp. 78-9.
6. Ibid., p. 80.
7. Ibid., p. 291.
8. Report of the Poor Law Commission, 1834, p. 94.
9. Ibid., p. 172.
10. Ibid., p. 66.
11. Report of the Poor Law Commission, 1834, pp. 98-104.
12. Ibid., p. 100.
13. Report of the Poor Law Commission, 1834, p. 108.
14. Ibid., p. 210.
15. Report of the Poor Law Commission, 1834, p. 73.
16. Ibid., p. 157.
17. Ibid., p. 158.
18. Ibid., p. 161.
19. Ibid., p. 130.
20. Appendix F, No. 3, to 1st Report of commissioners.
21. See Webb's History of Trade Unionism, p. 59.
22. Tom Jones, Bk., XII, chap. i.
Chapter Ten
The Last Labourers' Revolt
Where not otherwise stated the authorities for the two following chapters are the Home Office
Papers for the time (Municipal and Provincial, Criminal, disturbances, domestic, etc.), the Times and
local papers.
I
A traveller who wished to compare the condition of the English and the French rural populations in
1830 would have had little else to do than to invert all that had been written on the subject by
travellers a century earlier. At the beginning of the eighteenth century England had the prosperous
and France the miserable peasantry. But by the beginning of the nineteenth century the French
peasant had been set free from the impoverishing and degrading services which had made his lot
so intolerable in the eyes of foreign observers; he cultivated his own land, and lived a life, spare,
arduous, and exacting but independent. The work of the Revolution had been done so thoroughly in
this respect that the Bourbons, when Wellington and the allies lifted them back on to their throne,
could not undo it. It is true that the future of the French peasants was a subject of some anxiety to
English observers, and that M'Culloch committed himself to the prediction that in half a century,
owing to her mass of small owners, France would be the greatest pauper-warren in Europe. If any
French peasant was disturbed by this nightmare of the political economy of the time, he had the
grim satisfaction of knowing that his position could hardy become worse than the position that the
English labourer already occupied. He would have based his conclusion, not on the wild language of
revolutionaries, but on the considered statement of those who were so far from meditating revolution
that they shrank even from a moderate reform of Parliament. Lord Carnarvon said in one House of
Parliament that the English labourer had been reduced to a plight more abject than that of any race
in Europe; English landlords reproduced in the other that very parallel between the English labourer
and the West Indian negro which had figured so conspicuously in Thelwall's lectures. Thelwall, as
Canning reminded him in a savage parody on the Benedicite, got pelted for his pains. Since the
days of those lectures all Europe had been overrun by war, and England alone had escaped what
Pitt had called the liquid fire of Jacobinism. There had followed for England fifteen years of healing
peace. Yet at the end of all this time the conquerors of Napoleon found themselves in a position
which they would have done well to exchange with the position of his victims. The German peasant
had been rescued from serfdom; Spain and italy had at least known a brief spell of less unequal
government. The English labourer alone was the poorer; poorer in money, poorer in happiness,
poorer in sympathy, and infinitely poorer in horizon and in hope. The riches that he had been
promised by the champions of enclosure had faded into something less than a maintenance. The
wages he received without land had a lower purchasing power than the wages he had received in
the days when his wages were supplemented by common rights. The standard of living which was
prescribed for him by the governing class was now much lower than it had been in 1795.
This was not part of a general decline. Other classes for whom the rulers of England prescribed the
standard had advanced during the years in which the labourers had lost ground. The King's Civil List
had been revised when provisions rose. The salaries of the judges had been raised by three several
Acts of Parliament (1799, 1809, and 1825), a similar course had been taken in the case of officials.
Those who have a taste for the finished and unconscious cynicism of this age will note --
recollecting that the upper classes refused to raise wages in 1795 to meet the extra cost of living, on
the ground that it would be difficult afterwards to reduce them -- that all the upper-class officials,
whose salaries were increased because living was more expensive, were left to the permanent
enjoyment of that increase. The lives of the judges, the landlords, the parsons, and the rest of the
governing class were not become more meagre but more spacious in the last fifty years. During that
period many of the great palaces of the English nobility had been built, noble libraries had been
collected, and famous galleries had grown up, wing upon wing. The agricultural labourers whose
fathers had eaten meat, bacon, cheese, and vegetables were living on bread and potatoes. They
had lost their gardens, they had ceased to brew their beer in their cottages. In their work they had no
sense of ownership or interest. They no longer 'sauntered after cattle' on the open common, and at
twilight they no longer 'played down the setting sun;' the games had almost disappeared from the
English tillage, their wives and children were starting before their eyes, their homes were more
squalid, and the philosophy of the hour taught the upper classes that to mend a window or to put in
a brick to shield the cottage from damp or wind was to increase the ultimate miseries of the poor.
The sense of sympathy and comradeship, which had been mixed with rude and unskilful
government, in the old village had been destroyed in the bitter days of want and distress. Degrading
and repulsive work was invented for those whom the farmer would not or could not employ. De
Quincey, wishing to illustrate the manners of eighteenth-century France, used to quote M. Simond's
story of how he had seen, not very long before the Revolution, a peasant ploughing with a team
consisting of a donkey and a woman. The English poor could have told him that half a century later
there were English tillages in which it was the practice of the overseer to harness men and women
to the parish cart, and that the sight of an idiot woman between the shafts was not unknown within a
hundred miles of London.(1*) Men and women were living on roots and sorrel; in the summer of the
year 1830 four harvest labourers were found under a hedge dead of starvation, and Lord
Winchilsea, who mentioned the fact in the House of Lords, said that this was not an exceptional
case. The labourer was worse fed and worse housed than the prisoner, and he would not have been
able to keep body and soul together if he had not found in poaching or in thieving or in smuggling
the means of eking out his doles and wages.
The feelings of this sinking class, the anger, dismay, and despair with which it watched the going
out of all the warm comfort and light of life, scarcely stir the surface of history. The upper classes
have told us what the poor ought to have thought of these vicissitudes; religion, philosophy, and
political economy were ready with alleviations and explanations which seemed singularly helpful
and convincing to the rich. The voice of the poor themselves does not come to our ears. This great
population seems to resemble nature, and to bear all the storms that beat upon it with a strange
silence and resignation. But just as nature has her power of protest in some sudden upheaval, so
this world of men and women -- an underground world as we trace the distance that its voices have
to travel to reach us -- has a volcanic character of its own, and it is only by some volcanic surprise
that it can speak the language of remonstrance or menace or prayer, or place on record its
consciousness of wrong. This world has no member of Parliament, no press, it does not make
literature or write history; no diary or memoirs have kept alive for us the thoughts and cares of the
passing day. It is for this reason that the events of the winter of 1830 have so profound an interest,
for in the scenes now to be described we have the mind of this class hidden from us through all this
period of pain, bursting the silence by the only power at its command. The demands presented to
the farmer, the parson, and the squire this winter tell us as much about the South of England
labourer in 1830 as the cahiers tell us of the French peasants in 1789.
We have seen that in 1795 and in 1816 there had been serious disturbances in different parts of
England. These had been suppressed with a firm hand, but during hard winters sporadic violence
and blazing hay-stack showed from time to time that the fire was still alive under the ashes. The
rising of 1830 was far more general and more serious; several counties in the south of England
were in state bordering on insurrection; London was in a panic, and to some at least of those who
had tried to forget the price that had been paid for the splendour of the rich, the message of red
skies and broken mills and mob diplomacy and villages in arms sounded like the summons that
came to Hernani. The terror of the landowners during those weeks is reflected in such language as
that of the Duke of Buckingham, who talked of the country being in the hands of the rebels, or of
one of the Barings, who said in the House of Commons that if the disorders went on for three or four
days longer they would be beyond the reach of almost any power to control them. This chapter of
social history has been overshadowed by the riots that followed the rejection of the Reform Bill.
Every one knows about the destruction of the Mansion House at Bristol, and the burning of
Nottingham Castle; few know of the destruction of the hated workhouses at Selborne and Headley.
The riots at Nottingham and Bristol were a prelude to victory; they were the wild shout of power. If
the rising of 1830 had succeeded, and won back for the labourer his lost livelihood, the day when
the Headley workhouse was thrown down would be remembered by the poor as the day of the
taking of the Bastille. But this rebellion failed, and the men who led that last struggle for the labourer
passed into the forgetfulness of death and exile.
Kent was the scene of the first disturbances. There had been some alarming fires in the west of the
county during the summer, at Orpington and near Sevenoaks. In one case the victim had made
himself unpopular by pulling down a cottage built on a common adjoining his property, and turning
out the occupants. How far these fires were connected with later events it is impossible to say: the
authors were never discovered. The first riot occurred at Hardres on Sunday the 29th of August,
when four hundred labourers destroyed some threshing machines.(2*) Next day two magistrates
with a hundred special constables and some soldiers went to Hardres Court, and no more was
heard of the rioters. The Spectator early next year announced that it had found as a result of
inquiries that the riots began with a dispute between farmers over a threshing machine, in the
course of which a magistrate had expressed strong views against the introduction of these
machines. The labourers proceeded to destroy the machine, whereupon, to their surprise, the
magistrate turned on them and punished them; in revenge they fired his ricks.' A farmer in another
village, talking of the distress of the labourers, said, "Ah, I should be well pleased if a plague were to
break out among them, and then I should have their carcases as manure, and right good stuff it
would make for my hops." This speech, which was perhaps only intended as a brutal jest, was
reported; it excited rage instead of mirth, and the stacks of the jester were soon in a blaze. This act
of incendiarism was open and deliberate. The incendiary is known, and not only has he not been
tried, he has not even been charged.'(3*) Cobbett, on the other hand, maintained that the occasion
of the first riots was the importation of Irish labourers, a practice now some years old, that might well
inflame resentment, at a time when the governing class was continually contending that the sole
cause of distress was excessive population, and that the true solution was the removal of surplus
labourers to the colonies.
Whatever the actual origin of the first outbreak may have been, the destruction of machinery was to
be a prominent feature of this social war. This was not merely an instinct of violence, there was
method and reason in it. Threshing was one of the few kinds of work left that provided the labourer
with a means of existence above starvation level. A landowner and occupier near Canterbury wrote
to the Kent Herald,(4*) that in his parish, where no machines had been introduced, there were
twenty-three barns. He calculated that in these barns fifteen men at least would find employment
threshing corn up till May. If we suppose that each man had a wife and three children, this
employment would affect seventy-five persons. 'An industrious man who has a barn never requires
poor relief; he can earn from 15s. to 20s. per week; he considers it almost as his little freehold, and
that in effect it certainly is.' It is easy to imagine what the sight of one of these hated engines meant
to such a parish; the fifteen men, their wives and families would have found cold comfort, when they
had become submerged in the morass of parish relief, in the reflection that the new machine
extracted for their master's and the public benefit ten per cent. more corn than they could hammer
out by their free arms. The destruction of threshing machines by bands of men in the district round
Canterbury continued through September practically unchecked. By the end of the month three of
the most active rioters were in custody, and the magistrates were under the pleasant illusion that
there would be voluntary surrenders. In this they were disappointed, and the disturbances spread
over a wider area, which embraced the dover district. Early in October there was a riot at Lyminge,
at which Sir Edward Knatchbull and the Rev. Mr. Price succeeded in arresting the ringleaders, and
bound over about fifty other persons. Sir Edward Knatchbull, in writing to the Home Office, stated
that the labourers said 'they would rather do anything than encounter such a winter as the last.' Mr.
Price had to pay the penalty for his active part in this affair, and his ricks were fired.
Large rewards were promised from the first to informers, these rewards including a wise offer of
establishment elsewhere, but the prize was refused, and rick-burning spread steadily through a
second month. Threatening letters signed 'Swing,' a mysterious name that for the next few weeks
spread terror over England, were received by many farmers and landowners. The machine-breakers
were reported not to take money or plunder, and to refuse it if offered. Their programme was
extensive and formidable. When the High Sheriff attended one of their meetings to remonstrate with
them, they listened to his homily with attention, but before dispersing one of them said, 'We will
destroy the cornstacks and threshing machines this year, next year we will have a turn with the
parsons, and the third we will make war upon the statesmen.'(5*)
On 24th October seven prisoners were tried at the East Kent Quarter Sessions, for machine-
breaking. They pleaded guilty, and were let off with a lenient sentence of three days' imprisonment
and an harangue from Sir Edward Knatchbull, Hitherto all attempts to discover the incendiaries had
been baffled, but on 21st October a zealous magistrate wrote to the Home Office to say that he had
found a clue. He had apprehended a man called Charles Blow, and since the evidence was not
sufficient to warrant committal for arson, he had sent him to Lewes Jail as a vagrant for three
months. 'In company with Blow was a girl of about ten years of age (of the name of Mary Ann
Johnson), but of intelligence and cunning far beyond her age. It having been stated to me that she
had let fall some expressions which went to show that she could if she pleased communicate
important information, I committed her also for the same period as Blow.' Now the fires in question
had taken place in Kent, and the vagrants were apprehended in Sussex, consequently the officials
of both counties meddled with the matter and between them spoilt the whole plan, for Mary Ann and
her companion were questioned by so many different persons that they were put on their guard, and
failed to give the information that was expected. Thus at any rate, Lord Camden, the Lord-
Lieutenant, explained their silence, but he did not despair, 'if the Parties cannot even be convicted I
am apt to think their Committal now will do good, though they may be to be liberated afterwards, but
nothing is so likely to produce alarm and produce evidence as a Committal for a Capital Crime.'
However, as no more is heard of Mary Ann, it may be assumed that when she had served her three
months she left Lewes Jail a sadder and a wiser child.
Towards the end of October, after something of a lull in the middle of the month, the situation
became more serious. Dissatisfaction, or, as some called it, 'frightful anarchy,' spread to the
Maidstone and Sittingbourne districts. Sir Robert Peel was anxious to take strong measures. 'I beg
to repeat to you that I will adopt any measure-will incur any expense at the public charge-that can
promote the suppression of the outrages in Kent and the detection of the offenders.' A troop of
cavalry was sent to Sittingbourne. In the last days of October, mobs scoured the country round
Maidstone, demanding half a crown a day wages and constant employment, forcing all labourers to
join them, and levying money, beer, and provisions. At Stockbury, between Maidstone and
Sittingbourne, one of these mobs paraded a tricolour and a black flag. On 30th October the
Maidstone magistrates went out with a body of thirty-four soldiers to meet a mob of four hundred
people, about four miles from Maidstone, and laid hold of the three ringleaders. The arrests were
made without difficulty or resistance, from which it looks as if these bands of men were not very
formidable, but the officer in command of the soldiers laid stress in his confidential report on the
dangers of the situation and the necessity for fieldpieces, and Peel promptly ordered two pieces of
artillery to be dispatched.
At the beginning of November disturbances broke out in Sussex, and the movement developed into
an organised demand for a living wage. By the middle of the month the labourers were masters over
almost all the triangle on the map, of which Maidstone is the apex and Hythe and Brighton are the
bases. The movement, which was more systematic, thorough, and successful in this part of the
country than anywhere else, is thus described by the special correspondent of the Times, 17th
November: 'Divested of its objectionable character, as a dangerous precedent, the conduct of the
peasantry has been admirable. There is no ground for concluding that there has been any extensive
concert amongst them. Each parish, generally speaking, has risen per se; in many places their
proceedings have been managed with astonishing coolness and regularity; there has been little of
the ordinary effervescence displayed on similar occasions. The farmers have notice to meet the
men: a deputation of two or more of the latter produce a written statement, well drawn up, which the
farmers are required to sign; the spokesman, sometimes a dissenting or Methodist teacher, fulfils
his office with great propriety and temper. Where disorder has occurred, it has arisen from dislike to
some obnoxious clergyman, or tithe man, or assistant overseer, who has been trundled out of the
parish in a wheelbarrow, or drawn in triumph in a load of ballast by a dozen old women. The farmers
universally agreed to the demands they made: that is, they were not mad enough to refuse requests
which they could not demonstrate to be unreasonable in themselves, and which were urged by three
hundred or four hundred men after a barn or two had been fired, and each farmer had an incendiary
letter addressed to him in his pocket.'
There was another development of the movement which is not noted in this account by the
correspondent of the Times. It often happened that the farmers would agree to pay the wages
demanded by the labourers, but would add that they could not continue to pay those wages unless
rents and tithes were reduced. The labourers generally took the hint and turned their attention to
tithes and rents, particularly to tithes. Their usual procedure was to go in a body to the rector, often
accompanied by the farmers, and demand an abatement of tithes, or else to attend the tithe audit
and put some not unwelcome pressure upon the farmers to prevent them from paying.
It must not be supposed that the agitation for a living wage was confined to the triangular district
named above, though there it took a more systematic shape. Among the Home Office Papers is a
very interesting letter from Mr. D. Bishop, a London police officer, written from deal on 11th
November, describing the state of things in that neighbourhood: ' I have gone to the different Pot
Houses in the Villages, disguised among the Labourers, of an evening and all their talk is about the
wages, some give 1s. 8d. per day some 2s. some 2s. 3d.... all they say they want is 2s. 6d. per day
and then they say they shall be comfortable. I have every reason to believe the Farmers will give the
2s. 6d. per day after a bit... they are going to have a meeting and I think it will stop all outrages.'
The disturbances in Sussex began with a fire on 3rd November at an overseer's in Battle. The
explanation suggested by the authorities was that the paupers had been 'excited by a lecture lately
given here publicly by a person named Cobbett.' Next night there was another fire at Battle; but it
was at Brede, a village near Rye, that open hostilities began. As the rising at Brede set the fashion
for the district, it is perhaps worth while to describe it in some detail.(6*)
For a long time the poor of Brede had smarted under the insults of Mr. Abel, the assistant overseer,
who, among other innovations, had introduced one of the hated parish carts, and the labourers were
determined to have a reckoning with him. After some preliminary discussions on the previous day,
the labourers held a meeting on 5th November, and deputed four men to negotiate with the farmers.
At the conference which resulted, the following resolutions, drawn up by the labourers, were signed
by both parties:(7*) --
'Nov. 5, 1830. At a meeting held this day at the Red Lion, of the farmers, to meet the poor labourers
who delegated david Noakes Senior, Thomas Henley, Joseph Bryant and Th. Noakes, to meet the
gentlemen this day to discuss the present distress of the poor.... Resolution 1. The gentlemen agree
to give to every able-bodied labourer with wife and two children 2s. 3d. per day, from this day to the
1st of March next, and from the 1st of March to the 1st of Oct. 2s. 6d. per day, and to have ls. 6d.
per week with three children, and so on according to their family. Resolution 2. The poor are
determined to take the present overseer, Mr. Abell, out of the parish to any adjoining parish and to
use him with civility.'
The meeting over, the labourers went to Mr. Abel's house with their wives and children and some of
the farmers, and placed the parish cart at his door. After some hammering at the gates, Mr. Abel
was persuaded to come out and get into the cart. He was then solemnly drawn along by women and
children, accompanied by a crowd of five hundred, to the place of his choice, Vine Hall, near
Robertsbridge, on the turnpike road, where he was deposited with all due solemnity. Mr. Abel made
his way to the nearest magistrate to lodge his complaint, while the people of the parish returned
home and were regaled with beer by the farmers: 'and Mr. Coleman... he gave every one of us half
a pint of Beer, women and men, and Mr. Reed of Brede High gave us a Barrel because we had
done such a great thing in the Parish as to carry that man away, and Mr. Coleman said he never
was better pleased in his life than with the day's work which had been done.'(8*)
The parish rid of Mr. Abel, the next reform in the new era was to be the reduction of tithes, and here
the farmers needed the help of the labourers. What happened is best told in the words of one of the
chief actors. He describes how, a little before the tithe audit, his employer came to him when he was
working in the fields and suggested that the labourers should see if they could 'get a little of the tithe
off;' they were only to show themselves and not to take any violent action. Other farmers made the
same suggestions to their labourers. 'We went to the tithe audit and Mr. Hele came out and spoke to
us a good while and I and david Noakes and Thomas Noakes and Thomas Henley answered him
begging as well as we could for him to throw something off for us and our poor Children and to set
up a School for them and Mr. Hele said he would see what he could do.
'Mr. Coleman afterwards came out and said Mr. Hele had satisfied them all well and then Mr. Hele
came out and we made our obedience to him and he to us, and we gave him three cheers and went
and set the Bells ringing and were all as pleased as could be at what we had done.'
The success of the Brede rising had an immediate effect on the neighbourhood, and every parish
round prepared to deport its obnoxious overseer and start a new life on better wages. Burwash,
Ticehurst, Mayfield, Heathfield, Warbleton and Ninfield were among the parishes that adopted the
Brede programme. Sometimes the assistant overseer thought it wise to decamp before the cart was
at his door. Sometimes the mob was aggressive in its manners. 'A very considerable Mob,' wrote Sir
Godfrey Webster from Battle Abbey on 9th November, 'to the amount of nearly 500, having their
Parish Officer in custody drawn in a dung Cart, attempted to enter this town at eleven o'clock this
Morning.' The attempt was unsuccessful, and twenty of the rioters were arrested. The writer of this
letter took an active part throughout the disturbances. In this emergency he seems to have
displayed great zeal and energy. A second letter of his on 12th November gives a good description
of the state of affairs round Mayfield. 'The Collector of Lord Carrington's Tithes had been driven out
of the Parish and the same Proceeding was intended to be adopted towards the Parish Officer who
fled the place, it had been intended by the Rioters to have taken by Force this Morning as many
Waggons as possible (forcibly) carried off the Tithe Corn and distributed it amongst themselves in
case of interruption they were resolved to burn it. One of the most violent and dangerous papers I
have yet seen (a copy of which I enclose) was carried round the 3 adjoining Parishes and
unfortunately was assented to by too many Occupiers of Land. I arrived in Time to prevent its
circulation at Mayfield a small Town tho' populous parish 3000. By apprehending the Bearer of the
Paper who acted as Chief of the Party and instantly in presence of a large Mob committing him for
Trial I succeeded in repressing the tumultuous action then going on, and by subsequently calling
together the Occupiers of Land, and afterwards the Mob (composed wholly of Agricultural
Labourers) I had the satisfaction of mediating an arrangement between them perfectly to the content
of each party, and on my leaving Mayfield this afternoon tranquillity was perfectly restored at that
Place.' The violent and dangerous paper enclosed ran thus: 'Now gentlemen this is what we intend
to have for a married man to have 2s. and 3d. per day and all over two children 1s. 6d. per head a
week and if a Man has got any boys or girls over age for to have employ that they may live by there
Labour and likewise all single men to have 1s. 9d. a day per head and we intend to have the rents
lowered likewise and this is what we intend to have before we leave the place and if ther is no
alteration we shall proceed further about it. For we are all at one and we will keep to each other.'
At Ringmer in Sussex the proceedings were marked by moderation and order. Lord Gage, the
principal landowner of the neighbourhood, knowing that disturbances were imminent, met the
labourers by appointment on the village green. There were about one hundred and fifty persons
present. By this time magistrates in many places had taken to arresting arbitrarily the ringleaders of
the men, and hence when Lord Gage, who probably had no such intention, asked for the leader or
captain nobody came forward, but a letter was thrown into the ring with a general shout. The letter
which Lord Gage picked up and took to the Vestry for consideration read as follows: 'We the
labourers of Ringmer and surrounding villages, having for a long period suffered the greatest
privations and endured the most debasing treatment with the greatest resignation and forbearance,
in the hope that time and circumstances would bring about an amelioration of our condition, till, worn
out by hope deferred and disappointed in our fond expectations, we have taken this method of
assembling ourselves in one general body, for the purpose of making known our grievances, and in
a peaceable, quiet, and orderly manner, to ask redress; and we would rather appeal to the good
sense of the magistracy, instead of inflaming the passions of our fellow labourers, and ask those
gentlemen who have done us the favour of meeting us this day whether 7d. a day is sufficient for a
working man, hale and hearty, to keep up the strength necessary to the execution of the labour he
has to do? We ask also, is 9s. a week sufficient for a married man with a family, to provide the
common necessaries of life? Have we no reason to complain that we have been obliged for so long
a period to go to our daily toil with only potatoes in our satchels, and the only beverage to assuage
our thirst the cold spring; and on retiring to our cottages to be welcomed by the meagre and half-
famished offspring of our toilworn bodies? All we ask, then, is that our wages may be advanced to
such a degree as will enable us to provide for ourselves and families without being driven to the
overseer, who, by the bye, is a stranger amongst us, and as in most instances where permanent
overseers are appointed, are men callous to the ties of nature, lost to every feeling of humanity, and
deaf to the voice of reason. We say we want wages sufficient to support us, without being driven to
the overseer to experience his petty tyranny and dictation. We therefore ask for married men 2s. 3d.
per day to the first of March, and from that period to the first of October 2s. 6d. a day: for single men
ls. 9d. a day to the first of March, and 2s. from that time to the first of October. We also request that
the permanent overseers of the neighbouring parishes may be directly discharged, particularly
Finch, the governor of Ringmer poorhouse and overseer of the parish, that in case we are obliged,
through misfortune or affliction, to seek parochial relief, we may apply to one of our neighboring
farmers or tradesmen, who would naturally feel some sympathy for our situation, and who would be
much better acquainted with our characters and claims. This is what we ask at your hands -- this is
what we expect, and we sincerely trust this is what we shall not be under the painful necessity of
demanding.'
While the Vestry deliberated the labourers remained quietly in the yard of the poorhouse. One of
them, a veteran from the Peninsular War who had lost a limb, contrasted his situation on 9d. a day
with that of the Duke of Wellington whose 'skin was whole' and whose pension was £60,000 a year.
After they had waited some time, they were informed that their demands were granted, and they
dispersed to their homes with huzzas and tears of joy, and as a sign of the new and auspicious era
they broke up the parish grindstone, a memory of the evil past.(9*)
An important feature of the proceedings in Kent and Sussex was the sympathy of other classes with
the demands of the labourers. The success of the movement in Kent and Sussex, and especially of
the rising that began at Brede, was due partly, no doubt, to the fact that smuggling was still a
common practice in those counties, and that the agricultural labourers thus found their natural
leaders among men who had learnt audacity, resourcefulness, and a habit of common action in that
school of danger. But the movement could not have made such headway without any serious
attempt to suppress it if the other classes had been hostile. There was a general sense that the
risings were due to the neglect of the Government. Mr. Hodges, one of the Members for Kent,
declared in the Souse of Commons on 10th December that if the duke of Wellington had attended to
a petition received from the entire Grand Jury of Kent there would have been no disturbances.(10*)
The same spirit is displayed in a letter written by a magistrate at Battle, named Collingwood. 'I have
seen three or four of our parochial insurrections, and been with the People for hours alone and
discussing their matters with them which they do with a temper and respectful behaviour and an
intelligence which must interest everyone in their favor. The poor in the Parishes in the South of
England, and in Sussex and Kent greatly, have been ground to the dust in many instances by the
Poor Laws. Instead of happy peasants they are made miserable and sour tempered paupers. Every
Parish has its own peculiar system, directed more strictly, and executed with more or less severity or
harshness. A principal tradesman in Salehurst (Sussex) in one part of which, Robertsbridge, we had
our row the other night, said to me these words " You attended our meeting the other day and voted
with me against the two principal Rate payers in this parish, two Millers, paying the people in two
gallons of bad flour instead of money. You heard how saucy they were to their betters, can you
wonder if they are more violent to their inferiors? They never call a man Tom, Dick etc. but you d----
d rascal etc., at every word, and force them to take their flour. Should you wonder that they are
dissatisfied? "These words he used to me a week before our Robertsbridge Row. Each of these
Parochial Rows differs in character as the man whom they select as leader differs in impudence or
courage or audacity or whatever you may call it. If they are opposed at the moment, their resistance
shows itself in more or less violent outrages; personally I witnessed but one, that of Robertsbridge
putting Mr. Johnson into the cart, and that was half an accident. I was a stranger to them, went
among them and was told by hundreds after that most unjustifiable assault that I was safe among
them as in my bed, and I never thought otherwise. One or two desperate characters, and such there
are, may at any moment make the contest of Parish A differ from that of Parish B, but their spirit, as
far as regards loyalty and love for the King and Laws, is, I believe, on my conscience, sound. I feel
convinced that all the cavalry in the world, if sent into Sussex, and all the spirited acts of Sir Godfrey
Webster, who, however, is invaluable here will (not?) stop this spirit from running through
Hampshire, Wiltshire, Somersetshire, where Mr. Hobhouse, your predecessor, told me the other day
that they have got the wages for single men down to 6s. per week (on which they cannot live)
through many other counties. In a week you will have Demands for cavalry from Hampshire under
the same feeling of alarm as I and all here entertained: the next week from Wiltshire, Dorsetshire,
and all the counties in which the poor Rates have been raised for the payment of the poor up to
Essex and the very neighbourhood of London, where Mr. Geo. Palmer, a magistrate, told me lately
that the poor single man is got down to 6s. I shall be over to-morrow probably at Benenden where
they are resolved not to let either Mr. Hodges's taxes, the tithes or the King's taxes be paid. So I
hear, and so I dare say two or three carter boys may have said. I shall go to-morrow and if I see
occasion will arrest some man, and break his head with my staff. But do you suppose that that
(though a show of vigor is not without avail) will prevent Somersetshire men from crying out, when
the train has got to them, we will not live on 6s. per week, for living it is not, but a long starving, and
we will have tithes and taxes, and I know not what else done away with. The only way to stop them
is to run before the evil. Let the Hampshire Magistrates and Vestries raise the wages before the
Row gets to their County, and you will stop the thing from spreading, otherwise you will not, I am
satisfied. In saying all this, I know that I differ with many able and excellent Magistrates, and my
opinion may be wrong, but I state it to you.'
It is not surprising that magistrates holding these opinions acted rather less vigorously than the
central Government wished, and that Lord Camden's appeals to them not to let their political
feelings and 'fanciful Crotchets'(11*) interfere with their activity were unsuccessful. But even had all
the magistrates been united and eager to crush the risings they could not act without support from
classes that were reluctant to give it. The first thought of the big landed proprietors was to
reestablish the yeomanry, but they found an unexpected obstacle in the temper of the farmers. The
High Sheriff, after consultation with the Home Secretary, convened a meeting for this purpose at
Canterbury on 1st November, but proceedings took an unexpected turn, the farmers recommending
as a preferable alternative that public salaries should be reduced, and the meeting adjourned
without result. There were similar surprises at other meetings summoned with this object, and
landlords who expected to find the farmers rallying to their support were met with awkward
resolutions calling for reductions in rent and tithes. The Kent Herald went so far as to say that only
the dependents of great landowners will join the yeomanry, 'this most unpopular corps.' The
magistrates found it equally difficult to enlist special constables, the farmers and tradesmen
definitely refusing to act in this capacity at Maidstone, at Cranbrook, at Tonbridge, and at Tonbridge
Wells,(12*) as well as in the smaller villages. The chairman of the Battle magistrates wrote to the
Home Office to say that he intended to reduce his rents in the hope that the farmers would then
consent to serve.
Even the Coast Blockade Service was not considered trustworthy. 'It is the last force,' wrote one
magistrate, 'I should resort to, on account of the feeling which exists between them and the people
hereabouts.'(13*) In the absence of local help, the magistrates had to rely on military aid to quell a
mob, or to execute a warrant. Demands for troops from different quarters were incessant, and
sometimes querulous. 'If you cannot send a military force,' wrote one indignant country gentleman
from Heathfield on 14th November, 'for God's sake, say so, without delay, in order that we may
remove our families to a place of safety from a district which want of support renders us totally
unable longer to defend.'(14*) Troops were despatched to Cranbrook, but when the Battle
magistrates sent thither for help they were told to their great annoyance that no soldiers could be
spared. The Government indeed found it impossible to supply enough troops. 'My dear Lord
Liverpool,' wrote Sir Robert Peel on 15th November, 'since I last saw you I have made
arrangements for sending every disposable cavalry soldier into Kent and the east part of Sussex.
General Dalbiac will take the command. He will be at Battel to-day to confer with the Magistracy and
to attempt to establish some effectual plan of operations against the rioters.'
The 7th Dragoon Guards at Canterbury were to provide for East Kent; the 2nd Dragoon Guards at
Maidstone were to provide for Mid-kent; and the 5th Dragoon Guards at Tunbridge Wells for the
whole of East Sussex. Sir Robert Peel meanwhile thought that the magistrates should themselves
play a more active part, and he continually expressed the hope that they would 'meet and concert
some effectual mode of resisting the illegal demands.'(15*) He deprecated strongly the action of
certain magistrates in yielding to the mobs. Mr. Collingwood, who has been mentioned already,
received a severe reproof for his behaviour at Goudhurst, where he had adopted a conciliatory
policy and let off the rioters on their own recognisances. 'We did not think the case a very strong
one,' he wrote on 18th November, 'or see any very urgent necessity for the apprehension of Eaves,
nor after Captain King's statement that he had not felt a blow, could we consider the assault of a
magistrate proved. The whole parish unanimously begged them off, and said that their being
discharged on their own recognisances would probably contribute to the peace of the parish.'
The same weakness, or sympathy, was displayed by magistrates in the western part of Sussex,
where the rising spread after the middle of November. In the Arundel district the magistrates
anticipated disturbances by holding a meeting of the inhabitants to fix the scale of wages. The
wages agreed on were '2s. a day wet and dry and 1s. 6d. a week for every child (above 2 ) under 4,'
during the winter: from Lady day to Michaelmas 14s. a week, wet and dry, with the same allowance
for children. A scale was also drawn up for lads and young men. The mobs were demanding 14s. a
week all the year round, but they seem to have acquiesced in the Arundel scale, and to have given
no further trouble. At Horsham, the labourers adopted more violent measures and met with almost
universal sympathy. There was a strong Radical party in that town, and one magistrate described it
later as 'a hot Bed of Sedition.' Attempts were made, without success, to show that the Radicals
were at the bottom of the disturbances. The district round Horsham was in an agitated state. Among
others who received threatening letters was Sir Timothy Shelley of Field Place. The letter was
couched in the general spirit of Shelley's song to the men of England: --
<poem>
'Men of England, wherefore plough,
For the lords who lay ye low,'
</poem>
which his father may, or may not, have read. The writer urged him, 'if you wish to escape the
impending danger in this world and in that which is to come,' to go round to the miserable beings
from whom he exacted tithes, 'and enquire and hear from there own lips what disstres there in.' Like
many of these letters, it contained at the end a rough picture of a knife, with 'Beware of the fatel
daggar' inscribed on it.
In Horsham itself the mob, composed of from seven hundred to a thousand persons, summoned a
vestry meeting in the church. Mr. Sanctuary, the High Sheriff for Sussex, described the episode in a
letter to the Home Office on the same day (18th November). The labourers, he said, demanded 2s.
6d. a day, and the lowering of rents and tithes: 'all these complaints were attended to -- thought
reasonable and complied with,' and the meeting dispersed quietly. Anticipating, it may be, some
censure, he added, 'I should have found it quite impossible to have prevailed upon any person to
serve as special constable -- most of the tradespeople and many of the farmers considering the
demands of the people but just (and) equitable -- indeed many of them advocated (them) a doctor
spoke about the taxes -- but no one backed him -- that was not the object of the meeting.' A lady
living at Horsham wrote a more vivid account of the day's work. She described how the mob made
everybody come to the church. Mr. Simpson, the vicar, went without more ado, but Mr. Hurst, senior,
owner of the great tithes, held out till the mob seized a chariot from the King's Arms and dragged it
to his door. Whilst the chariot was being brought he slipped out, and entered the church with his two
sons. All the gentlemen stood up at the altar, while the farmers encouraged the labourers in the
body of the church. 'Mr. Hurst held out so long that it was feared blood would be shed, the doors
were shut till the demands were granted, no lights were allowed, the Iron railing that surrounds the
Monuments torn up, and the sacred boundary between the chancel and Altar overleapt before he
would yield.' Mr. Hurst himself wrote to the Home Office to say that it was only the promise to reduce
rents and tithes that had prevented serious riots, but he met with little sympathy at headquarters. 'I
cannot concur,' wrote Sir Robert Peel, 'in the opinion of Mr. Hurst that it was expedient or necessary
for the Vestry to yield to the demands of the Mob. In every case that I have seen, in which the mob
has been firmly and temperately resisted, they have given way without resorting to personal
violence.' A neighbouring magistrate, who shared Sir Robert Peel's opinion about the affair, went to
Horsham a day or two later to swear in special constables. He found that out of sixty-three
'respectable householders' four only would take the oath. Meanwhile the difficulties of prodding
troops increased with the area of disturbances. 'I have requested that every effort may be made to
reinforce the troops in the western part of Sussex,' wrote Sir Robert Peel to a Horsham magistrate
on 18th November, 'and you may judge of the difficulty of doing so, when I mention to you that the
most expeditious mode of effecting this is to bring from Dorchester the only cavalry force that is in
the West of England. This, however, shall be done, and 100 men (infantry) shall be brought from the
Garrison of Portsmouth.'
Until the middle of November the rising was confined to Kent, Sussex and parts of Surrey, with
occasional fires and threatening letters in neighbouring counties. After that time the disturbances
became more serious, spreading not only to the West of Sussex, but to Berkshire, Hampshire, and
Wiltshire. On 22nd November the Duke of Buckingham wrote from Adington in Hampshire to the
duke of Wellington: 'Nothing can be worse than the state of this neighbourhood. I may say that this
part of the country is wholly in the hands of the rebels... 1500 rioters are to assemble to-morrow
morning, and will attack any farmhouses where there are threshing machines. They go about
levying contributions on every gentleman's house. There are very few magistrates; and what there
are are completely cowed. In short, something decisive must instantly be done.' The risings in these
counties differed in some respects from the rising in Kent and Sussex. The disturbances were not
so much like the firing of a train of discontent, they were rather a sudden and spontaneous
explosion. They lasted only about a week, and were well described in a report of Colonel Brotherton,
one of the two military experts sent by Lord Melbourne to Wiltshire to advise the magistrates. He
wrote on 28th November: 'The insurrectionary movement seems to be directed by no plan or
system, but merely actuated by the spontaneous feeling of the peasantry and quite at random.' The
labourers went about in larger numbers, combining with the destruction of threshing machines and
the demand for higher wages a claim for 'satisfaction' as they called it in the form of ready money. It
was their practice to charge £2 for breaking a threshing machine, but in some cases the mobs were
satisfied with a few coppers. The demand for ready money was not a new feature, for many
correspondents of the Home Office note in their letters that the mobs levied money in Kent and
Sussex, but hitherto this 'sturdy begging,' as Cobbett called it, had been regarded by the
magistrates as unimportant. The wages demanded in these counties were 2s. a day, whereas the
demands in Kent and usually in Sussex had been for 2s. 6d. or 2s. 3d. Wages had fallen to a lower
level in Hampshire, Berkshire and Wiltshire. The current rate in Wiltshire was 7s., and Colonel Mair,
the second officer sent down by the Home Office, reported that wages were sometimes as low as
6s. It is therefore not surprising to learn that in two parishes the labourers instead of asking for 2s. a
day, asked only for 8s. or 9s. a week. In Berkshire wages varied from 7s. to 9s., and in Hampshire
the usual rate seems to have been 8s.
The rising in Hampshire was marked by a considerable destruction of property. At Fordingbridge,
the mob under the leadership of a man called Cooper, broke up the machinery both at a sacking
manufactory and at a manufactory of threshing machines. Cooper was soon clothed in innumerable
legends: he was a gipsy, a mysterious gentleman, possibly the renowned 'Swing' himself. At the
Fordingbridge riots he rode on horseback and assumed the title of Captain Hunt. His followers
addressed him bareheaded. In point of fact he was an agricultural labourer of good character, a
native of East Grimstead in Wilts, who had served in the artillery in the French War. Some two
months before the riots his wife had robbed him, and then eloped with a paramour. This unhinged
his self-control; he gave himself up to drink and despair, and tried to forget his misery in reckless
rioting. Near Andover again a foundry was destroyed by a mob, after the ringleader, Gilmore, had
entered the justices' room at Andover, where the justices were sitting, and treated with them on
behalf of the mob. Gilmore also was a labourer; he was twenty-five years old and had been a
soldier.
The most interesting event in the Hampshire rising was the destruction of the workhouses at
Selborne and Headley. Little is reported of the demolition of the poorhouse at Selborne. The
indictment of the persons accused of taking part in it fell through on technical grounds, and as the
defendants were also the persons charged with destroying the Headley workhouse, the prosecution
in the Selborne case was abandoned. The mob first went to Mr. Cobbold, Vicar of Selborne, and
demanded that he should reduce his tithes, telling him with some bluntness 'we must have a touch
of your tithes: we think £300 a year quite enough for you... £4 a week is quite enough.' Mr. Cobbold
was thoroughly alarmed, and consented to sign a paper promising to reduce his tithes, which
amounted to something over £600, by half that sum. The mob were accompanied by a good many
farmers who had agreed to raise wages if the labourers would undertake to obtain a reduction of
tithes, and these farmers signed the paper also. After Mr. Cobbold's surrender the mob went on to
the workhouse at Headley, which served the parishes of Bramshott, Headley and Kingsley. Their
leader was a certain Robert Holdaway, a wheelwright, who had been for a short time a publican. He
was a widower, with eight small children, described by the witnesses at his trial as a man of
excellent character, quiet, industrious, and inoffensive. The master of the workhouse greeted
Holdaway with 'What, Holdy, are you here?' 'Yes, but I mean you no harm nor your wife nor your
goods: so get them out as soon as you can, for the house must come down.' The master warned
him that there were old people and sick children in the house. Holdaway promised that they should
be protected, asked where they were, and said the window would be marked. What followed is
described in the evidence given by the master of the workhouse: 'There was not a room left entire,
except that in which the sick children were. These were removed into the yard on two beds, and
covered over, and kept from harm all the time. This was done by the mob. They were left there
because there was no room for them in the sick ward. The sick ward was full of infirm old paupers. It
was not touched, but of all the rest of the place not a room was left entire.' The farmers looked on
whilst the destruction proceeded, and one at least of the labourers in the mob declared afterwards
that his master had forced him to join.
In Wiltshire also the destruction of property was not confined to threshing machines. At Wilton, the
mob, under the leadership of a certain John Jennings, aged eighteen,(16*) who declared that he
'was going to break the machinery to make more work for the poor people,' did £500 worth of
damage in a woollen mill. Another cloth factory at Quidhampton was also injured; in this affair an
active part was taken by a boy even younger than Jennings, John Ford, who was only seventeen
years old.(17*)
The riot which attracted most attention of all the disturbances in Wiltshire took place at Pyt House,
the seat of Mr. John Benett, M.P. for the county. Mr. Benett was a well-known local figure, and had
given evidence before several Committees on Poor Laws. The depth of his sympathy with the
labourers may be gauged by the threat that he uttered before the Committee of 1817 to pull down
his cottages if Parliament should make length of residence a legal method of gaining a settlement.
Some member of the Committee suggested that if there were no cottages there would be no
labourers, but Mr. Benett replied cheerfully enough that it did not matter to a labourer how far he
walked to his work: 'I have many labourers coming three miles to my farm every morning during the
winter, (the hours were six to six) 'and they are the most punctual persons we have.' At the time he
gave this evidence, he stated that about three-quarters of the labouring population in his parish of
Tisbury received relief from the poor rates in aid of wages, and he declared that it was useless to let
them small parcels of land. The condition of the poor had not improved in Mr. Benett's parish
between 1817 and 1830, and Lord Arundel, who lived in it, described it as 'a Parish in which the
Poor have been more oppressed and are in greater misery as a whole than any Parish in the
Kingdom.'(18*) It is not surprising that when the news of what had been achieved in Kent and
Sussex spread west to Wiltshire, the labourers of Tisbury rose to demand 2s. a day, and to destroy
the threshing machines. A mob of five hundred persons collected, and their first act was to destroy a
threshing machine, with the sanction of the owner, Mr. Turner, who sat by on horseback, watching
them. They afterwards proceeded to the Pyt House estate. Mr. Benett met them, parleyed and rode
with them for some way; they behaved politely but firmly, telling him their intentions. One incident
throws a light on the minds of the actors in these scenes. 'I then,' said Mr. Benett afterwards,
'pointed out to them that they could not trust each other, for any man, I said, by informing against ten
of you will obtain at once £500.' It was an adroit speech, but as it happened the Wiltshire labourers,
half starved, degraded and brutalised, as they might be, had a different standard of honour from that
imagined by this magistrate and member of Parliament, and the devilish temptation he set before
them was rejected. The mob destroyed various threshing machines on Mr. Benett's farms, and
refused to disperse; at last, after a good deal of sharp language from Mr. Benett, they threw stones
at him. At the same time a troop of yeomanry from Hindon came up and received orders to fire
blank cartridges above the heads of the mob. This only produced laughter; the yeomanry then
began to charge; the mob took shelter in the plantations round Pyt House and stoned the yeomanry,
who replied by a fierce onslaught, shooting one man dead on the spot,(19*) wounding six by cutting
off fingers and opening skulls, and taking a great number of prisoners. At the inquest at Tisbury on
the man John Harding, who was killed, the jury returned a verdict of justifiable homicide, and the
coroner refused to grant a warrant for burial, saying that the man's action was equivalent to felo de
se. Hunt stated in the House of Commons that the foreman of the jury was the father of one of the
yeomen.
We have seen that in these counties the magistrates took a very grave view of the crime of levying
money from householders. This was often done by casual bands of men and boys, who had little
connection with the organised rising. An examination of the cases described before the Special
Commissions gives the impression that in point of fact there was very little danger to person or
property. A farmer's wife at Aston Tirrold in Berkshire described her own experience to the Abingdon
Special Commission. A mob came to her house and demanded beer. Her husband was out and she
went to the door. 'Bennett was spokesman. He said "Now a little of your beer if you please." I
answered "Not a drop." He asked "Why?" and I said "I cannot give beer to encourage riot." Bennett
said "Why you don't call this rioting do you?" I said "I don't know what you call it, but it is a number of
people assembled together to alarm others: but don't think I'm afraid or daunted at it." Bennett said "
Suppose your premises should be set on fire?" I said "Then I certainly should be alarmed but I don't
suppose either of you intends doing that." Bennett said "No, we do not intend any such thing, I don't
wish to alarm you and we are not come with the intention of mischief."' The result of the dialogue
was that Bennett and his party went home without beer and without giving trouble.
It was natural that when mob-begging of this kind became fashionable, unpopular individuals should
be singled out for rough and threatening visits. Sometimes the assistant overseers were the objects
of special hatred, sometimes the parson. It is worth while to give the facts of a case at St. Mary
Bourne in Hampshire, because stress was laid upon it in the subsequent prosecutions as an
instance of extraordinary violence. The clergyman, Mr. Easton, was not a favourite in his parish, and
he preached what the poor regarded as a harsh and a hostile sermon. When the parish rose, a mob
of two hundred forced their way into the vicarage and demanded money, some of them repeating,
'Money or blood.' Mrs. Easton, who was rather an invalid, Miss Lucy Easton, and Master Easton
were downstairs, and Mrs. Easton was so much alarmed that she sent Lucy upstairs to fetch 10s.
Meanwhile Mr. Easton had come down, and was listening to some extremely unsympathetic
criticisms of his performances in the pulpit. 'Damn you,' said Daniel Simms,(20*) 'where will your
text be next Sunday?' William Simms was equally blunt and uncompromising. Meanwhile Lucy had
brought down the half-sovereign, and Mrs. Easton gave it to William Simms,(21*) who thereupon
cried 'All out,' and the mob left the Eastons at peace.
One representative of the Church was distinguished from most of the country gentlemen and
clergymen of the time by his treatment of one of these wandering mobs. Cobbett's letter to the
Hampshire parsons, published in the Political Register, 15th January 1831, contains an account of
the conduct of Bishop Sumner, the Bishop of Winchester. 'I have, at last, found a Bishop of the Law
Church to praise. The facts are these: the Bishop, in coming from Winchester to his palace at
Farnham, was met about a mile before he got to the latter place, by a band of sturdy beggars, whom
some call robbers. They stopped his carriage, and asked for some money, which he gave them. But
he did not prosecute them: he had not a man of them called to account for his conduct, but, the next
day, set twenty-four labourers to constant work, opened his Castle to the distressed of all ages, and
supplied all with food and other necessaries who stood in need of them. This was becoming a
Christian teacher.' Perhaps the bishop remembered the lines from Dryden's Tales from Chaucer,
describing the spirit in which the good parson regarded the poor:
'Who, should they steal for want of his relief,
He judged himself accomplice with the thief.'
There was an exhibition of free speaking at Hungerford, where the magistrates sat in the Town Hall
to receive deputations from various mobs, in connection with the demand for higher wages. The
magistrates had made their peace with the Hungerford mob, when a deputation from the Kintbury
mob arrived, led by William Oakley, a young carpenter of twenty-five. Oakley addressed the
magistrates in language which they had never heard before in their lives and were never likely to
hear again. 'You have not such d d flats to deal with now, as you had before; we will have 2s. a day
till Lady day, and 2s. 6d. afterwards for labourers and 3s. 6d. for tradesmen. And as we are here we
will have £5 before we leave the place or we will smash it.... You gentlemen have been living long
enough on the good things, now is our time and we will have them. You gentlemen would not speak
to us now, only you are afraid and intimidated.' The magistrates acceded to the demands of the
Kintbury mob and also gave them the £5, after which they gave the Hungerford mob £5, because
they had behaved well, and it would be unjust to treat them worse than their Kintbury neighbours.
Mr. Page, Deputy-Lieutenant for Berks, sent Lord Melbourne some tales about this same Kintbury
mob, which was described by Mr. Pearse, M.P., as a set of 'desperate savages.' 'I beg to add some
anecdotes of the mob yesterday to illustrate the nature of its component parts. They took £2 from
Mr. Cherry a magistrate and broke his Machine. Afterwards another party came and demanded One
Pound when the two parties had again formed into one, they passed by Mr. Cherry's door and said
they had taken one pound too much, which they offered to return to him which it is said he refused-
they had before understood that Mrs. Cherry was unwell and therefore came only in small parties. A
poor woman passed them selling rabbitts, some few of the mob took some by force, the ringleader
ordered them to be restored. At a farmer's where they had been regaled with bread cheese and
beer one of them stole an umbrella: the ringleader hearing of it, as they were passing the canal
threw him into it and gave him a good ducking.'(22*)
In the early days of the rising in Hampshire, Wiltshire and Berkshire, there was a good deal of
sympathy with the labourers. The farmers in many cases made no objection to the destruction of
their threshing machines. One gentleman of Market Lavington went so far as to say that 'nearly all
the Wiltshire Farmers were willing to destroy or set aside their machines.' 'My Lord,' wrote Mr.
Williams, J.P., from Marlborough, 'you will perhaps be surprised to hear that the greatest number of
the threshing machines destroyed have been put out for the Purpose by the Owners themselves.'
The duke of Buckingham complained that in the district round Avington 'the farmers have not the
Spirit and in some instances not the Wish to put down' disturbances.(23*) At a meeting in
Winchester, convened by the Mayor to preserve the peace (reported in the Hampshire Chronicle of
22nd November), Dr. Newbolt, a clergyman and magistrate, described his own dealings with one of
the mobs. The mob said they wanted 12s. a week wages: this he said was a reasonable demand.
He acted as mediator between the labourers and farmers, and as a result of his efforts the farmers
agreed to these terms, and the labourers returned to work, abandoning their project of a descent on
Winchester. The Mayor of Winchester also declared that the wages demanded were not
unreasonable, and he laid stress on the fact that the object of the meeting was not to appoint special
constables to come into conflict with the people, but merely to preserve the peace. Next week Dr.
Newbolt put an advertisement into the Hampshire Chronicle, acknowledging the vote of thanks that
had been passed to him, and reaffirming his belief that conciliation was the right policy.(24*) At
Overton, in Hampshire, Henry Hunt acted as mediator between the farmers and a hungry and
menacing mob. Such was the fear of the farmers that they gave him unlimited power to make
promises on their behalf: he promised the labourers that their wages should be raised from 9s. to
12s., with house rent in addition, and they dispersed in delight.
Fortune had so far smiled upon the rising, and there was some hope of success. If the spirit that
animated the farmers, and in Kent many of the landowners, had lasted, the winter of 1830 might
have ended in an improvement of wages and a reduction of rents and tithes throughout the south of
England. In places where the decline of the labourer had been watched for years without pity or
dismay, magistrates were now calling meetings to consider his circumstances, and the Home Office
Papers show that some, at any rate, of the country gentlemen were aware of the desperate
condition of the poor. Unhappily the day of conciliatory measures was a brief one. Two facts
frightened the upper classes into brutality: one was the spread of the rising, the other the scarcity of
troops.(25*) As the movement spread, the alarm of the authorities inspired a different policy, and
even those landowners who recognised that the labourers were miserable, thought that they were in
the presence of a rising that would sweep them away unless they could suppress it at once by
drastic means. They pictured the labourers as Huns and the mysterious Swing as a second Attila,
and this panic they contrived to communicate to the other classes of society.
Conciliatory methods consequently ceased; the upper classes substituted action for diplomacy, and
the movement rapidly collapsed. Little resistance was offered, and the terrible hosts of armed and
desperate men melted down into groups of weak and ill-fed labourers, armed with sticks and stones.
On 26th November the Times could report that seventy persons had been apprehended near
Newbury, and that 'about 60 of the most forward half-starved fellows, had been taken into custody
some two miles from Southampton. Already the housing of the Berkshire prisoners was becoming a
problem, the gaols at Reading and Abingdon being overcrowded: by the end of the month the
Newbury Mansion House and Workhouse had been converted into prisons. This energy had been
stimulated by a circular letter issued on 24th November, in which Lord Melbourne urged the lord-
lieutenants and the magistrates to use firmness and vigour in quelling disturbances, and virtually
promised them immunity for illegal acts done in discharge of their duty. A village here and there
continued to give the magistrates some uneasiness, for example, Broughton in Hants, 'an open
village in an open country... where there is no Gentleman to overawe them,'(26*) but these were
exceptions. The day of risings was over, and from this time forward, arson was the only weapon of
discontent. At Charlton in Wilts, where 'the magistrates had talked of 12s. and the farmers had given
10s.,' a certain Mr. Polhill, who had lowered the wages one Saturday to 9s., found his premises in
flame. 'The poor,' remarked a neighbouring magistrate, 'naturally consider that they will be beaten
down again to 7s.'(27*) By 4th December the Times correspondent in Wiltshire and Hampshire
could report that quiet was restored, that the peasantry were cowed, and that men who had been
prominent in the mobs were being picked out and arrested every day. He gave an amusing account
of the trials of a special correspondent, and of the difficulties of obtaining information. 'The circular
of Lord Melbourne which encourages the magistrates to seize suspected persons, and promises
them impunity if the motives are good (such is the construction of the circular in these parts), and
which the magistrates are determined to act upon, renders inquiries unsafe, and I have received a
few good natured hints on this head. Gentlemen in gigs and post chaises are peculiar objects of
jealousy. A cigar, which is no slight comfort in this humid atmosphere, is regarded on the road as a
species of pyrotechnical tube; and even an eye glass is in danger of being metamorphosed into a
newly invented air gun, with which these gentlemen ignite stacks and barns as they pass. An
innocent enquiry of whose house or farm is that? is, under existing circumstances, an overt act of
incendiarism.'
In such a state of feeling, it was not surprising that labourers were bundled into prison for sour looks
or discontented conversation. A zealous magistrate wrote to the Home Office on 13th December
after a fire near Maidenhead, to say that he had committed a certain Greenaway to prison on the
following evidence: 'Dr. Vansittart, Rector of Shottesbrook, gave a sermon a short time before the
fire took place, recommending a quiet conduct to his Parishioners. Greenaway said openly in the
churchyard, we have been quiet too long. His temper is bad, always discontented and churlish,
frequently changing his Master from finding great difficulty in maintaining a large family from the
Wages of labour.'
Meanwhile the rising had spread westward to Dorset and Gloucestershire, and northward to Bucks.
In Dorsetshire and Gloucestershire, the disturbances were much like those in Wiltshire. In Bucks, in
addition to the usual agricultural rising, with the breaking of threshing machines and the demand for
higher wages, there were riots in High Wycombe, and considerable destruction of paper-making
machinery by the unemployed. Where special grievances existed in a village, the labourers took
advantage of the rising to seek redress for them. Thus at Walden in Bucks, in addition to demanding
2s. a day wages with 6d. for each child and a reduction of tithes, they made a special point of the
improper distribution of parish gifts. 'Another person said that buns used to be thrown from the
church steeple and beer given away in the churchyard, and a sermon preached on the bun day.
Witness (the parson) told them that the custom had ceased before he came to the parish, but that
he always preached a sermon on St. George's day, and two on Sundays, one of which was a
volunteer. He told them that he had consulted the Archdeacon on the claim set up for the distribution
of buns, and that the Archdeacon was of opinion that no such claim could be maintained.'
At Benson or Bensington, in Oxfordshire, the labourers, after destroying some threshing machines,
made a demonstration against a proposal for enclosure. Mr. Newton, a large proprietor, had just
made one of many unsuccessful attempts to obtain an Enclosure Act for the parish. Some thousand
persons assembled in the churchyard expecting that Mr. Newton would try to fix the notice on the
church door, but as he did not venture to appear, they proceeded to his house, and made him
promise never again to attempt to obtain an Enclosure Act.(28*)
The movement for obtaining higher wages by this rude collective bargaining was extinguished in the
counties already mentioned by the beginning of December, but disturbances now developed over a
larger area. A 'daring riot' took place at Stotfold in Bedfordshire. The labourers met together to
demand exemption from taxes, dismissal of the assistant overseer, and the raising of wages to 2s. a
day. The last demand was refused, on which the labourers set some straw alight in a field to alarm
the farmers. Mr. Whitbread, J.P., brought a hundred special constables, and arrested ten
ringleaders, after which the riot ceased. There were disturbances in Norfolk, Suffolk, and Essex; and
in many other counties the propertied classes were terrified from time to time by the news of fires. In
Cambridgeshire there were meetings of labourers to demand higher wages, in some places with
immediate success, and one magistrate was alarmed by rumours of a design to march upon
Cambridge itself on market day. In devonshire Lord Ebrington reported an agitation for higher
wages with encouragement from the farmers. He was himself impressed by the low wages in force,
and had raised them in places still quiet; a mistake for which he apologised. Even Hereford, 'this
hitherto submissive and peaceful county,' was not unaffected. In Northamptonshire there were
several fires, and also risings round Peterborough, Oundle and Wellingborough, and a general
outbreak in the Midlands was thought to be imminent. Hayricks began to blaze as far north as
Carlisle. Swing letters were delivered in Yorkshire, and in Lincolnshire the labourer was said to be
awakening to his own importance. There were in fact few counties quite free from infection, and a
leading article appeared in the Times on 6th December, in which it was stated that never had such a
dangerous state of things existed to such an extent in England, in the period of well-authenticated
records. 'Let the rich be taught that Providence will not suffer them to oppress their fellow creatures
with impunity. Here are tens of thousands of Englishmen, industrious, kind-hearted, but broken-
hearted beings, exasperated into madness by insufficient food and clothing, by utter want of
necessaries for themselves and their unfortunate families.'
Unfortunately Providence, to whom the Times attributed these revolutionary sentiments, was not so
close to the scene as Lord Melbourne, whose sentiments on the subject were very different. On 8th
December he issued a circular, which gave a death-blow to the hope that the magistrates would act
as mediators on behalf of the labourers. After blaming those magistrates who, under intimidation,
had advised the establishment of a uniform rate of wages, the Home Secretary went on, 'Reason
and experience concur in proving that a compliance with demands so unreasonable in themselves,
and urged in such a manner, can only lead, and probably within a very short period of time, to the
most disastrous results.' He added that the justices had 'no general legal authority to settle the
amount of the wages of labour.' The circular contained a promise on the part of the Government that
they would adopt 'every practicable and reasonable measure' for the allegation of the labourers'
privations.
From this time the magistrates were everywhere on the alert for the first signs of life and movement
among the labourers, and they forbade meetings of any kind. In Suffolk and Essex the labourers
who took up the cry for higher wages were promptly thrown into prison, and arbitrary arrests became
the custom. The movement was crushed, and the time for retribution had come. The gaols were full
to overflowing, and the Government appointed Special Commissions to try the rioters in Hampshire,
Wiltshire, Dorset, Berks, and Bucks. Brougham, who was now enjoying the office in whose
pompous manner he must have lisped in his cradle, told the House of Lords on 2nd December,
'Within a few days from the time I am addressing your Lordships, the sword of justice shall be
unsheathed to smite, if it be necessary, with a firm and vigorous hand, the rebel against the law.'
The disturbances were over, but the panic had been such that the upper classes could not persuade
themselves that England was yet tranquil. As late as Christmas Eve the Privy Council gave orders to
the archbishop to prepare 'a form of prayer to Almighty God, on account of the troubled state of
certain parts of the United Kingdom.' The archbishop's composition, which was published after
scores of men and boys had been sentenced to transportation for life, must have been recited with
genuine feeling by those clergymen who had either broken, or were about to break, their agreement
to surrender part of their tithes. One passage ran as follows: 'Restore, O Lord, to Thy people the
quiet enjoyment of the many and great blessings which we have received from Thy bounty: defeat
and frustrate the malice of wicked and turbulent men, and turn their hearts: have pity, O Lord, on the
simple and ignorant, who have been led astray, and recall them to a sense of their duty; and to
persons of all ranks and conditions in this country vouchsafe such a measure of Thy grace, that our
hearts being filled with true faith and devotion, and cleansed from all evil affections, we may serve
Thee with one accord, in duty and loyalty to the King, in obedience to the laws of the land, and in
brotherly love towards each other....'
We shall see in the next chapter what happened to 'the simple and ignorant' who had fallen into the
hands of the English judges.
NOTES:
1. See Fawley, p. 279.
2. Kent Herald, September 2, 1830.
3. Times, January 3, 1831.
4. September 30, 1830.
5. Brighton Chronicle, October 6, quoted in Times, October 14.
6. For Brede see H.O. Papers, Extracts from Poor Law Commissioners' Report, published 1833, and
newspapers.
7. They were signed by G.S. Hill, minister, by eight farmers and the four labourer delegates.
8. Affidavit in H.O. Papers.
9. Times, November 25.
10. The petition was as follows: 'We feel that in justice we ought not to suffer a moment to pass
away without communicated to your Grace the great and unprecedented distress which we are
enabled from our own personal experience to state prevails among all the peasantry to a degree not
only dreadful to individuals, but also to an extent which, if not checked, must be attended with
serious consequences to the national prosperity.' Mr Hodges does not mention the date, merely
stating that it was sent Wellington when Prime Minister.
11. H.O. Papers.
12. Ibid.
13. Ibid.
14. H.O. Papers.
15. Ibid.
16. Transported for life to New South Wales.
17. Ford was capitally convicted and sentenced to transportation for life, but his sentence was
commuted to imprisonment.
18. H.O. Papers.
19. According to local tradition he was killed not by the yeomanry but by a farmer, before the troop
came up. See Hudson, A Shepherd's Life, p. 248.
20. Transported for life to New South Wales.
21. Transported for life to New South Wales.
22. H.O. Papers.
23. Ibid.
24. Ten days later, after Lord Melbourne's circular of December 8, Dr Newbolt changed his tone.
Writing to the Home Office he depreciated the censure implied in that circular, and stated that his
conduct was due to personal infirmities and threats of violence: indeed he had subsequently heard
from a certain Mr Wickham that 'I left his place just in time to save my own life, as some of the Mob
had it in contemplation to drag me out of the carriage, and to destroy me upon the spot, and it was
entirely owing to the interference of some of the better disposed of the Peasantry that my life was
preserved.'
25. See p. 258.
26. H.O. Papers.
27. Ibid.
28. See Oxford University and City Herald, November 20 and 27, 1830.
Chapter Eleven
The Last Labourers' Revolt
II
The bands of men and boys who had given their rulers one moment of excitement and lively interest
in the condition of the poor had made themselves liable to ferocious penalties. For the privileged
classes had set up a code under which no labourer could take a single step for the improvement of
the lot of his class without putting his life and liberties in a noose. It is true that the savage laws
which had been passed against combination in 1799 and 1800 had been repealed in 1824, and that
even under the less liberal Act of the following year, which rescinded the Act of 1824, it was no
longer a penal offence to form a Trades Union. But it is easy to see that the labourers who tried to
raise their wages were in fact on a shelving and most perilous slope. If they used threats or
intimidation or molested or obstructed, either to get a labourer to join with them or to get an
employer to make concessions, they were guilty of a misdemeanour punishable with three months'
imprisonment. They were lucky if they ran no graver risk than this. Few of the prosecutions at the
Special Commissions were under the Act of 1825. A body of men holding a meeting in a village
where famine and unemployment were chronic, and where hardly any one had been taught to read
and write, might very soon find themselves becoming what the Act of 1714 called a riotous
assembly, and if a magistrate took alarm and read the Riot Act, and they did not disperse within one
hour, every one of them might be punished as a felon. The hour's interval did not mean an hour's
grace, for, as Mr. Justice Alderson told the court at Dorchester, within that hour 'all persons, even
private individuals, may do anything, using force even to the last extremity to prevent the
commission of a felony.'
There were at least three ways in which labourers meeting together to demonstrate for higher
wages ran a risk of losing their lives, if any of their fellows got out of hand from temper, or from
drink, or from hunger and despair. Most of the prosecutions before the Special Commissions were
prosecutions under three Acts of 1827 and 1828, consolidating the law on the subject of offences
against property and offences against the person. Under the eighth section of one Act (7 and 8
George IV. c. 30), any persons riotously or tumultuously assembled together who destroyed any
house, stable, coach-house, outhouse, barn, granary, or any building or erection or machinery used
in caring on any trade or manufacture were to suffer death as felons. In this Act there is no definition
of riot, and therefore 'the common law definition of a riot is resorted to, and in such a case if any one
of His Majesty's subjects was terrified there was a sufficient terror and alarm to substantiate that part
of the charge.'(1*) Under the sixth section of another Act, any person who robbed any other person
of any chattel, money, or valuable security was to suffer death as a felon. Now if a mob presented
itself before a householder with a demand for money, and the householder in fear gave even a few
coppers, any person who was in that mob, whether he had anything to do with this particular
transaction or not, whether he was aware or ignorant of it, was guilty of robbery, and liable to the
capital penalty. Under section 12 of the Act of the following year, generally known as Lansdowne's
Act, which amended Ellenborough's Act of 1803, it was a capital offence to attempt to shoot at a
person, or to stab, cut, or wound him, with intent to murder, rob, or maim. Under this Act, as it was
interpreted, if an altercation arose and any violence was offered by a single individual in the mob,
the lives of the whole band were forfeit. This was put very clearly by Baron Vaughan: 'There seems
to be some impression that unless the attack on an individual is made with some deadly weapons,
those concerned are not liable to capital punishment; but it should be made known to all persons
that if the same injury were inflicted by a blow of a stone, all and every person forming part of a
riotous assembly is equally guilty as he whose hand may have thrown it, and all alike are liable to
death.' Under section 4 of one Act of 1827 the penalty for destroying a threshing machine was
transportation for seven years, and under section 17 the penalty for firing a rick was death. These
were the terrors hanging over the village labourers of whom several hundreds were now awaiting
their trial.
The temper of the judges was revealed in their charges to the Grand Juries. In opening the
Maidstone Assizes on 14th December, Mr. Justice Bosanquet(2*) declared that though there might
be some distress it was much exaggerated, and that he was sure that those whom he had the
honour to address would find it not only their duty but their pleasure to lend an ear to the wants of
the poor.(3*) Mr. Justice Taunton(4*) was even more reassuring on this subject at the Lewes
Assizes: the distress was less than it had been twelve months before. 'I regret to say,' he went on,
'there are persons who exaggerate the distress and raise up barriers between different classes --
who use the most inflammatory language -- who represent the rich as oppressors of the poor. It
would be impertinent in me to say anything to you as to your treatment of labourers or servants.
That man must know little of the gentry of England, whether connected with the town or country,
who represents them as tyrants to the poor, as not sympathising in their distress, and as not anxious
to relieve their burdens and to promote their welfare and happiness.'(5*) In opening the Special
Commission at Winchester Baron Vaughan(6*) alluded to the theory that the tumults had arisen
from distress and admitted that it might be partly true, but, he continued, 'every man possessed of
the feelings common to our nature must deeply lament it, and endeavour to alleviate it (as you
gentlemen no doubt have done and will continue to do), by every means which Providence has put
within his power.' If individuals were aggrieved by privations and injuries, they must apply to the
Legislature, which alone could afford them relief, 'but it can never be tolerated in any country which
professes to acknowledge the obligations of municipal law, that any man or body of men should be
permitted to sit in judgment upon their own wrongs, or to arrogate to themselves the power of
redressing them. To suffer it would be to relapse into the barbarism of savage life and to dissolve
the very elements by which society is held together.'(7*) The opinions of the Bench on the sections
of the Act (7 and 8 George IV. c. 30) under which men could be hung for assembling riotously and
breaking machinery were clearly expressed by Mr. Justice Parke(8*) (afterwards Lord Wensleydale)
at Salisbury: 'If that law ceases to be administered with due firmness, and men look to it in vain for
the security of their rights, our wealth and power will soon be at an end, and our capital and industry
would be transferred to some more peaceful country 'whose laws are more respected or better
enforced.'(9*) By another section of that Act seven years was fixed as the maximum penalty for
breaking a threshing machine. Mr. Justice Alderson(10*) chafed under this restriction, and he told
two men, Case and Morgan, who were found guilty at the Salisbury Special Commission of going
into a neighbouring parish and breaking a threshing machine, that had the Legislature foreseen
such crimes as theirs, it would have enabled the court to give them a severer sentence.(11*)
Mr. Justice Park(12*) was equally stern and uncompromising in defending the property of the
followers of the carpenter of Nazareth against the unreasoning misery of the hour. Summing up in a
case at Aylesbury, in which one of the charges was that of attempting to procure a reduction of
tithes, he remarked with warmth: 'It was highly insolent in such men to requite of gentlemen, who
had by an expensive education qualified themselves to discharge the sacred duties of a Minister of
the Gospel, to descend from that station and reduce themselves to the situation of common
labourers.'(13*)
Few judges could resist the temptation to introduce into their charges a homily on the economic
benefits of machinery. Mr. Justice Park was an exception, for he observed at Aylesbury that the
question of the advantages of machinery was outside the province of the judges, 'and much
mischief often resulted from persons stepping out of their line of duty.'(14*) Mr. Justice Alderson
took a different view, and the very next day he was expounding the truths of political economy at
Dorchester, starting with what he termed the 'beautiful and simple illustration' of the printing press.
(15*) The illustration must have seemed singularly intimate and convincing to the labourers in the
dock who had never been taught their letters.
Such was the temper of the judges. Who and what were the prisoners before them? After the
suppression of the riots, the magistrates could pick out culprits at their leisure, and when a riot had
involved the whole of the village the temptation to get rid by this method of persons who for one
reason or another were obnoxious to the authorities was irresistible. Hunt, speaking in the House of
Commons,(16*) quoted the case of Hindon; seven men had been apprehended for rioting and they
were all poachers. Many of the prisoners had already spent a month in an overcrowded prison;
almost all of them were poor men; the majority could not read or write.(17*) Few could afford
counsel, and it must be remembered that counsel could not address the court on behalf of prisoners
who were being tried for breaking machines, or for belonging to a mob that asked for money or
destroyed property. By the rules of the gaol, the prisoners at Salisbury were not allowed to see their
attorney except in the presence of the gaoler or his servant. The labourers' ignorance of the law was
complete and inevitable. Many of them thought that the King or the Government or the magistrates
had given orders that machines were to be broken. Most of them supposed that if a person from
whom they demanded money threw it down or gave it without the application of physical force, there
was no question of robbery. We have an illustration of this illusion in a trial at Winchester when
Isaac Hill, junior, who was charged with breaking a threshing machine near Micheldever, for which
the maximum penalty was seven years, pleaded in his defence that he had not broken the machine
and that all that he did 'was to ask the prosecutor civilly for the money, which the mob took from
him, and the prosecutor gave it to him, and that he thanked him very kindly for it,'(18*) an admission
which made him liable to a death penalty. A prisoner at Salisbury, when he was asked what he had
to say in his defence to the jury, replied: 'Now, my Lord, I'se got nothing to say to 'em, I doant knaow
any on 'em.'(19*) The prisoners were at this further disadvantage that all the witnesses whom they
could call as to their share in the conduct of a mob had themselves been in the mob, and were thus
liable to prosecution. Thus when James Lush (who was afterwards selected for execution) and
James Toomer appealed to a man named Lane, who had just been acquitted on a previous charge,
to give evidence that they had not struck Mr. Pinniger in a scuffle, Mr. Justice Alderson cautioned
Lane that if he acknowledged that he had been in the mob he would be committed. Lane chose the
safer part of silence.(20*) In another case a witness had the courage to incriminate himself. When
the brothers Simms were being tried for extorting money from Parson Easton's wife, a case which
we have already described, Henry Bunce, called as a witness for the defence, voluntarily declared,
in spite of a caution from the judge (Alderson), that he had been present himself and that William
Simms did not use the expression 'blood or money.' He was at once ordered into custody. 'The
prisoner immediately sprung over the bar into the dock with his former comrades, seemingly
unaffected by the decision of the learned judge.'(21*)
Perhaps the darkest side of the business was the temptation held out to prisoners awaiting trial to
betray their comrades. Immunity or a lighter sentence was freely offered to those who would give
evidence. Stokes, who was found guilty at Dorchester of breaking a threshing machine, was
sentenced by Mr. Justice Alderson to a year's imprisonment, with the explanation that he was not
transported because 'after you were taken into custody, you gave very valuable information which
tended greatly to further the ends of justice.'(22*) These transactions, were not often dragged into
the daylight, but some negotiations of this character were made public in the trial of Mr. Deacle next
year. Mr. Deacle, a well-to-do gentleman farmer, was tried at the Lent Assizes at Winchester for
being concerned in the riots. One of the witnesses against him, named Collins, admitted in cross-
examination that he believed he should have been prosecuted himself, if he had not promised to
give evidence against Mr. Deacle; another witness, named Barnes, a carpenter, stated in cross-
examination that during the trials at the Special Commission, 'he being in the dock, and about to be
put on his trial, the gaoler Beckett called him out, and took him into a room where there were Walter
Long, a magistrate, and another person, whom he believed to be Bingham Baring, who told him that
he should not be put upon his trial if he would come and swear against Deacle.' When the next
witness was about to be cross-examined, the counsel for the prosecution abruptly abandoned the
case.(23*)
The first Special Commission was opened at Winchester with suitable pomp on 18th December. Not
only the prison but the whole town was crowded, and the inhabitants of Winchester determined to
make the best of the windfall. The jurymen and the Times special correspondent complained bitterly
of the abnormal cost of living, the latter mentioning that in addition to extraordinary charges for beds,
5s. a day was exacted for firing and tallow candles, bedroom fire not included. The three judges
sent down as commissioners were Baron Vaughan, Mr. Justice Parke, and Mr. Justice Alderson.
With them were associated two other commissioners, Mr. Sturges Bourne, of assistant overseer
fame, and Mr. Richard Pollen. The Duke of Wellington, as Lord-Lieutenant, sat on the Bench. The
Attorney-General, Mr. Sergeant Wild, and others appeared to prosecute for the Crown. The County
took up every charge, the Government only the more serious ones.
There were three hundred prisoners, most of them charged with extorting money by threats or with
breaking machinery. What chance had they of a fair trial? They started with the disabilities already
described. They were thrown by batches into the dock; the pitiless law was explained to the jury;
extenuating circumstances were ruled out as irrelevant. 'We do not come here,' said Mr. Justice
Alderson, 'to inquire into grievances. We come here to decide law.' But though evidence about
wages or distress was not admitted, the judges did not scruple to give their own views of the social
conditions which had produced these disturbances. Perhaps the most flagrant example was
provided by a trial which happily was for a misdemeanour only. Seven men were indicted for
conspiring together and riotously assembling for the purpose of raising wages and for compelling
others to join them. The labourers of the parish of Fawley had combined together for two objects,
the first to raise their wages, which stood at 9s. a week, the second to get rid of the assistant
overseer, who had introduced a parish cart, to which he had harnessed women and boys, amongst
others an idiot woman, named Jane Stevens. The labourers determined to break up the cart, but
they desisted on the promise of a farmer that a horse should be bought for it. Lord Cavan was the
large landowner of the parish. He paid his men as a rule 9s. a week, but two of them received 10s.
The mob came up to his house to demand an increase of wages: Lord Cavan was out, quelling
rioters elsewhere. Lady Cavan came down to see them. 'Seeing you are my neighbours and armed,'
said she, 'yet, as I am an unprotected woman, I am sure you will do no harm.' The labourers
protested that they meant no harm, and they did no harm. 'I asked them,' said Lady Cavan
afterwards, in evidence, 'why they rose then, there was no apparent distress round Eaglehurst, and
the wages were the same as they had been for several years. I have been in several of their
cottages and never saw any appearance of distress. They said they had been oppressed long and
would bear it no longer.' One man told her that he had 9s. a week wages and 3s. from the parish, he
had heard that the 3s. was to be discontinued. With the common-sense characteristic of her class
Lady Cavan assured him that he was not improving his position by idling. The labourers impressed
the Cavan men, and went on their peaceful way round the parish. The farmers who gave evidence
for the prosecution were allowed to assert that there was no distress, but when it came to evidence
for the defence a stricter standard of relevancy was exacted. One witness for the prisoners said of
the labourers: 'The men were in very great distress; many of the men had only a few potatoes in
their bag when they came to work.' 'The learned judges objected to this course of examination being
continued: it might happen that through drinking a man might suffer distress.' The Attorney-General,
in his closing speech, asserted again that the prisoners did not seem to have been in distress.
Baron Vaughan, in summing up, said that men were not to assemble and conspire together for the
purpose of determining what their wages should be. 'That which at first might be in itself a lawful act,
might in the event become illegal.... A respectful statement or representation of their grievances was
legal, and to which no one would object, but the evidence, if they believed it, showed that the
conduct of this assembly was far from being respectful. N o one could feel more for the distresses of
the people than he did, but he would never endure that persons should by physical strength compel
wages to be raised. There was no country where charity fell in a purer stream than in this. Let the
man make his appeal in a proper and respectful manner, and he might be assured that appeal
would never be heard in vain... His Lordship spoke very highly of conduct of Lady Cavan. She
visited the cottages of all those who lived in the neighbourhood, she knew they were not distressed,
and she also felt confident from her kindness to them that they would not offer her any violence.' All
seven were found guilty; four were sentenced to six months hard labour, and three to three months.
Very few, however, of the cases at Winchester were simple misdemeanours, for in most instances,
in addition to asking for higher wages, the labourers had made themselves liable to a prosecution
for felony, either by breaking a threshing machine or by asking for money. Those prisoners who had
taken part in the Fordingbridge riots, or in the destruction of machinery near Andover, or in the
demolition of the Headley Workhouse, were sentenced to death or to transportation for life. Case
after case was tried in which prisoners from different villages were indicted for assault and robbery.
The features varied little, and the spectators began to find the proceedings monotonous. Most of the
agricultural population of Hampshire had made itself liable to the death penalty, if the authorities
cared to draw the noose. The three hundred who actually appeared in Court were like the men on
whom the tower of Siloam fell.
A case to which the prosecution attached special importance arose out of an affair at the house of
Mr. Eyre Coote. A mob of forty persons, some of whom had iron bars, presented themselves before
Mr. Coote's door at two o'clock in the morning. Two bands of men had already visited Mr. Coote that
evening, and he had given them beer: this third band was a party of stragglers. Mr. Coote stationed
his ten servants in the portico, and when the mob arrived he asked them, 'What do you want, my
lads?' 'Money,' was the answer. 'Money,' said Mr. Coote, 'you shan't have.' One of the band seemed
to Mr. Coote about to strike him. Mr. Coote seized him, nine of the mob were knocked down and
taken, and the rest fled. Six of the men were prosecuted for feloniously demanding money. Baron
Vaughan remarked that outrages like this made one wonder whether one was in a civilised country,
and he proceeded to raise its moral tone by sentencing all the prisoners to transportation for life,
except one, Henry Eldridge, who was reserved for execution. He had been already capitally
convicted of complicity in the Fordingbridge riots, and this attempt to 'enter the sanctuary of Mr. Eyre
Coote's home' following upon that crime, rendered him a suitable 'sacrifice to be made on the altar
of the offended justice' of his country.
In many of the so-called robberies punished by the Special Commissions the sums taken were
trifling. George Steel, aged eighteen, was sentenced to transportation for life for obtaining a shilling,
when he was in liquor, from Jane Neale: William Sutton, another boy of eighteen, was found guilty
of taking 4d. in a drunken frolic: Sutton, who was a carter boy receiving 1s. 6d. a week and his food,
was given an excellent character by his master, who declared that he had never had a better
servant. The jury recommended him to mercy, and the judges responded by sentencing him to
death and banishing him for life. George Clerk, aged twenty, and E. C. Nutbean, aged eighteen,
paid the same price for 3d. down and the promise of beer at the Greyhound. Such cases were not
exceptional, as any one who turns to the reports of the trials will see.
The evidence on which prisoners were convicted was often of the most shadowy kind. Eight young
agricultural labourers, of ages varying from eighteen to twenty-five, were found guilty of riotously
assembling in the parish of St. Lawrence Wootten and feloniously stealing £2 from William Lutely
Sclater of Tangier Park. 'We want to get a little satisfaction from you' was the phrase they used. Two
days later another man, named William Farmer, was charged with the same offence. Mr. Sclater
thought that Farmer was like the man in the mob who blew a trumpet or horn, but could not swear to
his identity. Other witnesses swore that he was with the mob elsewhere, and said, 'Money wa want
and money wa will hae.' On this evidence he was found guilty, and though Mr. Justice Alderson
announced that he felt warranted in recommending that he should not lose his life, 'yet, it was his
duty,' he continued, 'to state that he should for this violent and disgraceful outrage be sent out of the
country, and separated for life from those friends and connections which were dear to him here: that
he should have to employ the rest of his days in labour, at the will and for the profit of another, to
show the people of the class to which the prisoner belonged that they cannot with impunity lend their
aid to such outrages against the peace and security of person and property.'
We have seen that at the time of the riots it was freely stated that the farmers incited the labourers
to make disturbances. Hunt went so far as to say in the House of Commons that in nineteen cases
out of twenty the farmers encouraged the labourers to break the threshing machines. The county
authorities evidently thought it unwise to prosecute the farmers, although it was proved in evidence
that there were several farmers present at the destruction of the Headley Workhouse, and at the
demonstration at Mr. Cobbold's house. Occasionally a farmer, in testifying to a prisoner's character,
would admit that he had been in a mob himself. In such cases the judge administered rebukes, but
the prosecution took no action. There was, however, one exception. A small farmer, John Boys, of
the parish of Owslebury, had thrown himself heartily into the labourers' cause. A number of small
farmers met and decided that the labourers' wages ought to be raised. Boys agreed to take a paper
round for signature. The paper ran as follows: 'We the undersigned are willing to give 2s. per day for
able-bodied married men, and 9s. per week for single men, on consideration of our rents and tithes
being abated in proportion.' In similar cases, as a rule, the farmers left it to the labourers to collect
signatures, and Boys, by undertaking the work himself, made himself a marked man. He had been
in a mob which extorted money from Lord Northesk's steward at Owslebury, and for this he was
indicted for felony. But the jury, to the chagrin of the prosecution, acquitted him. What followed is
best described in the report of Sergeant Wilde's speech in the House of Commons (21st July 1831).
'Boyce was tried and acquitted: but he (Mr. Wilde) being unable to account for the acquittal,
considering the evidence to have been clear against him, and feeling that although the jury were
most respectable men, they might possibly entertain some sympathy for him in consequence of his
situation in life, thought it his duty to send a communication to the Attorney-General, stating that
Boyce was deeply responsible for the acts which had taken place: that he thought he should not be
allowed to escape, and recommending that he be tried before a different jury in the other Court. The
Attorney-General sent to him (Mr. Wilde) to come into the other Court, and the result was that Boyce
was then tried and convicted.' In the other more complaisant Court, Farmer Boys and James
Fussell, described as a genteel young man of about twenty, living with his mother, were found guilty
of heading a riotous mob for reducing rents and tithes and sentenced to seven years' transportation.
(24*)
This was not the only case in which the sympathies of the jury created a difficulty. The Home Office
Papers contain a letter from Dr. Quarrier, a Hampshire magistrate, who had been particularly
vigorous in suppressing riots, stating that Sir James Parke discharged a jury at the Special
Commission 'under the impression that they were reluctant to convict the Prisoners which was more
strongly impressed upon the mind of the Judge, by its being reported to his Lordship that "some of
the Gosport Jurors had said, while travelling in the stage coach to Winchester, that they would not
convict in cases where the Labourers had been driven to excess by Poverty and low Wages!" It was
ascertained that some of those empannelled upon the acquitting Jury were from Gosport, which
confirmed the learned Judge in the determination to discharge them.'(25*)
An interesting feature of the trials at Winchester was the number of men just above the condition of
agricultural labourers who threw in their lot with the poor: the village mechanics, the wheelwrights,
carpenters, joiners, smiths, and the bricklayers, shoemakers, shepherds and small holders were
often prominent in the disturbances. To the judges this fact was a riddle. The threshing machines
had done these men no injury; they had not known the sting of hunger; till the time of the riots their
characters had been as a rule irreproachable. Nemo repente turpissimus fuit, and yet apparently
these persons had suddenly, without warning, turned into the 'wicked and turbulent men' of the
archbishop's prayer. Such culprits deserved, in the opinions of the bench, severer punishment than
the labourers, whom their example should have kept in the paths of obedience and peace.(26*)
Where the law permitted, they were sentenced to transportation for life. One heinous offender of this
type, Gregory, a carpenter, was actually earning 18s. a week in the service of Lord Winchester. But
the most interesting instances were two brothers, Joseph and Robert Mason, who lived at
Bullington. They rented three or four acres, kept a cow, and worked for the neighboring farmers as
well. Joseph, who was thirty-two, had a wife and one child; Robert, who was twenty-four, was
unmarried. Between them they supported a widowed mother. Their characters were exemplary, and
the most eager malice could detect no blot upon their past. But their opinions were dangerous: they
regularly took in Cobbett's Register and read it aloud to twenty or thirty of the villagers. Further,
Joseph had carried on foot a petition for reform to the king at Brighton from a hundred and seventy-
seven 'persons, belonging to the working and labouring classes' of Wonston, Barton Stacey and
Bullington, and was reported to have given some trouble to the king's porter by an importunate
demand for an audience. The recital of these facts gave rise to much merriment at his trial, and was
not considered irrelevant by judges who ruled out all allusions to distress.(27*) An interesting light is
thrown on the history of this petition by a fragment of a letter, written by Robert Mason to a friend,
which somehow fell into the hands of a Captain Thompson of Longparish, and was forwarded by
him to the Home Office as a valuable piece of evidence.
'P.S. -- Since I wrote the above I have saw and talked with two persons who say " Bullington Barton
and Sutton has sent a petition and why not Longparish Hursborne and Wherwell send another." I
think as much, to be sure if we had all signed one, one journey and expense would have served but
what is expence? Why I would engage to carry a Petition and deliver it at St. James for 30 shillings,
and to a place like Longparish what is that? If you do send one pray do not let Church property
escape your notice. There is the Church which cost Longparish I should think nearly £1500 yearly:
yes and there is an old established Chaple which I will be bound does not cost £25 annually. For
God sake...' (illegible).
The first charge brought against the Masons was that of robbing Sir Thomas Baring's steward of
£10 at East Stratton. The money had been taken by one of the mobs; the Masons were acquitted.
They were next put on their trial together with William Winkworth, a cobbler and a fellow reader of
Cobbett, and ten others, for a similar offence. This time they were accused of demanding £2 or £5
from Mr. W. Dowden of Micheldever. The Attorney-General, in opening the case, drew attention to
the circumstances of the Masons and Winkworth, saying that the offence with which they were
charged was of a deeper dye, because they were men of superior education and intelligence. A
humane clergyman, Mr. Cockerton, curate of Stoke Charity, gave evidence to the effect that if the
men had been met in a conciliatory temper in the morning they would have dispersed. Joseph
Mason and William Winkworth were found guilty, and sentenced, in the words of the judge, to 'be
cut off from all communion with society' for the rest of their lives. Robert Mason was still
unconvicted, but he was not allowed to escape. The next charge against him was that of going with
a mob which extorted five shillings from the Rev. J. Joliffe at Barton Stacey. He admitted that he had
accompanied the mob, partly because the labourers had urged him to do so, partly because he
hoped that Mr. Joliffe, being accustomed to public speaking, would be able to Persuade the
labourers to disperse before any harm was done. There was no evidence to show that he had
anything to do with the demand for money. He was found guilty and sentenced to transportation for
life. When asked what he had to say for himself, he replied, 'If the learned Counsel, who has so
painted my conduct to you, was present at that place and wore a smock frock instead of a gown,
and a straw hat instead of a wig, he would now be standing in this dock instead of being seated
where he is.'
Six men were reserved for execution, and told that they must expect no mercy on this side of the
grave: Cooper, the leader in the Fordingbridge riots; Holdaway, who had headed the attack on
Headley Workhouse; Gilmore, who had entered the justices' room in Andover 'in rather a violent
manner' and parleyed with the justices, and afterwards, in spite of their remonstrances, been a
ringleader in the destruction of a foundry in the parish of Upper Clatford; Eldridge, who had taken
part in the Fordingbridge riot and also 'invaded the sanctuary' of Mr. Eyre Coote's home; James
Aunalls, a lad of nineteen, who had extorted money at night with threats of a fire, from a person
whom he bade look over the hills, where a fire was subsequently seen, and Henry Cook. Cook was
a ploughboy of nineteen, who could neither read nor write. For most of his life, since the age of ten,
he had been a farm hand. For six months before the riots he had been employed at sawing, at 10s.
a week, but at the time of the rising he was out of work. After the riots he got work as a ploughboy at
about 5s. a week till his arrest. Like the other lads of the neighbourhood he had gone round with a
mob, and he was found guilty, with Joseph Mason, of extorting money from William dowden. For
this he might have got off with transportation for life, but another charge was preferred against him.
Mr. William Bingham Baring, J.P., tried, with the help of some of his servants, to quell a riot at
Northingdon down Farm. Silcock, who seemed the leader of the rioters, declared that they would
break every machine. Bingham Baring made Silcock repeat these words several times and then
seized him. Cook then aimed a blow at Bingham Baring with a sledge-hammer and struck his hat.
So far there was no dispute as to what had happened. One servant of the Barings gave evidence to
the effect that he had saved his master's life by preventing Cook from striking again; another
afterwards put in a sworn deposition to the effect that Cook never attempted to strike a second blow.
All witnesses agreed that Bingham Baring's hat had suffered severely; some of them said that he
himself had been felled to the ground. Whatever his injuries may have been, he was seen out a few
hours later, apparently in perfect health; next day he was walking the streets of Winchester; two
days later he was presented at Court, and within a week he was strong enough to administer a
sharp blow himself with his stick to a handcuffcd and unconvicted prisoner, a display of zeal for
which he had to pay £50. Cook did not put up any defence. He was sentenced to death.
Perhaps it was felt that this victim to justice was in some respects ill chosen, for reasons for severity
were soon invented. He was a heavy, stolid, unattractive boy, and his appearance was taken to
indicate a brutal and vicious disposition. Stories of his cruelties to animals were spread abroad. 'The
fate of Henry Cook,' said the Times correspondent (3rd January 1831), 'excites no commiseration.
From everything I have heard of him, justice has seldom met with a more appropriate sacrifice. He
shed some tears shortly after hearing his doom, but has since relapsed into a brutal insensibility to
his fate.' His age was raised to thirty, his wages to 30s. a week. Denman described him in the
House of Commons, after his execution, as a carpenter earning 30s. a week, who had struck down
one of the family of his benefactor, and had only been prevented from killing his victim by the
interposition of a more faithful individual. This is the epitaph written on this obscure ploughboy of
nineteen by the upper classes. His own fellows, who probably knew him at least as well as a
Denman or a Baring, regarded his punishment as murder. Cobbett tells us that the labourers of
Micheldever subscribed their pennies to get Denman's misstatements about Cook taken out of the
newspapers. When his body was brought home after execution, the whole parish went out to meet
it, and he was buried in Micheldever churchyard in solemn silence.
Bingham Baring himself, as has been mentioned, happened to offend against the law by an act of
violence at this time. He was not like Cook, a starving boy, but the son of a man who was reputed to
have made seven millions of money, and was called by Erskine the first merchant in Europe. He did
not strike his victim in a riot, but in cold blood. His victim could not defend himself, for he was
handcuffed. The man struck was a Mr. Deacle, a small farmer who had had his own threshing
machine broken, and was afterwards arrested with his wife, by Bingham Baring and a posse of
magistrates, on suspicion of encouraging the rioters. deacle's story was that Baring and the other
magistrates concerned in the arrest treated his wife with great insolence in the cart in which they
drove the Deacles to prison, and that Bingham Baring further struck him with a stick. For this deacle
got £50 damages in an action he brought against Baring. 'This verdict,' said the Morning Herald,
'seemed to excite the greatest astonishment; for most of the Bar and almost every one in Court said,
if on the jury, they would have given at least £5000 for so gross and wanton an insult and unfeeling
conduct towards those who had not offered the least resistance; the defendants not addressing the
slightest evidence in palliation or attempting to justify it.' The judge, in summing up, 'could not help
remarking that the handcuffing was, to say the least of it, a very harsh proceeding towards a lady
and gentleman who had been perfectly civil and quiet.' Meanwhile the case of the magistrates
against the Deacles had collapsed in the most inglorious manner. Though they had handcuffed
these two unresisting people, they had thought it wiser not to proceed against them. Deacle,
however, insisted on being tried, and by threatening the magistrates with an action, he obliged them
to prosecute. He was tried at the Assizes, and, as we have seen, the trial came to an abrupt
conclusion under circumstances that threw the gravest suspicion on the methods of the authorities.
Meanwhile the treatment these two persons had received (and we can imagine from their story how
innocent poor people, without friends or position, were handled) had excited great indignation, and
the newspapers were full of it. There were petitions sent up to Parliament for a Committee of Inquiry.
Now the class to which Cook was unlucky enough to belong had never sent a single member to
Parliament, but the Baring family had five Members in the House of Commons at this very moment,
one of whom had taken part with Bingham Baring in the violent arrest of the Deacles. The five,
moreover, were very happily distributed, one of them being Junior Lord of the Treasury in Grey's
Government and husband of Grey's niece, and another an important member of the Opposition and
afterwards Chancellor of the Exchequer under Peel. The Baring therefore were in less danger of
misrepresentation or misunderstanding; the motion for a Committee was rejected by a great majority
on the advice of Althorp and Peel; the leader of the House of Commons came forward to testify that
the Baring were friends of his, and the discussion ended in a chorus of praise for the family that had
been judged so harshly outside the walls of Parliament.
When the Special Commission had finished its labours at Winchester, 101 prisoners had been
capitally convicted; of these 6 were left for execution. The remaining 95 were, with few exceptions,
transported for life. Of the other prisoners tried, 36 were sentenced to transportation for various
periods, 65 were imprisoned with hard labour, and 67 were acquitted. Not a single life had been
taken by the rioters, not a single person wounded. Yet the riots in this county alone were punished
by more than a hundred capital convictions, or almost double the number that followed the devilish
doings of Lord George Gordon's mob. The spirit in which Denman regarded the proceeding is
illustrated by his speech in the House of Commons on the amnesty debate: 'No fewer than a
hundred persons were capitally convicted at Winchester, of offences for every one of which their
lives might have been justly taken, and ought to have been taken, if examples to such an extent had
been necessary.(28*)
These sentences came like a thunderclap on the people of Winchester, and all classes, except the
magistrates, joined in petitions to the Government for mercy. The Times correspondent wrote as
follows: --
'Winchester, Friday Morning, 7th Jan.
'The scenes of distress in and about the jail are most terrible. The number of men who are to be torn
from their homes and connexions is so great that there is scarcely a hamlet in the county into which
anguish and tribulation have not entered. Wives, sisters, mothers, children, beset the gates daily,
and the governor of the jail informs me that the scenes he is obliged to witness at the time of locking
up the prison are truly heartbreaking.
'You will have heard before this of the petitions which have been presented to the Home Office from
Gosport, Portsmouth, Romsey, Whitchurch, and Basingstoke, praying for an extension of mercy to
all the men who now lie under sentence of death. A similar petition has been got up in this city. It is
signed by the clergy of the Low Church, some of the bankers, and every tradesman in the town
without exception. Application was made to the clergy of the Cathedral for their signatures, but they
refused to give them, except conditionally, upon reasons which I cannot comprehend. They told the
petitioners, as I am informed, that they would not sign any such petition unless the grand jury and
the magistracy of the county previously affixed their names to it. Now such an answer, as it appears
to me, is an admission on their part that no mischief would ensue from not carrying into effect the
dreadful sentence of the law; for I cannot conceive that if they were of opinion that mischief would
ensue from it, they would sign the petition, even though it were recommended by all the talent and
respectability of the Court of quarter Sessions. I can understand the principles on which that man
acts, who asserts and laments the necessity of vindicating the majesty of the law by the sacrifice of
human life; but I cannot understand the reasons of those who, admitting that there is no necessity
for the sword of justice to strike the offender, decline to call upon the executive government to stay
its arm, and make their application for its mercy dependent on the judgment, or it may be the
caprice, of an influential aristocracy. Surely, of all classes of society, the clergy is that which ought
not to be backward in the remission of offences. They are daily preaching mercy to their flocks, and
it wears but an ill grace when they are seen refusing their consent to a practical application of their
own doctrines. Whatever my own opinion may be, as a faithful recorder of the opinions of those
around me, I am bound to inform you, that, except among the magistracy of the county, there is a
general, I had almost said a universal, opinion among all ranks of society, that no good will be
effected by sacrificing human life.'(29*)
This outburst of public opinion saved the lives of four of the six men who had been left for execution.
The two who were hung were Cooper and Cook. But the Government and the judges were
determined that the lessons of civilisation should not be wanting in impressiveness or in dignity.
They compelled all the prisoners who had been condemned by the Commission to witness the last
agonies of the two men whom public opinion had been unable to rescue. The account given in the
Times of 17th January shows that this piece of refined and spectacular discipline was not thrown
away, and that the wretched comrades of the men who were hanged suffered as acutely as
Denman or Alderson themselves could have desired. 'At this moment I cast my eyes down into the
felons' yard, and saw many of the convicts weeping bitterly, some burying their faces in their smock
frocks, others wringing their hands convulsively, and others leaning for support against the wall of
the yard and unable to cast their eyes upwards.' This was the last vision of English justice that each
labourer carried to his distant and dreaded servitude, a scene that would never fade from his mind.
There was much that England had not taught him. She had not taught him that the rich owed a duty
to the poor, that society owed any shelter to the freedom or the property of the weak, that the mere
labourer had a share in the State, or a right to be considered in its laws, or that it mattered to his
rulers in what wretchedness he lived or in what wretchedness he died. But one lesson she had
taught him with such savage power that his simple memory would not forget it, and if ever in an
exile's gilding dreams he thought with longing of his boyhood's famine-shadowed home, that
inexorable dawn would break again before his shrinking eyes and he would thank God for the wide
wastes of the illimitable sea.
The Special Commission for Wiltshire opened at Salisbury on 2nd January 1831. The judges were
the same as those at Winchester; the other commissioners were Lord Radnor, the friend of Cobbett,
and Mr. T. G. B. Estcourt. Lord Lansdowne, the Lord-Lieutenant, sat on the bench. The foreman of
the Grand Jury was Mr. John Benett, who has already figured in these pages as the proprietor
whose property was destroyed and the magistrate who committed the culprits. There were three
hundred prisoners awaiting trial.
The method in which the prosecutions were conducted in Wiltshire, though it did not differ from the
procedure followed in Hampshire and elsewhere, provoked some criticism from the lawyers. The
prosecutions were all managed by the county authorities. The clerks of the committing magistrates
in the different districts first took the depositions, and then got up all the prosecutions in their
capacity of solicitors to the same magistrates prosecuting as county authorities, to the exclusion of
the solicitors of the individual prosecutors. Further, all the prosecutions were managed for the
county by a single barrister, who assisted the Attorney-General and left no opening for other
members of the Bar. The counsel for one of the prisoners objected to this method, not only on the
ground of its unfairness to the legal profession, but on the wider ground of the interests of justice.
For it was inconsistent with the impartiality required from magistrates who committed prisoners, that
they should go on to mix themselves up with the management of the prosecution; in many cases
these magistrates served again as grand jurors in the proceedings against the prisoners. Such
procedure, he argued 'was calculated to throw at least a strong suspicion on the fair administration
of justice.' These protests, however, were silenced by the judges, and though the Attorney-General
announced that he was willing that the counsel for the magistrates should retire, no change was
made in the arrangements.
The Salisbury prisoners were under a further disadvantage peculiar, it is to be hoped, to that gaol.
They were forbidden to see their attorney except in the presence of the gaoler or his servants. This
rule seems to have been construed by the authorities in a manner that simplified considerably the
task of the prosecution. The facts of the case of James Lush, condemned to death on two charges
of extorting money in a mob, were made public by Hunt in a letter to the Times, 22nd January 1831.
Lush was a very poor man, but when first committed he sent for an attorney and made a full
confession. 'This confession, so confidentially made to his attorney (by an extraordinary rule of the
gaol) the legal adviser was compelled to submit to the inspection of the gaoler, which paper he kept
in his hands for several days and in all human probability, this document, or a copy of it, was either
submitted to the inspection of the judge, or placed in the hands of the prosecutor, the Crown
Solicitor, or the Attorney-General: when this man was called up for trial, such was his extreme
poverty, that he could not raise a guinea to fee counsel, and he was left destitute, without legal
advice or assistance.' The Attorney-General could only answer this charge in the House of
Commons by declaring that he had no recollection of any such circumstance himself, and that no
gentleman of the Bar would avail himself of information obtained in such a manner. Lush could not
distinguish these niceties of honour, or understand why his confession should be examined and
kept by the gaoler unless it was to be used against him, and it is not surprising that he thought
himself betrayed. It is only fair to Lord Melbourne to add that when Hunt drew his attention to this
iniquitous rule in Salisbury Gaol he had it abolished.
The cases tried were very similar to those at Winchester; batch after batch of boys and men in the
prime of life were brought up to the dock for a brief trial and sentence of exile. Such was the haste
that in one case at least the prisoners appeared with the handcuffs still on their wrists, a
circumstance which elicited a rebuke from the judge, and an excuse of overwork from the gaoler.
Amongst the first cases eight prisoners, varying in age from seventeen to thirty, were sentenced to
transportation for life for doing £500 worth of damage at Brasher's cloth mill at Wilton. Thirteen men
were transported for seven years and one for fourteen years for breaking threshing machines on the
day of the Pyt House affray. Mr. John Benett was satisfied with this tale of victims in addition to the
man killed by the yeomanry, and refrained from prosecuting for the stones thrown at him. For this he
took great credit in the House of Commons, and no doubt it was open to him to imitate Bingham
Baring's friends, and to talk of that kind of outrage as 'murder.'
At Salisbury, as at Winchester, evidence about distress and wages was ruled out by the judges
whenever possible; thus when twelve men, nine of whom were afterwards transported for seven
years, were being tried for breaking a threshing machine on the farm of a man named Ambrose
Patience, the cross-examination of Patience, which aimed at eliciting facts about wages and
distress, was stopped by the court on the ground that in a case of this sort such evidence was
scarcely regular; it was intimated, however, that the court would hear representations of this kind
later. But some light was thrown incidentally in the course of the trials on the circumstances of the
prisoners. Thus one of the Pyt House prisoners urged in his defence: 'My Lord, I found work very
bad in my own parish for the last three years, and having a wife and three children to support I was
glad to get work wherever I could get it. I had some work at a place four miles from my house.' He
then described how on his way to work he was met by the mob and forced to join them. 'It is a hard
case with me, my Lord; I was glad to get work though I could earn only seven shillings per week,
and it cost me a shilling a week for iron, so that I had only six shillings a week to support five
persons.' Another prisoner, Mould of Hatch, was stated by Lord Arundel to be very poor: he had a
wife and six children, of whom one or two had died of typhus since his committal. They had nothing
to live on but what they got at Lord Arundel's house. The benevolent Lord Arundel, or the parish,
must have supported the survivors indefinitely, for Mould was exiled for seven years. Barett again,
another of these prisoners, was supporting himself, a wife, and a child on 5s. a week. The usual rate
of wages in Wiltshire was 7s. a week.
Evidence about the instigation of the labourers by those in good circumstances was also ruled out,
and much that would be interesting in the history of the riots has thus perished. When six men were
being prosecuted for breaking a threshing machine on the farm of Mr. Judd at Newton Toney,
counsel for the defence started a cross-examination of the prosecutor designed to show that certain
landowners in the parish had instigated the labourers to the outrages, but he was stopped by Mr.
Justice Alderson, who declared that such an inquiry was not material to the issue, which was the
guilt or innocence of the prisoners. If the prisoners were found guilty these circumstances would be
laid before the court in mitigation of punishment. However strong the mitigating circumstances in
this case were, the punishment was certainly not mitigated, for all six men were sentenced to the
maximum penalty of seven years' transportation. In a similar case in Whiteparish it came out in the
evidence that Squire Bristowe had sent down buckets of strong beer, and that Squire Wynne, who
was staying with Squire Bristowe, was present at the breaking of the machine. In the affair at
Ambrose Patience's farm already mentioned, the defence of the prisoners was that Farmer Parham
had offered them half a hogshead of cider if they would come and break his machine, whilst in
another case three men were acquitted because one of the witnesses for the prosecution, a young
brother of the farmer whose property had been destroyed, unexpectedly disclosed the fact that his
brother had said to the mob: 'Act like men, go and break the machine, but don't go up to the house.'
The proportion of charges of extorting money was smaller at Salisbury than at Winchester: most of
the indictments were for breaking machines only. In some instances the prosecution dropped the
charge of robbery, thinking transportation for seven years a sufficient punishment for the offence.
Three brothers were sentenced to death for taking half a crown: nobody received this sentence for a
few coppers. In this case the three brothers, William, Thomas, and John Legg, aged twenty-eight,
twenty-one, and eighteen, had gone at midnight to the kitchen door of the house of Mrs.
Montgomery, wife of a J.P., and asked the manservant for money or beer. The man gave them half
a crown, and they thanked him civilly and went away. A curious light is thrown on the relations
between robbers and the robbed in the trial of six men for machine-breaking at West Grimstead: the
mob of fifty persons asked the farmer for a sovereign, he promised to pay it next day, whereupon
one of the mob, a man named Light who was his tenant, offered to pay the sovereign himself and to
deduct it from the rent.
At Salisbury, as at Winchester, the fate of the victims depended largely on the character given to the
prisoners by the local gentry. This was especially the case towards the end when justice began to
tire, and a good many charges were dropped. Thus Charles Bourton was only imprisoned for three
months for breaking a threshing machine, whilst John Perry was transported for seven years for the
same offence. But then John Perry had been convicted seven or eight times for poaching.
In Wiltshire, as in Hampshire, the judges were particularly severe to those prisoners who were not
agricultural labourers. A striking instance is worth quoting, not only as illustrating this special
severity, hut also because it shows that the judges when inflicting the maximum penalty of seven
years' transportation for machine-breaking were well award that it was tantamount to exile for life.
Thomas Porter, aged eighteen, a shepherd, Henry Dicketts, aged nineteen, a bricklayer's labourer,
Aaron Shepherd, aged forty (occupation not stated), James Stevens, aged twenty-five, an
agricultural labourer, and George Burbage, aged twenty-four, also an agricultural labourer, were
found guilty of machine-breaking at Mr. Blake's at Idmiston. Stevens and Burbage escaped with two
years' and one year's imprisonment with hard labour, respectively, and the following homily from Mr.
Justice Alderson to think over in prison: 'You are both thrashers and you might in the perversion of
your understanding think that these machines are detrimental to you. Be assured that your labour
cannot ultimately be hurt by the employment of these machines. If they are profitable to the farmer,
they will also be profitable ultimately to the labourer, though they may for a time injure him. If they
are not profitable to the farmer he will soon cease to employ them.' The shepherd boy of eighteen,
the bricklayer's labourer of nineteen, and their companion of forty were reserved for a heavier
penalty: 'As to you, Aaron Shepherd, I can give you no hope of remaining in this country. You
Thomas Porter, are a shepherd, and you Henry Dicketts, are a bricklayer's labourer. You have
nothing to do with threshing machines. They do not interfere with your labour, and you could not,
even in the darkness of your ignorance, suppose that their destruction would do you any good.... I
hope that your fate will be a warning to others. You will leave the country, all of you: you will see
your friends and relations no more: for though you will be transported for seven years only, it is not
likely that at the expiration of that term you will find yourselves in a situation to return. You will be in
a distant land at the expiration of your sentence. The land which you have disgraced will see you no
more: the friends with whom you are connected will be parted from you for ever in this world.'
Mr. Justice Alderson's methods received a good deal of attention in one of the Salisbury trials,
known as the Looker case. Isaac Looker, a well-to-do farmer, was indicted for sending a threatening
letter to John Rowland: 'Mr. Rowland, Haxford Farm, Hif you goes to sware against or a man in
prisson, you have here farm burnt down to ground, and thy bluddy head chopt off.' Some evidence
was produced to show that Isaac Looker had asserted in conversation that it was the magistrates
and the soldiers, and not the mobs, who were the real breakers of the peace. But this did not
amount to absolute proof that he had written the letter: to establish this conclusion the prosecution
relied on the evidence of four witnesses; the first had quarrelled with Looker, and had not seen his
writing for four or five years; the second denied that there had been any quarrel, but had not been in
the habit of speaking to the prisoner for five or six years, or seen his writing during that time; the
third had not had 'much of a quarrel' with him, but had not seen his writing since 1824; the fourth
was the special constable who found in Looker's bureau, which was unlocked and stood in the
kitchen where the family sat, a blank piece of paper that fitted on to the piece on which the letter
was written. More witnesses were called for the defence than for the prosecution, and they included
the vestry clerk of Wimborne, an ex-schoolmaster; all of these witnesses had known Looker's
writing recently, and all of them swore that the threatening letter was not in his writing. Mr. Justice
Alderson summed up against the prisoner, the jury returned a verdict of guilty, and sentence of
transportation for life was passed upon Looker in spite of his vehement protestations of innocence. 'I
cannot attend to these asseverations,' said Mr. Justice Alderson, 'for we all know that a man who
can be guilty of such an offence as that of which you have been convicted, will not hesitate to deny it
as you now do. I would rather trust to such evidence as has been given in your case, than to the
most solemn declarations even on the scaffold.'
The learned judge and the jury then retired for refreshment, when a curious development took
place. Edward, son of Isaac Looker, aged eighteen years, came forward and declared that he had
written the letter in question and other letters as well. He wrote a copy from memory, and the
handwriting was precisely similar. He explained that he had written the letters without his father's
knowledge and without a thought of the consequences, in order to help two cousins who were in
gaol for machine-breaking. He had heard people say that 'it would get my cousins off if threatening
letters were written.' He had let his father know in prison that he had written the letters, and had also
told his father's solicitor. Edward Looker was subsequently tried and sentenced to seven years'
transportation: Isaac's case was submitted to the Home Secretary for pardon.
Although, as we have said, the Government, or its representatives, grew rather more lenient towards
the end of the proceedings at Salisbury, it was evidently thought essential to produce some crime
deserving actual death. The culprit in this case was Peter Withers, a young man of twenty-three,
married and with five children. His character till the time of the riots was exemplary. He was
committed on a charge of riot, and briefed a lawyer to defend him for this misdemeanour. Just
before the trial came on the charge was changed, apparently by the Attorney-General, to the capital
charge of assaulting Oliver Calley Codrington with a hammer. His counsel was of course
unprepared to defend him on this charge, and, as he explained afterwards, 'it was only by the
humane kindness of the Attorney-General who allowed him to look at his brief that he was aware of
all the facts to be alleged against his client.' Withers himself seemed equally unprepared; when
asked for his defence he said that he would leave it to his counsel, as of course he had arranged to
do when the charge was one of misdemeanour only.
The incident occurred in an affray at Rockley near Marlborough. Mr. Baskerville, J.P., rode up with
some special constables to a mob of forty or fifty men, Withers amongst them, and bade them go
home. They refused, declaring that they did not care a damn for the magistrates. Mr. Baskerville
ordered Mr. Codrington, who was a special constable, to arrest Withers. A generallée ensued,
blows were given and received, and Codrington was hit by a hammer thrown by Withers. Withers'
own version of the affair was that Codrington attacked him without provocation in a ferocious
manner with a hunting whip, loaded with iron at the end. Baskerville also struck him. He aimed his
hammer at Codrington and it missed. Codrington's horse then crushed him against the wall, and he
threw his hammer a second time with better aim. There was nothing in the evidence of the
prosecution to discredit this version, and both Baskerville and Codrington admitted that they might
have struck him. Codrington's injuries were apparently more serious than Bingham Baring's; it was
stated that he had been confined to bed for two or three days, and to the house from Tuesday to
Saturday, and that he had a scar of one and a half inches on the right side of his nose. No surgeon,
however, appeared as a witness, and the hammer WaS not produced in court. Withers was found
guilty and reserved, together with Lush, for execution.
The special correspondent of the Times who had been present at Winchester made an interesting
comparison between the Hampshire and the Wiltshire labourers on trial (8th January 1831). The
Wiltshire labourers he described as more athletic in appearance and more hardy in manner. 'The
prisoners here turn to the witnesses against them with a bold and confident air: cross-examine
them, and contradict their answers, with a confidence and a want of common courtesy, in terms of
which comparatively few instances occurred in the neighbouring county.' In this behaviour the
correspondent detected the signs of a very low state of moral intelligence.
When the time came for the last scene in court there was no trace of the bold demeanour which had
impressed the Times correspondent during the conduct of the trials. For the people of Wiltshire, like
the people of Hampshire, were stunned by the crash and ruin of this catastrophic vengeance. The
two men sentenced to death were reprieved, but one hundred and fifty-four men and boys were
sentenced to transportation, thirty-three of them for life, the rest for seven or fourteen years, with no
prospect of ever returning to their homes. And Alderson and his brother judges in so punishing this
wild fling of folly, or hope, or despair, were not passing sentence only on the men and boys before
them: they were pronouncing a doom not less terrible on wives and mothers and children and babes
in arms in every village on the Wiltshire Downs. One man begged to be allowed to take his child,
eight months old, into exile, for its mother had died in childbirth, and it would be left without kith or
kin. He was told by the judge that he should have remembered this earlier. The sentence of final
separation on all these families and homes was received with a frenzy of consternation and grief,
and the judges themselves were affected by the spectacle of these broken creatures in the dock
and round the court, abandoned to the unchecked paroxysms of despair.(30*) 'Such a total
prostration of the mental faculties by fear,' wrote the Times correspondent, 'and such a terrible
exhibition of anguish and despair, I never before witnessed in a Court of Justice.' 'Immediately on
the conclusion of this sentence a number of women, who were seated in court behind the prisoners,
set up a dreadful shriek of lamentation. Some of them rushed forward to shake hands with the
prisoners, and more than one voice was heard to exclaim, "Farewell, I shall never see you more."'
'The whole proceedings of this day in court were of the most afflicting and distressing nature. But
the laceration of the feelings did not end with the proceedings in court. The car for the removal of
the prisoners was at the back entrance to the court-house and was surrounded by a crowd of
mothers, wives, sisters and children, anxiously waiting for a glance of their condemned relatives.
The weeping and wailing of the different parties, as they pressed the hands of the convicts as they
stepped into the car, was truly heartrending. We never saw so distressing a spectacle before, and
trust that the restored tranquillity of the country will prevent us from ever seeing anything like it
again.'
The historian may regret that these men do not pass out before him in a cold and splendid defiance.
Their blind blow had been struck and it had been answered; they had dreamt that their lot might be
made less intolerable, and the governing class had crushed that daring fancy for ever with
banishment and the breaking of their homes; it only remained for them to accept their fate with a
look of stone upon their faces and a curse of fire in their hearts. So had Muir and Palmer and many
a political prisoner, victims of the tyrannies of Pitt and Dundas, of Castlereagh and Sidmouth, gone
to their barbarous doom. So had the Lantenacs and the Gauvains alike gone to the guillotine.
History likes to match such calm and unshaken bearing against the distempered justice of power.
Here she is cheated of her spectacle. Outwardly it might seem a worse fate for men of education to
be flung to the hulks with the coarsest of felons: for men whose lives had been comfortable to be
thrust into the dirt and disorder of prisons. But political prisoners are martyrs, and martyrs are not
the stuff for pity. However bitter their sufferings, they do not suffer alone: they are sustained by a
Herculean comradeship of hopes and of ideas. The darkest cage is lighted by a ray from Paradise
to men or women who believe that the night of their sufferings will bring a dawn less cold and
sombre to mankind than the cold and sombre dawn of yesterday. But what ideas befriended the
ploughboy or the shepherd torn from his rude home? What vision had he of a nobler future for
humanity? To what dawn did he leave his wife or his mother, his child, his home, his friends, or his
trampled race? What robe of dream and hope and fancy was thrown over his exile or their hunger,
his poignant hour of separation, or their ceaseless ache of poverty and cold
'to comfort the human want.
From the bosom of magical skies'?
The three judges who had restored respect for law and order in Wiltshire and Hampshire next
proceeded to Dorchester, where a Special Commission to try the Dorsetshire rioters was. The rising
had been less serious in opened on 11th January Dorset than in the two other counties, and there
were only some fifty prisoners awaiting trial on charges of machine-breaking, extorting money and
riot. The Government took no part in the prosecutions; for, as it was explained in a letter to Denman,
'the state of things is quite altered; great effect has been produced: the law has been clearly
explained, and prosecutions go on without the least difficulty.'(31*) Baron Vaughan and Mr. Justice
Parke had given the charges at Winchester and Salisbury: it was now the turn of Mr. Justice
Alderson, and in his opening survey of the social conditions of the time he covered a wide field. To
the usual dissertation on the economics of machinery he added a special homily on the duties
incumbent on the gentry, who were bidden to discourage and discountenance, and if necessary to
prosecute, the dangerous publications that were doing such harm in rural districts. But their duties
did not end here, and they were urged to go home and to educate their poorer neighbours and to
improve their conditions. The improvement to be aimed at, however, was not material but moral.
'Poverty,' said Mr. Justice Alderson,' is indeed, I fear, inseparable from the state of the human race,
but poverty itself and the misery attendant on it, would no doubt be greatly mitigated if a spirit of
prudence were more generally diffused among the people, and if they understood more fully and
practised better their civil, moral and religious duties.'
The Dorsetshire labourers had unfortunately arrived at the precipitate conclusion that a spirit of
prudence would not transform 7s. a week into a reasonable livelihood. They used no violence
beyond breaking up the threshing machines. 'We don't intend to hurt the farmer,' they told the owner
of one machine, 'but we are determined that the land shall come down, and the tithes, and we will
have more wages.' When money was taken it seems to have been demanded and received in an
amicable spirit. The sums asked for were often very small. Sentence of death was pronounced on
two men, Joseph Sheppard and George Legg, for taking 2s. from Farmer Christopher Morey at
Buckland Newton. The mob asked for money, and the farmer offered them 1s.: they replied that
they wanted 1s. 6d., and the farmer gave them 2s. Sheppard's character was very good, and it
came out that he and the prosecutor had had a dispute about money some years before. He was
transported, but not for life. Legg was declared by the prosecutor to have been 'saucy and
impudent,' and to have 'talked rough and bobbish.' His character, however, was stated by many
witnesses, including the clergyman, to be exemplary. He had five children whom he supported
without parish help on 7s. a week: a cottage was given him but no fuel. Baron Vaughan was so
much impressed by this evidence that he declared that he had never heard better testimony to
character, and that he would recommend a less severe penalty than transportation. But Legg
showed a lamentable want of discretion, for he interrupted the judge with these words: 'I would
rather that your Lordship would put twenty-one years' transportation upon me than be placed in the
condition of the prosecutor. I never said a word to him, that I declare.' Baron Vaughan sardonically
remarked that he had not benefited himself by this observation.
The tendency to give less severe punishment, noticed in the closing trials at Salisbury, was more
marked at Dorchester. Nine men were let off on recognisances and ten were not proceeded against:
in the case of six of these ten the prosecutor, one Robert Bullen, who had been robbed of 4s. and
2s. 6d., refused to come forward. But enough sharp sentences were given to keep the labourers in
submission for the future. One man was transported for life and eleven for seven years: fifteen were
sentenced to various terms of imprisonment; seven were acquitted. It was not surprising that the
special correspondent of the Times complained that such meagre results scarcely justified the pomp
and expense of a Special Commission. In the neighbouring county of Gloucester, where the country
gentlemen carried out the work of retribution without help from headquarters, seven men were
transported for fourteen years, twenty for seven years, and twenty-five were sentenced to terms of
imprisonment ranging from six months to three years. All of these sentences were for breaking
threshing machines.
The disturbances in Berks and Bucks had been considered serious enough to demand a Special
Commission, and Sir James Alan Park, Sir William Bolland and Sir John Patteson were the judges
appointed. The first of the two Berkshire Commissions opened at Reading on 27th December. The
Earl of Abingdon, Lord-Lieutenant of the County, and Mr. Charles Dundas were the two local
commissioners. Mr. Dundas has figured already in these pages as chairman of the meeting at
Speenhamland. One hundred and thirty-eight prisoners were awaiting trial at Reading: they were
most of them young, only eighteen being forty or over. The rest, with few exceptions, varied from
seventeen to thirty-five in age, and must have lived all their lives under the Speenhamland system.
It is impossible to compare the accounts of the Special Commissions in Berks and Bucks with those
in Hampshire and Wiltshire without noticing a difference in the treatment of the rioters. The risings
had been almost simultaneous, the offences were of the same character, and the Commissions sat
at the same time. The difference was apparent from the first, and on 1st January the Times
published a leading article pleading for uniformity, and pointing out that the Berkshire Commission
was 'a merciful contrast' to that at Winchester. The cause is probably to be found in the dispositions
and characters of the authorities responsible in the two cases. The country gentlemen of Berkshire,
represented by a man like Mr. Dundas, were more humane than the country gentlemen of
Hampshire, represented by men like the duke of Wellington and the Barings; Mr. Gurney, the public
prosecutor at Reading, was more lenient than Sir Thomas Denman, and the Reading judges were
more kindly and considerate than the judges at Winchester. Further, there had been in Berkshire
little of the wild panic that swept over the country houses in Hampshire and Wiltshire. The judges at
Reading occasionally interjected questions on the prisoners, behalf, and in many cases they did not
conceal their satisfaction at an acquittal. Further, they had a more delicate sense for the proprieties.
Contrary to custom, they asked neither the Grand Jury nor the magistrates to dinner on the first day,
being anxious, we are told, to free the administration of justice 'from the slightest appearance of
partiality in the eyes of the lower classes.' The Lord Chancellor and Lord Melbourne had been
consulted and had approved.
It must not be supposed that Mr. Justice Park's theories of life and social relationships differed from
those of his brothers at Winchester. In his address to the Grand Jury he repudiated with indignation
the 'impudent and base slander... that the upper ranks of society care little for the wants and
privations of the poor. I deny this positively, upon a very extensive means of knowledge upon
subjects of this nature. But every man can deny it who looks about him and sees the vast institutions
in every part of the kingdom for the relief of the young and the old, the deaf and the lame, the blind,
the widow, the orphan -- and every child of wretchedness and woe. There is not a calamity or
distress incident to humanity, either of body or of mind, that is not humbly endeavoured to be
mitigated or relieved, by the powerful and the affluent, either of high or middling rank, in this our
happy land, which for its benevolence, charity, and boundless humanity, has been the admiration of
the world.' The theory that the rich kept the poor in a state of starvation and that this was the cause
of the disturbances, he declared later to be entirely disproved by the conduct of one of the mobs in
destroying a threshing machine belonging to William Mount, Esq., at Wasing, 'Mr. Mount having
given away £100 no longer ago than last winter to assist the lower orders during that inclement
season.'
A feature of the Reading Commission was the difficulty of finding jurymen. All farmers were
challenged on behalf of the prisoners, and matters were at a deadlock until the judges ordered the
bystanders to be impannelled.
The earlier cases were connected with the riots in Hungerford. Property in an iron foundry had been
destroyed, and fifteen men were found guilty on this capital charge. One of the fifteen was William
Oakley, who now paid the penalty for his £5 and strong language. But when the first cases were
over, Mr. Gurney began to drop the capital charge, and to content himself, as a rule, with convictions
for breaking threshing machines. One case revealed serious perjury on one side or the other.
Thomas Goodfellow and Cornelius Bennett were charged with breaking a threshing machine at
Matthew Batten's farm. The prisoners produced four witnesses, two labourers, a woman whose
husband was in prison for the riots, and John Gaiter, who described himself as 'not quite a master
bricklayer,' to prove that Matthew Batten had encouraged the riots. The first three witnesses
declared that Batten had asked the rioters to come and break his machine in order to serve out his
landlord and Mr. Ward, and had promised them victuals and £1. Batten and his son, on the other
hand, swore that these statements were false. The prisoners were found guilty, with a
recommendation to mercy which was disregarded. Goodfellow, who was found guilty of breaking
other machines as well, was sentenced to fourteen, and Cornelius Bennett to seven years'
transportation, The judge spoke of their scandalous attempt to blacken the character of a
respectable farmer: 'it pleased God however that the atrocious attempt had failed.' It would be
interesting to know what were the relations between Matthew Batten and his landlord.
On the last day of the trials Mr. Gurney announced that there would be no more prosecutions for
felony, as enough had been done in the way of making examples. Some interesting cases of riot
were tried. The most important riot had taken place as early as 19th November, and the hero of the
proceedings was the Rev. Edward Cove, the venerable Vicar of Brimpton, one of the many parson
magistrates. A mob had assembled in order to demand an increase of wages, and it was met by Mr.
Cove and his posse of special constables. On occasions like this, Mr. Gurney remarked, we become
sensible of the great advantages of our social order. Mr. Cove without more ado read the Riot Act;
the mob refused to disperse; his special constables thereupon attacked them, and a general mêlée
followed in which hard blows were given and taken. No one attempted to strike Mr. Cove himself,
but one of his companions received from a rioter, whom he identified, a blow rivalling that given to
Mr. Bingham Baring, which beat the crown of his hat in and drove the rim over his eyes: it was
followed by other and more serious blows on his head and body. The counsel for the defence tried
to show that it was distress that had caused the rioters to assemble, and he quoted a remark of the
Chairman of Quarter Sessions that the poor were starved almost into insurrection; but all evidence
about wages was rUled out. The court were deeply impressed by this riot, and Mr. Justice Park
announced that it had alarmed him and his fellow judges more 'than anything that had hitherto
transpired in these proceedings.' 'Had one life been lost,' he continued, 'the lives of every individual
of the mob would have been forfeited, and the law must have been carried into effect against those
convicted.' As it was, nobody was condemned to death for his share in the affray, though the more
violent, such as George Williams, alias 'Staffordshire Jack,' a 'desperate character,' received
heavier penalties for machine-breaking in consequence.
Three men were reserved for execution: William Oakley, who was told that as a carpenter he had no
business to mix himself up in these transactions; Alfred Darling, a blacksmith by trade, who had
been found guilty on several charges of demanding money; and Winterbourne, who had taken part
in the Hungerford affair in the magistrates' room, and had also acted as leader in some cases when
a mob asked for money. In one instance the mob had been content with £1 instead of the £2 for
which it had asked for breaking a threshing machine, Winterbourne remarking, 'we will take half
price because he has stood like a man.'
Public opinion in Berkshire was horrified at the prospect of taking life. Petitions for mercy poured in
from Reading, including one from ladies to the queen, from Newbury, from Hungerford, from
Henley, and from other places. Two country gentlemen, Mr. J. B. Monck and Mr. Wheble, made
every exertion to save the condemned men. They waited with petitions on Lord Melbourne, who
heard them patiently for an hour. They obtained a reprieve for Oakley and for Darling, who were
transported for life; Winterbourne they could not save: he was hung on 11th January, praying to the
last that his wife, who was dangerously ill of typhus, might die before she knew of his fate.
Fifty-six men were sentenced to transportation from Reading -- twenty-three for life, sixteen for
fourteen years, seventeen for seven years thirty-six were sent to prison for various terms.
The same commissioners went on to Abingdon where proceedings opened on 6th January. Here
there were only forty-seven prisoners, all but two of whom were agricultural labourers, most of them
very young. The cases resembled those tried at Reading, but it is clear that the evidence of Mrs.
Charlotte Slade, whose conduct we have already described, and her method of dealing with the
rioters, made a great impression on Mr. Justice Park and his colleagues, and opened their eyes to
the true perspective of the rhetorical language that had assumed such terrifying importance to other
judges. One young labourer, Richard Kempster by name, who was found guilty of breaking a
threshing machine, had carried a black-and-red flag in the mob, and when arrested had exclaimed,
'be damned if I don't wish it was a revolution, and that all was a fire together:' it is easy to imagine
the grave homily on the necessity of cutting such a man off for ever from his kind that these words
would have provoked from the judges at Winchester. Mr. Justice Park and his colleagues sentenced
Kempster to twelve months' imprisonment. At Abingdon only one man was sentenced to be
transported; Thomas Mackrell, an agricultural labourer of forty-three. Another, Henry Woolridge, had
sentence of death commuted to eighteen months' imprisonment. Thirty-five others were sent to
prison for various terms.
The same three judges proceeded to Aylesbury to try the Buckinghamshire rioters. The chief event
in this county had been the destruction of paper-making machinery at Wycombe. The Commission
opened on 11th January: the duke of Buckingham and Mr. Maurice Swabey were the local
commissioners. There were one hundred and thirty-six prisoners to be tried, almost all young and
illiterate: only eighteen were forty years of age or over. Forty-four men and boys were found guilty of
the capital charge of destroying paper machinery. Most of the other prisoners who were charged
with breaking threshing machines were allowed to plead guilty and let off on their own
recognisances, or else the charge was not pressed. An exception was made in a case in which
some members of a mob had been armed with guns. Three men who had carried guns were sent to
transportation for seven years, and thirteen others involved were sent to prison for two years or
eighteen months. Several men were tried for rioting, and those who had combined a demand for
increased wages with a request for the restoration of parish buns were sent to prison for six weeks.
One more trial is worth notice, because it suggests that even in Buckinghamshire, where the general
temper was more lenient, individuals who had made themselves obnoxious were Singled out for
special treatment. John Crook, a miller, was indicted with four others for riotously assembling and
breaking a winnowing machine at Mr. Fryer's at Long Crendon. As Crook was charged with a
misdemeanour his counsel could address the jury, and we learn from his speech that Crook had
been kept in prison since 2nd December, though £2000 had been offered in bail and many other
prisoners had been allowed out. The explanation, it was argued, was to be found in the fact that
Crook had come into some property which qualified him to hold a gun licence and to kill game. He
was sentenced to three months' imprisonment without hard labour, and to pay a fine of £10.
Thirty-two men in all were sent to prison for the agricultural disturbances in addition to the three
sentenced to transportation. Forty-two of those concerned in the breaking of papermaking
machinery received sentence of death, but their punishment was commuted to life transportation for
one, seven years' transportation for twenty-two, and imprisonment for various terms for the rest. Two
men were reserved for execution. One, Thomas Blizzard, was thirty years old, with a wife and three
children. His character was excellent. At the time of the riots he was a roundsman, receiving 1s. a
day from the overseer's and 1s. 6d. a week from a farmer. He told his employer at Little Marlow that
he would take a holiday to go machine-breaking, for he would endure imprisonment, or even
transportation, rather than see his wife and children cry for bread. John Sarney, the other, was fifty-
six years old and had a wife and six children: he kept a small beer-shop and his character was
irreproachable. Petitions on behalf of the two men were signed extensively, and the sentence was
commuted to transportation for life. The Aylesbury sentences seem lenient in comparison with those
given at Salisbury and Winchester, but they did not seem lenient to the people in the district. 'Pen
cannot describe,' wrote a Times correspondent, 'the heart-rending scene of despair, misery and
want, prevailing at Flackwell-Heath, the residence of the families of the major part of the misguided
men now incarcerated at Aylesbury.' The same correspondent tells of a benevolent Quaker, who
had become rich as a maker of paper, helping these families by stealth.
The work of the Special Commissions was now over. Melbourne had explained in Parliament that
they had been set up 'to expound the law' and to bring home to the ignorant the gravity of their
crimes against social order. In spite of the daily imposition of ferocious punishments on poachers
and thieves, the poor apparently did not know in what letters of blood the code against rioting and
discontent was composed. These three weeks had brought a lurid enlightenment into their dark
homes. In the riots, as we have seen, the only man who had been killed was a rioter, killed
according to the reports of the time by a yeomanry soldier, according to local tradition by a farmer,
and for that offence he had been refused Christian burial. On the other side, not a single person had
been killed or seriously wounded. For these riots, apart from the cases of arson, for which six men
or boys were hung, aristocratic justice exacted three lives, and the transportation of four hundred
and fifty-seven men and boys,(32*) in addition to the imprisonment of about four hundred at home.
The shadow of this vengeance still darkens the minds of old men and women in the villages of
Wiltshire, and eighty years have been too short a time to blot out its train of desolating memories.
(33*) Nobody who does not realise what Mr. Hudson has described with his intimate touch, the
effect on the imagination and the character of 'a life of simple unchanging action and of habits that
are like instincts, of hard labour in sun and rain and wind from day to day,' can ever understand what
the breaking of all the ties of life and home and memory meant to the exiles and to those from
whose companionship they were then torn for ever.
We have said that one feature of the rising was the firing of stacks and ricks and barns. This
practice was widespread, and fires broke out even in counties where the organised rising made little
progress. Associations for the detection of incendiaries were formed at an early stage, and immense
rewards were offered. Yet not a single case of arson was tried before the Special Commissions, and
the labourers kept their secret well. Many of the governing class in the early days persuaded
themselves that the labourers had no secret to keep, and that the fires were due to any one except
the labourers, and to any cause except distress. Perhaps the wish was father to the thought, for as
the Times observed, persons responsible for grinding the faces of their labourers preferred to think
the outrages the work of strangers. Sometimes it was smugglers, suffering from the depression in
their trade: sometimes it was foreigners: sometimes it was mysterious gentlemen in gigs, driving
furiously about the country, led by Captain Swing, scattering fireballs and devastation. These were
the fashionable theories in the House of Lords, although Richmond reminded his brother peers that
there had been a flood of petitions representing the sufferings of the labourers from the very
beginning of the year, and that the House of Lords had not thought it necessary to give them the
slightest attention. Lord Camden ascribed the outrages to the French spirit, and argued that the
country was enjoying 'what was undeniably a genial autumn.' The Duke of Wellington took the same
view, denying that the troubles were due to distress: the most influential cause of disturbances was
the example, 'and I will unhesitatingly say the bad and the mischievous example, afforded by the
neighbouring States.' Eldon remarked that many of the prisoners taken in the riots were foreigners,
a point on which Melbourne undeceived him. The speakers who regarded the disturbances in the
south of England as the overflow of the Paris Revolution had no positive evidence to produce, but
they had a piece of negative evidence which they thought conclusive. For if the labourers knew who
were the incendiaries, they would surely have given information. In some cases a reward of £1000
with a free pardon for all except the actual author was waiting to be claimed, 'and yet not one of the
miserable beings have availed themselves of the prospect of becoming rich.'
Some eleven cases of arson were tried at the Assizes in Essex, Kent, Sussex, and Surrey: all the
prisoners were agricultural labourers and most of them were boys. Eight were convicted, often on
very defective evidence, and six were executed. One of the eight, Thomas Goodman, a boy of
eighteen, saved his life by declaring in prison that the idea had been put into his head by a lecture of
Cobbett's. Two brothers of the name of Pakeman, nineteen and twenty years old, were convicted on
the evidence of Bishop, another lad of eighteen, who had prompted them to set fire to a barn, and
later turned king's evidence 'after a gentleman in the gaol had told him of the big reward.' This fire
seems to have been a piece of bravado, as no doubt many others were, for Bishop remarked, as the
three were sitting under a hedge after lighting the barn, 'who says we can't have a fire too, as well as
them at Blean?' The two boys, who had never been taught to read or write, scandalised the public
by displaying a painful indifference to the ministrations of the chaplain, and dying without receiving
the sacrament.(34*) A half-witted boy of fourteen, Richard Pennells, was tried at Lewes for setting
fire to his master's haystack for a promise of sixpence from a man who was not discovered. His
master, who prosecuted, remarked that he was 'dull of apprehension, but not so much as not to
know right from wrong.' The boy, who had no counsel, offered no defence, and stood sobbing in the
dock. The jury found him guilty, with a recommendation to mercy on account of his youth and
imperfect understanding. Sentence of death was recorded, but he was told that his life would be
spared.
These same Lewes Assizes, conducted by Mr. Justice Taunton, afforded a striking example of the
comparative treatment of different crimes. Thomas Brown, a lad of seventeen, was charged with
writing the following letter to Lord Sheffield, 'Please, my Lord, I dont wise to hurt you. This is the
case al the world over. If you dont get rid of your foreign steward and farmer and bailiff in a few days
time -- less than a month -- we will burn him up, and you along with him. My writing is bad, but my
firing is good my Lord.' Lord Sheffield gave evidence as to the receipt of the letter: the prisoner, who
had no counsel, was asked by the judge if he would like to put any questions, and he only replied
that he hoped that his lordship would forgive him. The judge answered that his lordship had not the
power, and sentenced Brown to transportation for life.(35*) Later on in the same Assizes, Captain
Winter, a man of sixty, captain of a coasting vessel, was tried for the murder of his wife, who had
been killed in a most brutal manner. He had been hacking and wounding her for four hours at night,
and she was last seen alive at half past two in the morning, naked and begging for mercy. Her body
was covered with wounds. The man's defence was that he came home drunk, that he found his wife
drunk, and that he had no knowledge of what followed. To the general surprise Captain Winter
escaped with a verdict of manslaughter. 'The prisoner,' wrote the Times correspondent, 'is indebted
for his life to the very merciful way in which Mr. Justice Taunton appeared to view the case, and the
hint which he threw out to the jury, that the parties might have had a quarrel, in which case her
death by the prisoner would amount to manslaughter only.'
When the disturbances began, the duke of Wellington was Prime Minister, and Sir Robert Peel
Home Secretary. But in November 1830 Wellington, who had made a last effort to rally the old
Tories, sulking over his surrender on Catholic Emancipation, by some sudden thunder against
Reform, had been beaten on the Civil List and resigned. Reform was inevitable, and with Reform
the Whigs. Thus, towards the close of the year of the Revolution that drove Charles X from France,
Lord Grey became Prime Minister, to carry the measure which as Charles Grey, lieutenant of
Charles Fox, he had proposed in the House of Commons in 1793, a few months after Louis XVI had
lost his head in the Revolution which had maddened and terrified the English aristocracy. Fortune
had been sparing in her favours to this cold, proud, honourable and courageous man. She had shut
him out from power for twenty-three years, waiting to make him Prime Minister until he was verging
on seventy, and all the dash and ardour of youth had been chilled by disappointment and delay. But
she had reserved her extreme of malice to the end, for it was her chief unkindness that having
waited so long she did not wait a little longer. Grey, who had been forty-four years in public life, and
forty-three in opposition, took office at the moment that the rising passed into Sampshire and
Wiltshire, and thus his first act as Prime Minister was to summon his colleagues to a Cabinet
meeting to discuss, not their plans for Parliamentary Reform, but the measures to be taken in this
alarming emergency. After a lifetime of noble protest against war, intolerance, and repression, he
found himself in the toils and snares of the consequences of a policy in which war, intolerance, and
repression had been constant and conspicuous features. And those consequences were especially
to be dreaded by such a man at such a time.
Grey became Prime Minister to carry Reform, and Reform was still enveloped to many minds in the
wild fancies and terrors of a Jacobin past. To those who knew, conscious as they were of their own
modest purposes and limited aim, that their accession to power boded to many violence, confusion,
and the breaking up of the old ways and life of the State, it was maddening that these undiscerning
peasants should choose this moment of all others for noise and riot. The struggle for Reform was
certain to lead to strife, and it was hard that before they entered upon it England should already be
in tumult from other causes. Moreover, Grey had to reckon with William IV. So long as he could
remember, the Court had been the refuge of all that was base in English politics, and it was a
question whether Liberal ideas had suffered more from the narrow and darkened mind of George III
or the mean and incorrigible perfidy of George IV. In comparison with his father, the new king had
the wisdom of a Bentham or an Adam Smith; in comparison with his brother, he had the generous
and loyal heart of a Philip Sidney or a Falkland. But seen in any less flattering mirror, he was a very
ordinary mortal, and Grey had known this jolly, drinking, sailor prince too long and too well to trust
either his intellect or his character, under too fierce or too continuous a strain. These riots tried him
severely. No sooner was William on his throne than the labourers came out of their dens, looking
like those sansculottes whose shadows were never far from the imagination of the English upper
classes. The king's support of Reform was no violent enthusiasm, and the slightest threat of
disorder might disturb the uneasy equilibrium of his likes and fears. In the long run it depended on
the will of this genial mediocrity-so strangely had Providence mixed caprice and design in this world
of politics -- whether or not Reform should be carried, and carried without bloodshed. Throughout
these months then, the king, always at Melbourne's elbow, trying to tempt and push the Government
into more drastic measures, was a very formidable enemy to the cause of moderation and of justice.
These influences were strong, and there was little to counteract them. For there was nobody in the
world which Grey and Melbourne alike inhabited who could enter into the minds of the labourers.
This is readily seen, if we glance at two men who were regarded as extreme Radicals in the House
of Commons, Hobhouse and Burdett. Each of these men had served the cause of Reform in prison
as well as in Parliament, and each with rather ridiculous associations; Hobhouse's imprisonment
being connected with the ballad inspired by the malicious and disloyal wit of his friend and hero,
Byron, and Burdett's with the ludicrous scene of his arrest, with his boy spelling out Magna Charta
on his knee. It is difficult for those who have read Hobhouse's diaries to divine what play of reason
and feeling ever made him a Radical, but a Radical he was, an indefatigable critic of the old régime,
and in particular of such abuses as flogging in the army. Burdett was a leader in the same causes.
To these men, if to any, the conduct of the labourers might have seemed to call for sympathy rather
than for violence. But if we turn to Hobhouse's diary we see that he was never betrayed into a
solitary expression of pity or concern for the scenes we have described, and as for Burdett, he was
all for dragooning the discontented counties and placing them under martial law. And even Radnor,
who as a friend of Cobbett was much less academic in his Radicalism, sat on the Wiltshire
Commission without making any protest that has reached posterity.
All the circumstances then made it easy for Grey and his colleagues to slip into a policy of violence
and repression. They breathed an atmosphere of panic, and they dreaded the recoil of that panic on
their own schemes. Yet when all allowance is made for this insidious climate, when we remember
that no man is so dangerous as the kind man haunted by the fear of seeming weak, at a moment
when he thinks his power of doing good depends on his character for strength; when we remember,
too, the tone of Society caught between scare and excitement, the bad inspiration of the Court, the
malevolent influence of an alarmed Opposition, the absorbing interest of making a ministry, the
game apart from the business of politics, it is still difficult to understand how men like Grey and
Holland and Durham could ever have lent themselves to the cruelties of this savage retribution.
When first there were rumours of the intention of the Government to put down the riots with severe
measures, Cobbett wrote a passage in which he reviewed the characters of the chief ministers,
Grey with his 'humane disposition,' Holland 'who never gave his consent to an act of cruelty,' Althorp
'who has never dipped his hand in blood,' Brougham 'who with all his half Scotch crotchets has at
any rate no blood about him,' to show that the new ministers, unlike many of their Tory
predecessors, might be trusted to be lenient and merciful. Two of these men, Grey and Holland, had
made a noble stand against all the persecutions of which Tory Governments had been guilty,
defending with passion men whose opinions they regarded with horror; if any record could justify
confidence it was theirs. Unfortunately the politician who was made Home Secretary did not share in
this past. The common talk at the time of Melbourne's appointment was that he was too lazy for his
office; the real criticism should have been that he had taken the side of Castlereagh and Sidmouth
in 1817. As Home Secretary he stopped short of the infamous measures he had then approved; he
refused to employ spies, and the Habeas Corpus was not suspended. But nobody can follow the
history of this rising, and the history of the class that made it, without recognising that the
punishment which exiled these four hundred and fifty labourers is a stain, and an indelible stain, on
the reputation of the Government that lives in history on the fame of the Reform Bill. It is difficult to
believe that either Fox or Sheridan could have been parties to it. The chief shame attaches to
Melbourne, who let the judges do their worst, and to Lansdowne, who sat beside the judges on the
Salisbury bench, but the fact that the Prime Minister was immersed in the preparation of a reform,
believed by his contemporaries to be a revolution, does not relieve him of his share of the odium,
which is the due of Governments that are cruel to the weak, and careless of justice to the poor.
One effort was made, apart from the intercession of public opinion, to induce the Government to
relax its rigours. When the panic had abated and the last echo of the riots had been stilled by this
summary retribution, a motion was proposed in the House of Commons for a general amnesty.
Unhappily the cause of the labourers was in the hands of Henry Hunt, a man whose wisdom was
not equal to his courage, and whose egregious vanity demoralised and spoilt his natural eloquence.
If those who were in close sympathy with his general aims could not tolerate his manners, it is not
surprising that his advocacy was a doubtful recommendation in the unsympathetic atmosphere of
the House of Commons. He was a man of passionate sincerity, and had already been twice in
prison for his opinions, but the ruling class thinking itself on the brink of a social catastrophe, while
very conscious of Hunt's defects, was in no mood to take a detached view of this virtue. The debate,
which took place on the 8th of February 1831, reflects little credit on the House of Commons, and
the division still less, for Hume was Hunt's only supporter. The chief speakers against the motion
were Benett of Wiltshire, George Lamb, brother of Melbourne and Under-Secretary at the Home
Office, and Denman, the Attorney-General. Lamb amused himself and the House with jests on the
illiterate letter for writing which the boy Looker was then on the high seas, and Denman threw out a
suggestion that Looker's father had had a share in the boy's guilt. Denman closed his speech by
pouring scorn on those who talked sentimentality, and declaring that he would ever look back with
pride on his part in the scenes of this memorable winter.
So far the Government had had it all their own way. But in their anxiety to show a resolute front and
to reassure those who had suspected that a reform Government would encourage social disorder by
weakness, Lord Grey and his colleagues were drawn into a scrape in which they burnt their fingers
rather badly. They decided to prosecute two writers for inciting the labourers to rebel. The two
writers were Richard Carlile and William Cobbett. Carlile was the natural prey for a Government in
search of a victim. He had already spent six or seven years of his lion-hearted life in prison for
publishing the writings of Paine and Hone: his wife, his sister, and his shopman had all paid a
similar penalty for their association, voluntary or involuntary, with his public-spirited adventures. The
document for which he stood in the dock at the Old Bailey early in January l831 was an address to
the agricultural labourers, praising them for what they had done, and reviewing their misfortunes in
this sentence: 'The more tame you have grown, the more you have been oppressed and despised,
the more you have been trampled on.' Carlile defended himself in a speech that lasted four hours
and a half. The jury disagreed, but after several hours they united on a verdict of acquittal on the
charge of bringing the Crown into contempt, and of guilty on the charge of addressing inflammatory
language to the labouring classes. He was sentenced to imprisonment for two years, to pay a fine,
and to find sureties.
Cobbett's trial was a more important event, for whereas Carlile was the Don Quixote of liberty of
mind, Cobbett was a great political force, and his acquittal would give a very serious shock to the
prestige of the Government that attacked him. The attention of the authorities had been called to
Cobbett's speeches very early in the history of the riots, and the Home Office Papers show that
appeals to the Government to prosecute Cobbett were the most common of all the
recommendations and requests that poured into Whitehall from the country. Some of these letters
were addressed to Sir Robert Peel, and one of them is endorsed with the draft of a reply: 'My dear
Sir, -- If you can give me the name of the person who heard Cobbett make use of the expression to
which you refer you would probably enable me to render no small public service by the prosecution
of Cobbett for sedition. -- Very faithfully Yours, Robert Peel.'
In an evil moment for themselves, Peel's successors decided to take action, not indeed on his
speeches, but on his articles in the Political Register. The character of those articles might perhaps
be described as militant and uncompromising truth. They were inflammatory, because the truth was
inflammatory. Nobody who knew the condition of the labourers could have found in them a single
misstatement or exaggeration. The only question was whether it was in the public interest to publish
them in a time of disturbance. From this point of view the position of the Government was seriously
weakened by the fact that the Times had used language on this very subject which was not one whit
less calculated to excite indignation against the rich, and the Times, though it was the organ of
wealthy men, was in point of fact considerably cheaper to buy than the Register, the price of which
Cobbett had raised to a shilling in the autumn of 1830. But this was not the only reason why the
Government was in danger of exposing itself to a charge of malice in choosing Cobbett for a
prosecution. The unrest in the southern counties had been due to a special set of economic causes,
but there was unrest due to other causes in other parts of England. It was not the misery of
ploughboys and labourers in Hampshire and Kent that had made Wellington and Peel decide that it
was unsafe for the King to dine at the Guildhall in the winter of 1830: the Political Unions, which
struck such terror into the Court and the politicians, were not bred in the villages. There was a
general and acute discontent with extravagant government, with swollen lists and the burden of
sinecures, with the whole system of the control of the boroughs and its mockery of representation.
Now in such a state of opinion every paper on the side of reform might be charged with spreading
unrest. Statistics of sinecures, and pensions, and the fat revenues of bishopricks, were scattered all
over England, and the facts published in every such sheet were like sparks thrown about near a
powder magazine. The private citizens who wrote to the Home Office in the winter of 1830
mentioned these papers almost as often as they mentioned Cobbett's lectures. Many of these
papers were based on a pamphlet written by Sir James Graham, First Lord of the Admiralty in the
very Government that prosecuted Cobbett. One of the Barings complained in the House of
Commons in December 1830, that the official papers on offices and sinecures which the Reform
Government had itself presented to Parliament to satisfy public opinion of its sincerity in the cause
of retrenchment were the cause of mischief and danger. At such a time no writer, who wished to
help the cause of reform, could measure the effects of every sentence so nicely as to escape the
charge of exciting passion, and the Government was guilty of an extraordinary piece of folly in
attacking Cobbett for conduct of which their own chief supporters were guilty every time they put a
pen to paper.
The trial took place in July 1831 at the Guildhall. It was the great triumph of Cobbett's life, as his
earlier trial had been his great humiliation. There was very little of the lion in the Cobbett who
faltered before Vicary Gibbs in l810; there was very little of the lamb in the Cobbett who towered
before Denman in 1831. And the court that witnessed his triumph presented a strange scene. The
trial had excited intense interest, and Cobbett said that every county in England was represented in
the company that broke, from time to time, into storms of cheering. The judge was Tenterden, the
Chief Justice, who, as a bitter enemy of reform, hated alike accusers and accused. Six members of
the Cabinet, the Prime Minister himself and the Lord Chancellor, Melbourne and Durham,
Palmerston and Goderich listened, from no choice of their own, to the scathing speech in which
Cobbett renewed their conduct. Benett of Pyt House was there, a spectre of vengeance from one
Commission, and the father of the boy Cook of Micheldever, a shadow of death from another. All the
memories of those terrible weeks seemed to gather together in the suspense of that eager crowd
watching this momentous encounter.
Denman, who prosecuted, employed a very different tone towards Cobbett from the tone that
Perceval had used at the first of Cobbett's trials. Perceval, when prosecuting Cobbett for some
articles on Ireland in the Register in 1803, asked the jury with the patrician insolence of a class that
held all the prizes of life, 'Gentlemen, who is Mr. Cobbett? Is he a man writing purely from motives of
patriotism? Quis homo hic est? Quo patre natus?' No counsel prosecuting Cobbett could open with
this kind of rhetoric in 1831: Denman preferred to describe him as 'one of the greatest masters of
the English language.' Denman's speech was brief, and it was confined mainly to a paraphrase of
certain of Cobbett's articles and to comments upon their effect. It was no difficult task to pick out
passages which set the riots in a very favourable light, and emphasised the undoubted fact that they
had brought some improvement in the social conditions, and that nothing else had moved the heart
or the fears of the ruling class. But the speech was not long over before it became evident that
Cobbett, like another great political defendant, though beginning as the accused, was to end as the
accuser. His reply to the charge of exciting the labourers to violence was immediate and
annihilating. In December 1830, after the publication of the article for which he was now being tried,
Brougham, as President of the Society for the diffusion of Useful Knowledge, had asked and
obtained Cobbett's leave to reprint his earlier 'Letter to the Luddites,' as the most likely means of
turning the labourers from rioting and the breaking of machines. There stood the Lord Chancellor in
the witness-box, in answer to Cobbett's subpoena, to admit that crushing fact. This was a
thunderclap to Denman, who was quite ignorant of what Brougham had done, and, as we learn from
Greville, he knew at once that his case was hopeless. Cobbett passed rapidly from defence to
attack. Grey, Melbourne, Palmerston, Durham, and Goderich had all been subpoena'd in order to
answer some very awkward questions as to the circumstances under which Thomas Goodman had
been pardoned. The Lord Chief Justice refused to allow the questions to be put, but at least these
great Ministers had to listen as Cobbett told the story of those strange transactions, including a visit
from a parson and magistrates to a 'man with a rope round his neck,' which resulted in Goodman's
unexplained pardon and the publication of a statement purporting to come from him ascribing his
conduct to the incitement at Cobbett's 'lacture.' Cobbett destroyed any effect that Goodman's charge
might have had by producing a declaration signed by one hundred and three persons present at the
lecture -- farmers. tradesmen, labourers, carpenters, and shoemakers -- denying that Cobbett had
made the statement ascribed to him in Goodman's confession, one of the signatories being the
farmer whose barn Goodman had burnt. He then proceeded to contrast the treatment Goodman had
received with the treatment received by others convicted of incendiarism, and piecing together all
the evidence of the machinations of the magistrates, constructed a very formidable indictment to
which Denman could only reply that he knew nothing of the matter, and that Cobbett was capable of
entertaining the most absurd suspicions. On another question Denman found himself thrown on the
defensive, for he was now confronted with his own misstatements in Parliament about Cook, and
the affidavits of Cook's father present in court. Denman could only answer that till that day no one
had contradicted him, though he could scarcely have been unaware that the House of Commons
was not the place in which a Minister's statement about the age, occupation, pay, and conduct of an
obscure boy was most likely to be challenged. Denman made a chastened reply, and the jury, after
spending the night at the Guildhall, disagreed, six voting each way. Cobbett was a free man, for the
Whigs, overwhelmed by the invective they had foolishly provoked, remembered, when too late, the
wise saying of Maurice of Saxony about Charles V: 'I have no cage big enough for such a bird,' and
resisted all the King's invitations to repeat their rash adventure. To those who have made their
melancholy way through the trials at Winchester and Salisbury, at which rude boys from the
Hampshire villages and the Wiltshire downs, about to be tossed across the sea, stood shelterless in
the unpitying storm of question and insinuation and abuse, there is a certain grim satisfaction in
reading this last chapter and watching Denman face to face, not with the broken excuses and
appeals of ignorant and helpless peasants, but with a volleyed thunder that swept into space all his
lawyer's artifice and skill. Justice plays strange tricks upon mankind, but who will say that she has
not her inspirations?
One more incident has to be recorded in the tale of suppression. The riots were over, but the fires
continued. In the autumn of 1831 Melbourne, in a shameful moment, proposed a remedy borrowed
from the evil practices which a Tory Parliament had consented at last to forbid. The setting of spring
guns and man-traps, the common device of game preservers, had been made a misdemeanour in
1826 by an Act of which Suffield was the author. Melbourne now proposed to allow persons who
obtained a license from two magistrates to protect their property by these means. The Bill passed
the House of Lords, and the Journals record that it was introduced in the House of Commons, but
there, let us hope from very horror at the thought of this moral relapse, silently it disappears.
When Grey met Parliament as Prime Minister he said that the Government recognised two duties:
the duty of finding a remedy for the distress of the labourers, and the duty of repressing the riots
with severity and firmness. We have seen how the riots were suppressed; we have now to see what
was done towards providing a remedy. This side of the picture is scarcely less melancholy than the
other; for when we turn to the debates in Parliament we see clearly how hopeless it was to expect
any solution of an economic problem from the legislators of the time. Now, if ever, circumstances
had forced the problem on the mind of Parliament, and in such an emergency as this men might be
trusted to say seriously and sincerely what they had to suggest. Yet the debates are a mêlée of futile
generalisations, overshadowed by the doctrine which Grey himself laid down that 'all matters
respecting the amount of rent and the extent of farms would be much better regulated by the
individuals who were immediately interested than by any Committee of their Lordships.' One peer
got into trouble for blurting out the truth that the riots had raised wages; another would curse
machinery as vigorously as any labourer; many blamed the past inattention of the House of Lords to
the labourers' misery; and one considered the first necessity of the moment was the impeachment
of Wellington. Two men had actual and serious proposals to make. They were Lord King and Lord
Suffield.
Both of these men are striking figures. King (1776-1833) was an economist who had startled the
Government in 1811 by calling for the payments of his rents in the lawful coin of the realm. This
dramatic manoeuvre for discrediting paper money had been thwarted by Lord Stanhope, who,
though in agreement with King on many subjects, strongly approved of paper money in England as
he had approved of assignats in France. Lord Holland tells a story of how he twitted Stanhope with
wanting to see history repeat itself, and how Stanhope answered with a chuckle: 'And if they take
property from the drones and give it to the bees, where, my dear Citoyen, is the great harm of that?'
King was always in a small minority and his signature was given, together with those of Albemarle,
Thanet, and Holland, to the protest against establishing marital law in Ireland in 1801, which was
written with such wounding directness that it was afterwards blackened out of the records of the
House of Lords, on the motion of the infamous Lord Clare. But he was never in a smaller minority
than he was on this occasion when he told his fellow landlords that the only remedy for the public
distress was the abolition of the Corn Laws. Such a proposal stood no chance in the House of Lords
or n the House of Commons. Grey declared that the abolition of the Corn Laws would lead to the
destruction of the country, and though there were Free Traders among the Whigs, even nine years
after this Melbourne described such a policy as 'the wildest and maddest scheme that has ever
entered into the imagination of man to conceive.' Suffield (1781-1835), the only other politician with
a remedy, is an interesting and attractive character. Originally a Tory, and the son of Sir Harbord
Harbord, who was not a man of very tender sensbilities, Suffield gradually felt his way towards
Liberalism. He was too large-minded a man to be happy and at ease in an atmosphere where the
ruling class flew instinctively in every crisis to measures of tyranny and repression. Peterloo
completed his conversion. From that time he became a champion of the poor, a fierce critic of the
Game Laws, and a strong advocate of prison reform. He is revealed in his diary and all the traditions
of his life as a man of independence and great sincerity. Suffield's policy in this crisis was the policy
of home colonisation, and its fate can best be described by means of extracts from a memoir
prepared by R. M. Bacon, a Norwich journalist and publicist of importance, and printed privately in
1838, three years after Suffield had been killed by a fall from his horse. They give a far more
intimate and graphic picture of the mind of the Government than the best reported debates in the
records of Parliament.
We have seen in a previous chapter that there had been at this time a revival of the movement for
restoring the land to the labourers. One of the chief supporters of this policy was R. M. Bacon, who,
as editor of the Norwich Mercury, was in close touch with Suffield. Bacon set out an elaborate
scheme of home colonisation, resembling in its main ideas the plan sketched by Arthur Young thirty
years earlier, and this scheme Suffield took up with great enthusiasm. Its chief recommendation in
his eyes was that it applied public money to establishing labourers with a property of their own, so
that whereas, under the existing system, public money was used, in the form of subsidies from the
rates, to depress wages, public money would be used under this scheme to raise them. For it was
the object of the plan to make the labourers independent of the farmers, and to substitute the
competition of employers for the competition of employed. No other scheme, Suffield used to
maintain, promised any real relief. If rents and taxes were reduced the farmer would be able, but
would not be compelled, to give better wages: if taxes on the labourers' necessaries were reduced,
the labourers would be able to live on a smaller wage, and as long as they were scrambling for
employment they were certain to be ground down to the minimum of subsistence. The only way to
rescue them from this plight was to place them again in such a position that they were not absolutely
dependent on the farmers. This the government could do by purchasing land, at present waste, and
compelling parishes, with the help of a public loan, to set up labourers upon it, and to build cottages
with a fixed allotment of land.
Suffield's efforts to persuade the government to take up this constructive policy began as soon as
Grey came into office. His first letters to Bacon on the subject are written in November. The
opposition, he says, is very strong, and Sturges Bourne and Lansdowne are both hostile. On 17th
November he writes that a peer had told him that he had sat on an earlier committee on this subject
with Sturges Bourne, as chairman, and that 'those who understood the subject best agreed with
Malthus that vice and misery alone could cure the evil.' On 19th November he writes that he has had
a conference with Brougham, with about the same success as his conference with Lansdowne and
Sturges Bourne. On the 23rd he writes that he has been promised an interview at the Home Office;
on the 25th 'no invitation from Lord Melbourne -- the truth is he cannot find one moment of leisure.
The Home Office is distracted by the numerous representations of imminent danger to property, if
not to life, and applications for protection.' Later in the same day he writes that he has seen both
Grey and Melbourne: 'I at once attacked Grey. I found him disposed to give every possible
consideration to the matter. He himself has in Northumberland seen upon his own property the
beneficent effects of my plan, namely of apportioning land to cottagers, but he foresaw innumerable
difficulties.' A House of Lords Committee had been appointed on the Poor Laws at the instance of
Lord Salisbury, and Suffield hoped to persuade this committee to report in favour of his scheme. He
therefore pressed Grey to make a public statement of sympathy. Grey said 'he would intimate that
Government would be disposed to carry into effect any measure of relief recommended by the
Committee; very pressed but would call Cabinet together to-morrow.' The interview with Melbourne
was very different. 'Next I saw Lord Melbourne. "Oppressed as you are," said I, "I am willing to
relieve you from a conference, but you must say something on Monday next and I fear you have not
devoted much attention to the subject." "I understand it perfectly," he replied, "and that is the reason
for my saying nothing about it." "How is this to be explained?" "Because I consider it hopeless." "Oh,
you think with Malthus that vice and misery are the only cure?" "No," said Lord Melbourne, "but the
evil is in numbers and the sort of competition that ensues." "Well then I have measures to propose
which may meet this difficulty." "Of these," said Lord Melbourne, "I know nothing," and he turned
away from me to a friend to enquire respecting outrages.' Suffield concludes on a melancholy note:
'The fact is, with the exception of a few individuals, the subject is deemed by the world a bore: every
one who touches on it is a bore, and nothing but the strongest conviction of its importance to the
country would induce me to subject myself to the indifference that I daily experience when I venture
to intrude the matter on the attention of legislators.'
A fortnight later Suffield was very sanguine: 'Most satisfactory interview with Melbourne: thinks Lord
Grey will do the job in the recess.' But the sky soon darkens again, and on the 27th Suffield writes
strongly to Melbourne on the necessity of action, and he adds: 'Tranquillity being now restored, all
the farmers are of course reducing their wages to that miserable rate that led to the recent
disturbances.' Unhappily the last sentence had a significance which perhaps escaped Suffield.
Believing as he did in his scheme, he thought that its necessity was proved by the relapse of wages
on the restoration of tranquillity, but vice and misery-ridden politicians might regard the restoration of
tranquillity as an argument for dropping the scheme. After this the first hopes fade away. There is
strong opposition on the Select Committee to Suffield's views, and he is disappointed of the prompt
report in favour of action which he had expected from it. The Government are indisposed to take
action, and Suffield, growing sick and impatient of their slow clock, warns Melbourne in June that he
cannot defend them. Melbourne replies that such a measure could not be maturely considered or
passed during the agitation over the Reform Bill. Later in the month there was a meeting between
Suffield and Melbourne, of which unfortunately no record is preserved in the Memoir, with the result
that Suffield declared in Parliament that the Government had a plan. In the autumn of 1831 an Act
was placed on the Statute Book which was the merest mockery of all Suffield's hopes, empowering
churchwardens or overseers to hire or lease, and under certain conditions to enclose, land up to a
limit of fifty acres, for the employment of the poor. It is difficult to resist the belief that if the riots had
lasted longer they might have forced the Government to accept the scheme, in the efficacy of which
it had no faith, as the price of peace, and that the change in temperature recorded in Suffield's Diary
after the middle of December mark the restoration of confidence at Whitehall.
So perished the last hope of reform and reparation for the poor. The labourers' revolt was ended;
and four hundred and fifty men had spent their freedom in vain. Of these exiles we have one final
glimpse; it is in a letter from the Governor of Van Diemen's Land to Lord Goderich: 'If, my Lord, the
evidence, or conduct, of particular individuals, can be relied on as proof of the efficiency or non-
efficiency of transportation, I am sure that a strong case indeed could, be made out in its favour. I
might instance the rioters who arrived by the Eliza, several of whom died almost immediately from
disease, induced apparently by despair. A great many of them went about dejected and stupefied
with care and grief, and their situation after assignment was not for a long time much less
unhappy.'(36*)
NOTES:
1. Russell, On Crimes and Misdemeanours, p. 371.
2. Sir J.B. Bosanquet (1773-1847).
3. Times, December 15, 1830.
4. Sir W.E. Taunton (1773-1835).
5. The Times on December 25 quoted part of this charge is a leading article with some sharp
strictures.
6. Sir John Vaughan (1769-1839).
7. Times, December 21, 1830.
8. Sir James Parke (1782-1868).
9. Times, January 3, 1831.
10. Sir E.H. Alderson (1787-1857).
11. Times, January 6, 1831. Cf. letter of Mr R. Pollen, J.P., afterwards on of Winchester
Commissioners, to Home Office, November 26: 'It may be worth considering the law, which exempts
all Threshing Machines from capital punishment, should much scenes as these occur again
amongst the agricultural classes. I confess I view with great regret that they have found the mode of
combining, which I had hoped was confined to the manufacturing classes.'
12. Sir J.A. Park (1763-1838)
13. Times, January 15, 1831.
14. Ibid., January 12, 1831.
15. Ibid.
16. February 8, 1831.
17. There are no statistics for Wilts, Hants, Bucks, and Dorshetshire prisoners. At Reading out of
138 prisoners 37 could read, and 25 of the 37 could also write. At Abingdon, out of 47, 17 could
read, and 6 of them could also write. In Wilts and Hants the proportion was probably smaller, as the
people were more neglected.
18. Times, December 24, 1830.
19. Ibid., January 8, 1831.
20. Times, January 7, 1831.
21. Ibid., December 24, 1930. Henry Bunce was transported for life to New South Wales.
22. Ibid., January 14.
23. Cobbett, Political Register, vol. lxxiii, p. 535, and local papers.
24. Fusell's sentence was commuted to imprisonment. Boys was sent to Van Diemen's Land.
25. H.O. Papers, Municipal and Provincial. Hants. 1831, March 24.
26. As early as November 26, Mr Richard Pollen, Chairman of Quarter Sessions and afterwards a
commissioner at Winchester, had written to the Home Office. 'I have directed the Magistrates'
attention very much to the class of People found in the Mobs many miles from their own homes,
Taylors, Shoemakers etc., who have been found always very eloquent, they are universally
politicians: they should be, I think, selected.' -- H.O. Papers.
27. For a full account of the incident, including the text of the petition and list of signatures, see
Cobbett's Two-penny Trash, July 1, 1832.
28. February 8, 1831.
29. Times, January 8, 1831. The Times of the same day contains an interesting petition from the
Birmingham Political Union on behalf of all the prisoners tried before the Special Commissions.
30. The scene is still vividly remembered by an old woman over ninety years of age with whom Mr
Hudson spoke.
31. H.O. Papers, Disturbance Entry-Book, Letter of January 3, 1831.
32. Three boats carried the convicts, the Eliza and the Proteus to Van Diemen's Land, the Eleanor
to New South Wales. The list of the prisoners on board shows that they came from the following
countries: --
Berks, 44
Bucks, 29
Dorset, 13
Essex, 23
Gloucester, 23
Hampshire, 100
Hunts, 5
Kent, 22
Norfolk, 11
Oxford, 11
Suffolk, 7
Sussex, 17
Wilts, 151
Total 457
If this represents the total, some sentences of transportation must have ben commuted for
imprisonment; possibly some rioters were sent later, for Mr Potter MacQueen, in giving evidence
before the Committee on Secondary Punishments, spoke of the six hundred able-bodied men who
had been transported to consequence of being concerned in the Swing offences. -- Report of
Committee, p. 95. Four years later Lord John Russell, as Home Secretary, pardoned 264 of the
convicts, in 1836 he pardoned 86 more, and in 1837 the survivors, mostly men sentenced for life or
for fourteen years, were given pardons conditional on their 'continuing to reside in Australia for the
remainder of their sentences.' No free passages back were granted, and Mr Hudson states that very
few, not more than one in five or six, ever returned. -- A Shepherd's Life, p. 247.
33. See Hudson, Ibid.
34. See Annual Register and local Papers.
35. He was sent to Van Diemen's Land. It is only fair to Lord Sheffield to say that he applied in vain
to Lord Melbourne for a mitigation of the life sentence. See Criminal Entry-Book, H.O. Papers.
36. Correspondence on Secondary Punishment, March, 1834, p. 25.
Chapter XII
Conclusion
A row of eighteenth-century houses, or a room of normal eighteenth-century furniture, or a
characteristic piece of eighteenth-century literature, conveys at once a sense of satisfaction and
completeness. The secret of this charm is not to be found in any special beauty or nobility of design
or expression, but simply in an exquisite fitness. The eighteenth-century mind was a unity, an order;
it was finished, and it was simple. All literature and art that really belong to the eighteenth century
are the language of a little society of men and women who moved within one set of ideas; who
understood each other; who were not tormented by any anxious or bewildering problems; who lived
in comfort, and, above all things, in composure. The classics were their freemasonry. There was a
standard for the mind, for the emotions, for the taste: there were no incongruities. When you have a
society like this, you have what we roughly call a civilisation, and it leaves its character and canons
in all its surroundings and its literature. Its definite ideas lend themselves readily to expression. A
larger society seems an anarchy in contrast; just because of its escape into a greater world it seems
powerless to stamp itself on wood or stone; it is condemned as an age of chaos and mutiny, with
nothing to declare. In comparison with the dishevelled century that follows, the eighteenth century
was neat, well dressed and nicely appointed. It had a religion, the religion of quiet common sense
and contentment with a world that it found agreeable and encouraging; it had a style, the style of the
elegant and polished English of Addison or Gibbon. Men who were not conscious of any strain or
great emotion asked of their writers and their painters that they should observe in their art the
equanimity and moderation that were desirable in life. They did not torture their minds with eager
questions; there was no piercing curiosity or passionate love or hatred in their souls; they all
breathed the same air of distinguished satisfaction and dignified self-control. English institutions
suited them admirably; a monarchy so reasonable nobody could mind; Parliament was a convenient
instrument for their wishes, and the English Church was the very thing to keep religion in its place.
What this atmosphere could produce at its best was seen in Gibbon or in Reynolds; and neither
Gibbon nor Reynolds could lose themselves in a transport of the imagination. To pass from the
eighteenth century to the Revolt, from Pope to Blake, or from Sheridan to Shelley, is to burst from
this little hothouse of sheltered and nurtured elegance into an infinite wild garden of romance and
mystery. For the eighteenth century such escape was impossible, and if any one fell into the fatal
crime of enthusiasm, his frenzy took the form of Methodism, which was a more limited world than
the world he had quitted.
The small class that enjoyed the monopoly of political power and social luxuries, round whose
interests and pleasures the State revolved, consisted, down to the French war, of persons
accustomed to travel, to find amusement and instruction in foreign galleries and French salons, and
to study the fashions and changes of thought, and letters and religion, outside England; of persons
who liked to surround themselves with the refinements and the decorations of life, and to display
their good taste in collecting old masters, or fine fragments of sculpture, or the scattered treasures
of an ancient library. Perhaps at no time since the days when Isabella d'Este consoled herself for
the calamities of her friends and relatives with the thought of the little Greek statues that were
brought by these calamities into the market, has there been a class so keenly interested in the
acquisition of beautiful workmanship, for the sake of the acquisition rather than for the sake of the
renown of acquiring it. The eighteenth-century collectors bought with discernment as well as with
liberality: they were not the slaves of a single rage or passion, and consequently they enriched the
mansions of England with the achievements of various schools. Of course the eighteenth century
had its own fashion in art, and no admiration is more unintelligible to modern taste than the
admiration for Guercino and Guido Reni and the other seventeenth-century painters of Bologna. But
the pictures that came across the Channel in such great numbers were not the products of one
school, or indeed the products of one country. Dutch, Flemish, French, Italian, they all streamed into
England, and the nation suddenly found itself, or rather its rulers, very rich in masterpieces. The
importance of such a school of manner as this, with its knowledge of other worlds and other
societies, its interest in literature and art, its cosmopolitan atmosphere, can only be truly estimated
by those who remember the boorish habits of the country gentlemen of the earlier eighteenth
century described by Fielding. With the French war this cosmopolitan atmosphere disappeared.
Thenceforth the aristocracy were as insular in their prejudices as any of their countrymen, and Lord
Holland, who preserved the larger traditions of his class, provoked suspicion and resentment by
travelling in Spain during the Peninsular War.(1*)
But if the art and literature of the eighteenth century show the predominance of a class that
cultivated its taste outside England, and that regarded art and literature as mere ministers to the
pleasure of a few,(2*) they show also that that class had political power as well as social privileges.
There is no art of the time that can be called national either in England or in France, but the art of
eighteenth-century England bears a less distant relation to the English people than the art of
eighteenth-century France to the people of France, just in proportion as the great English houses
touched the English people more closely than Versailles touched the French. English art is less of
mere decoration and less of mere imitation, for, though it is true that Chippendale, Sheraton, and
the Adam brothers were all in one sense copying the furniture of other countries -- Holland, China,
France -- they all preserved a certain English strain, and it was the flavour of the vernacular, so to
speak, that saved their designs from the worst foreign extravagance. They were designing, indeed,
for a class and not for a nation, but it was for a class that had never broken quite away from the life
of the society that it controlled. The English aristocracy remained a race of country gentlemen. They
never became mere loungers or triflers, kicking their heels about a Court and amusing themselves
with tedious gallantries and intrigues. They threw themselves into country life and government, and
they were happiest away from London. The great swarms of guests that settled on such country
seats as Holkham were like gay and boisterous schoolboys compared with the French nobles who
had forgotten how to live in the country, and were tired of living at Versailles. If anything could
exceed Grey's reluctance to leave his great house in Northumberland for the excitements of
Parliament, it was Fox's reluctance to leave his little house in Surrey. The taste for country
pleasures and for country sports was never lost, and its persistence explains the physical vitality of
the aristocracy. This was a social fact of great importance, for it is health after all that wins half the
battles of classes. No quantity of Burgundy and Port could kill off a race that was continually
restoring its health by life in the open air; it did not matter that Squire Western generally spent the
night under the table if he generally spent the day in the saddle. This inheritance of an open-air life
is probably the reason that in England, in contrast to France and Italy, good looks are more often to
be found in the aristocracy than in other classes of society.
It was due to this physical vigour that the aristocracy, corrupt and selfish though it was, never fell
into the supreme vice of moral decadence. The other European aristocracies crumbled at once
before Napoleon: the English aristocracy, amidst all its blunders and errors, kept its character for
endurance and fortitude. Throughout that long struggle, when Napoleon was strewing Europe with
his triumphs and, as Sheridan said, making kings the sentinels of his power, England alone never
broke a treaty or made a surrender at his bidding. For ten years Pitt seems the one fixed point
among the rulers of Europe. It is not, of course, to be argued that the ruling class showed more
valour and determination than any other class of Englishmen would have shown: the empire-
builders of the century, men of daring and enterprise on distant frontiers, were not usually of the
ruling class, and Dr. Johnson once wrote an essay to explain why it was that the English common
soldier was the bravest of the common soldiers of the world. The comparison is between the English
aristocracy and the other champions of law and order in the great ordeal of this war, and in that
comparison the English aristocracy stands out in conspicuous eminence in a Europe of shifting and
melting governments.
The politics of a small class of privileged persons enjoying an undisputed power might easily have
degenerated into a mere business of money-making and nothing else. There is plenty of this
atmosphere in the eighteenth-century system: a study merely of the society memoirs of the age is
enough to dissipate the fine old illusion that men of blood and breeding have a nice and fastidious
Sense about money. Just the opposite is the truth. Aristocracies have had their virtues, hut the virtue
of a magnificent disdain for money is not to be expected in a class which has for generations taken
it as a matter of course that it should be maintained by the State. At no time in English history have
sordid motives been so conspicuous in politics as during the days when power was most a
monopoly of the aristocracy. No politicians have sacrificed so much of their time, ability, and
principles to the pursuit of gain as the politicians of the age when poor men could only squeeze into
politics by twos or threes in a generation, when the aristocracy put whole families into the House of
Commons as a matter of course, and Burke boasted that the House of Lords was wholly, and the
House of Commons was mainly, composed for the defence of hereditary property.
But the politics of the eighteenth century are not a mere scramble for place and power. An age
which produced the two Pitts could not be called an age of mere avarice. An age which produced
Burke and Fox and Grey could not be called an age of mere ambition. The politics of this little class
are illuminated by the great and generous behaviour of individuals. If England was the only country
where the ruling class made a stand against Napoleon, England was the only country where
members of the ruling class were found to make a stand for the ideas of the Revolution. Perhaps
the proudest boast that the English oligarchy can make is the boast that some of its members,
nursed as they had been in a soft and feathered world of luxury and privilege, could look without
dismay on what Burke called the strange, wild, nameless, enthusiastic thing established in the
centre of Europe. The spectacle of Fox and Sheridan and Grey leading out their handful of Liberals
night after night against the Treason and Sedition Bills, at a time when an avalanche of terror had
overwhelmed the mind of England, when Pitt, Burke, and Dundas thought no malice too poisoned,
Gillray and Rowlandson no deforming touch of the brush too brutal, when the upper classes thought
they were going to lose their property, and the middle classes thought they were going to lose their
religion, is one of the sublime spectacles of history. This quality of fearlessness in the defence of
great causes is displayed in a fine succession of characters and incidents; Chatham, whose
courage in facing his country's dangers was not greater than his courage in blaming his country's
crimes; Burke, with his elaborate rage playing round the dazzling renown of a Rodney; Fox, whose
voice sounds like thunder coming over the mountains, hurled at the whole race of conquerors;
Holland, pleading almost alone for the abolition of capital punishment for stealing before a bench of
bishops; a man so little given to revolutionary sympathies as Fitzwilliam, leaving his lord-lieutenancy
rather than condone the massacre of Peterloo. If moral courage is the power of combating and
defying an enveloping atmosphere of prejudice, passion, and panic, a generation which was poor in
most of the public virtues was, at least, conspicuously rich in one. Foreign policy, the treatment of
Ireland, of India, of slaves, are beyond the scope of this book, but in glancing at the class whose
treatment of the English poor has been the subject of our study, it is only just to record that in other
regions of thought and conduct they bequeathed a great inheritance of moral and liberal ideas: a
passion for justice between peoples, a sense for national freedom, a great body of principle by
which to check, refine, and discipline the gross appetites of national ambition. Those ideas were the
ideas of a minority, but they were expressed and defended with an eloquence and a power that
have made the man important and a glorious part of English history. In all this development of liberal
doctrine it is not fanciful to see the ennobling influence of the Greek writers on whom every
eighteenth-century politician was bred and nourished.
Fox thought in the bad days of the war with the Revolution that his own age resembled the age of
Cicero, and that Parliamentary government in England, undermined by the power of the Court,
would disappear like liberty in republican Rome. There is a strange letter in which, condoling with
Grey on his father's becoming a peer, he remarks that it matters the less because the House of
Commons will soon cease to be of any importance. This prediction was falsified, and England never
produced a Caesar. There is, however, a real analogy in the social history of the two periods. The
English ruling class corresponds to the Roman senatorial order, both classes claiming office on the
same ground of family title, a Cavendish being as inevitable as a Claudius, and an AEmilius as a
Gower. The equites were the second rank of the Roman social aristocracy, as the manufacturers or
bankers were of the English. A Roman eques could pass into the senatorial order by holding the
quaestorship; an English manufacturer could pass into the governing class by buying an estate. The
English aristocracy, like the Roman, looked a little doubtfully on new-comers, and even a Cicero or
a Canning might complain of the. freezing welcome of the old nobles; but it preferred to use rather
than to exclude them.
In both societies the aristocracy regarded the poor in much the same spirit, as a problem of
discipline and order, and passed on to posterity the same vague suggestion of squalor and
turbulence. Thus it comes that most people who think of the poor in the Roman Republic think only
of the great corn largesses; and most people who think of the poor in eighteenth-century England
think only of the great system of relief from the rates. Mr. Warde Fowler has shown how hard it is to
find in the Roman writers any records of the poor. So it is with the records of eighteenth-century
England. In both societies the obscurity which surrounded the poor in life has settled on their wrongs
in history. For one person who knows anything about so immense an event as the disappearance of
the old English village society, there are a hundred who know everything about the fashionable
scenes of high politics and high play, that formed the exciting world of the upper classes. The
silence that shrouds these village revolutions was not quite unbroken, but the cry that disturbed it is
like a noise that break for a moment on the night, and then dies away, only serving to make the
stillness deeper and more solemn. The Deserted Village is known wherever the English language is
spoken, but Goldsmith's critics have been apt to treat it, as Dr. Johnson treated it, as a beautiful
piece of irrelevant pathos, and his picture of what was happening in England has been admired as a
picture of what was happening in his discolouring dreams. Macaulay connected that picture with
reality in his ingenious theory, that England provided the village of the happy and smiling opening,
and Ireland the village of the sombre and tragical end. One enclosure has been described in
literature, and described by a victim, John Clare, the Northamptonshire peasant, who drifted into a
madhouse through a life of want and trouble. Those who recall the discussions of the time, and the
assumption of the upper classes that the only question that concerned the poor was the question
whether enclosure increased employment, will be struck by the genuine emotion with which Clare
dwells on the natural beauties of the village of his childhood, and his attachment to his home and its
memories. But Clare's day was brief and he has few readers.(3*) In art the most undistinguished
features of the most undistinguished members of the aristocracy dwell in the glowing colours of a
Reynolds; the poor have no heirlooms, and there was no Millet to preserve the sorrow and despair
of the homeless and dispossessed. So comfortably have the rich soothed to sleep the sensibilities
of history. These debonair lords who smile at us from the family galleries do not grudge us our
knowledge of the escapades at Brooks's or at White's in which they sowed their wild oats, but we
fancy they are grateful for the poppy seeds of oblivion that have been scattered over the secrets of
their estates. Happy the race that can so engage the world with its follies that it can secure repose
for its crimes.
De Quincey has compared the blotting out of a colony of Alexander's in the remote and unknown
confines of civilisation, to the disappearance of one of those starry bodies which, fixed in longitude
and latitude for generations, are one night observed to be missing by some wandering telescope.
'The agonies of a perishing world have been going on, but all is bright and silent in the heavenly
host.' So is it with the agonies of the poor. Wilberforce, in the midst of the scenes described in this
volume, could declare, 'What blessings do we enjoy in this happy country; I am reading ancient
history, and the pictures it exhibits of the vices and the miseries of men fill me with mixed emotions
of indignation, horror and gratitude.' Amid the great distress that followed Waterloo and peace, it
was a commonplace of statesmen like Castlereagh and Canning that England was the only happy
country in the world, and that so long as the monopoly of their little class was left untouched, her
happiness would survive. That class has left bright and ample records of its life in literature, in art, in
political traditions, in the display of great orations and debates, in memories of brilliant conversation
and sparkling wit; it has left dim and meagre records of the disinherited peasants that are the
shadow of its wealth; of the exiled labourers that are the shadow of its pleasures; of the villages
sinking in poverty and crime and shame that are the shadow of its power and its pride.
NOTES:
1. See a remarkable letter from Lord Dudley. 'He has already been enough on the Continent for any
reasonable and either of curiosity or instruction, and his availing himself so immediately of this
opportunity to go to a foreign country again looks a little too much like distaste for his own.' -- Letters
to Ivy from the first Earl of Dudley, October 1808.
2. See on this subject a very interesting article by Mr L. March Phillippe in the Contemporary
Review, August 1911.
3. Helpstone was enclosed by an Act of 1809. Clare was then sixteen years old. His association with
the old village life had been intimate, for he had tended geese and sheep on the common, and he
had learnt the old country songs from the last village cowherd. His poem on Helpstone was
published in 1820.
Livros Grátis
( http://www.livrosgratis.com.br )
Milhares de Livros para Download:
Baixar livros de Administração
Baixar livros de Agronomia
Baixar livros de Arquitetura
Baixar livros de Artes
Baixar livros de Astronomia
Baixar livros de Biologia Geral
Baixar livros de Ciência da Computação
Baixar livros de Ciência da Informação
Baixar livros de Ciência Política
Baixar livros de Ciências da Saúde
Baixar livros de Comunicação
Baixar livros do Conselho Nacional de Educação - CNE
Baixar livros de Defesa civil
Baixar livros de Direito
Baixar livros de Direitos humanos
Baixar livros de Economia
Baixar livros de Economia Doméstica
Baixar livros de Educação
Baixar livros de Educação - Trânsito
Baixar livros de Educação Física
Baixar livros de Engenharia Aeroespacial
Baixar livros de Farmácia
Baixar livros de Filosofia
Baixar livros de Física
Baixar livros de Geociências
Baixar livros de Geografia
Baixar livros de História
Baixar livros de Línguas
Baixar livros de Literatura
Baixar livros de Literatura de Cordel
Baixar livros de Literatura Infantil
Baixar livros de Matemática
Baixar livros de Medicina
Baixar livros de Medicina Veterinária
Baixar livros de Meio Ambiente
Baixar livros de Meteorologia
Baixar Monografias e TCC
Baixar livros Multidisciplinar
Baixar livros de Música
Baixar livros de Psicologia
Baixar livros de Química
Baixar livros de Saúde Coletiva
Baixar livros de Serviço Social
Baixar livros de Sociologia
Baixar livros de Teologia
Baixar livros de Trabalho
Baixar livros de Turismo