Download PDF
ads:
Lombard Street: A Description of the Money Market.
Walter Bagehot
CHAPTER I - Introductory
I venture to call this Essay `Lombard Street,' and not the `Money Market,' or any such phrase,
because I wish to deal, and to show that I mean to deal, with concrete realities. A notion prevails
that the Money Market is something so impalpable that it can only be spoken of in very abstract
words, and that therefore books on it must always be exceedingly difficult. But I maintain that the
Money Market is as concrete and real as anything else; that it can be described in as plain words;
that it is the writer's fault if what he says is not clear. In one respect, however, I admit that I am about
to take perhaps an unfair advantage. Half, and more than half, of the supposed `difficulty' of the
Money Market has arisen out of the controversies as to `Peel's Act,' and the abstract discussions on
the theory on which that act is based, or supposed to be based. But in the ensuing pages I mean to
speak as little as I can of the Act of 1844; and when I do speak of it, I shall deal nearly exclusively
with its experienced effects, and scarcely at all, if at all, with its refined basis.
For this I have several reasons,one, that if you say anything about the Act of 1844, it is little matter
what else you say, for few will attend to it. Most critics will seize on the passage as to the Act, either
to attack it or defend it, as if it were the main point. There has been so much fierce controversy as to
this Act of Parliamentand there is still so much animositythat a single sentence respecting it is far
more interesting to very many than a whole book on any other part of the subject. Two hosts of
eager disputants on this subject ask of every new writer the one questionAre you with us or against
us? and they care for little else. Of course if the Act of 1844 really were, as is commonly thought, the
primum mobile of the English Money Market,the source of all good according to some, and the
source of all harm according to others,the extreme irritation excited by an opinion on it would be no
reason for not giving a free opinion. A writer on any subject must not neglect its cardinal fact, for fear
that others may abuse him. But, in my judgment, the Act of 1844 is only a subordinate matter in the
Money Market; what has to be said on it has been said at disproportionate length; the phenomena
connected with it have been magnified into greater relative importance than they at all deserve. We
must never forget that a quarter of a century has passed since 1844,a period singularly remarkable
for its material progress, and almost marvellous in its banking development. Even, therefore, if the
facts so much referred to in 844 had the importance then ascribed to them,and I believe that in
some respects they were even then overstated,there would be nothing surprising in finding that in a
new world new phenomena had arisen which now are larger and stronger. In my opinion this is the
truth: since 1844, Lombard Street is so changed that we cannot judge of it without describing and
discussing a most vigorous adult world which then was small and weak. On this account I wish to
say as little as is fairly possible of the Act of 844, and, as far as I can, to isolate and dwell
exclusively on the `Post- Peel' agencies, so that those who have had enough of that well- worn
theme (and they are very many) may not be wearied, and that the new and neglected parts of the
subject may be seen as they really are.
The briefest and truest way of describing Lombard Street is to say that it is by far the greatest
combination of economical power and economical delicacy that the world has even seen. Of the
greatness of the power there will be no doubt. Money is economical power. Everyone is aware that
England is the greatest moneyed country in the world; everyone admits that it has much more
immediately disposable and ready cash than any other country. But very few persons are aware
how much greater the ready balancethe floating loan-fund which can be lent to anyone or for any
purposeis in England than it is anywhere else in the world. A very few figures will show how large
the London loan-fund is, and how much greater it is than any other. The known depositsthe deposits
of banks which publish their accountsare, in
£
London (31st December, 1872) 120,000,000
Paris (27th February, 1873) 13,000,000
ads:
Livros Grátis
http://www.livrosgratis.com.br
Milhares de livros grátis para download.
New York (February, 1873) 40,000,000
German Empire (31st January, 1873) 8,000,000
And the unknown depositsthe deposits in banks which do not publish their accountsare in London
much greater than those many other of these cities. The bankers' deposits of London are many
times greater than those of any other citythose of Great Britain many times greater than those of any
other country.
Of course the deposits of bankers are not a strictly accurate measure of the resources of a Money
Market. On the contrary, much more cash exists out of banks in France and Germany, and in all
non-banking countries, than could be found in England or Scotland, where banking is developed.
But that cash is not, so to speak, `money-market money:' it is not attainable. Nothing but their
immense misfortunes, nothing but a vast loan in their own securities, could have extracted the
hoards of France from the custody of the French people. The offer of no other securities would have
tempted them, for they had confidence in no other securities. For all other purposes the money
hoarded was useless and might as well not have been hoarded. But the English money is
`borrowable' money. Our people are bolder in dealing with their money than any continental nation,
and even if they were not bolder, the mere fact that their money is deposited in a bank makes it far
more obtainable. A million in the hands of a single banker is a great power; he can at once lend it
where he will, and borrowers can come to him, because they know or believe that he has it. But the
same sum scattered in tens and fifties through a whole nation is no power at all: no one knows
where to find it or whom to ask for it. Concentration of money in banks, though not the sole cause, is
the principal cause which has made the Money Market of England so exceedingly rich, so much
beyond that of other countries.
The effect is seen constantly. We are asked to lend, and do lend, vast sums, which it would be
impossible to obtain elsewhere. It is sometimes said that any foreign country can borrow in Lombard
Street at a price: some countries can borrow much cheaper than others; but all, it is said, can have
some money if they choose to pay enough for it. Perhaps this is an exaggeration; but confined, as of
course it was meant to be, to civilised Governments, it is not much of an exaggeration. There are
very few civilised Governments that could not borrow considerable sums of us if they choose, and
most of them seem more and more likely to choose. If any nation wants even to make a
railwayespecially at all a poor nationit is sure to come to this countryto the country of banksfor the
money. It is true that English bankers are not themselves very great lenders to foreign states. But
they are great lenders to those who lend. They advance on foreign stocks, as the phrase is, with `a
margin;' that is, they find eighty per cent of the money, and the nominal lender finds the rest. And it
is in this way that vast works are achieved with English aid which but for that aid would never have
been planned.
In domestic enterprises it is the same. We have entirely lost the idea that any undertaking likely to
pay, and seen to be likely, can perish for want of money; yet no idea was more familiar to our
ancestors, or is more common now in most countries. A citizen of London in Queen Elizabeth's time
could not have imagined our state of mind. He would have thought that it was of no use inventing
railways (if he could have understood what a railway meant), for you would not have been able to
collect the capital with which to make them. At this moment, in colonies and all rude countries, there
is no large sum of transferable money; there is no fund from which you can borrow, and out of which
you can make immense works. Taking the world as a whole-either now or in the pastit is certain that
in poor states there is no spare money for new and great undertakings, and that in most rich states
the money is too scattered, and clings too close to the hands of the owners, to be often obtainable in
large quantities for new purposes. A place like Lombard Street, where in all but the rarest times
money can be always obtained upon good security or upon decent prospects of probable gain, is a
luxury which no country has ever enjoyed with even comparable equality before.
But though these occasional loans to new enterprises and foreign States are the most conspicuous
instances of the power of Lombard Street, they are not by any means the most remarkable or the
most important use of that power. English trade is carried on upon borrowed capital to an extent of
which few foreigners have an idea, and none of our ancestors could have conceived. In every
district small traders have arisen, who `discount their bills' largely, and with the capital so borrowed,
harass and press upon, if they do not eradicate, the old capitalist. The new trader has obviously an
immense advantage in the struggle of trade. If a merchant have 50,000 l. all his own,to gain 10 per
cent on it he must make 5,000 l. a year, and must charge for his goods accordingly; but if another
ads:
has only 10,000 l., and borrows 40,000 l. by discounts (no extreme instance in our modem trade),
he has the same capital of 50,000 l. to use, and can sell much cheaper. If the rate at which he
borrows be 5 per cent., he will have to pay 2,000 l. a year; and if, like the old trader, he make 5,000
l. a year, he will still, after paying his interest, obtain 3,000 l. a year, or 30 per cent, on his own
10,000 l. As most merchants are content with much less than 30 per cent, he will be able, if he
wishes, to forego some of that profit, lower the price of the commodity, and drive the old-fashioned
traderthe man who trades on his own capitalout of the market. In modem English business, owing to
the certainty of obtaining loans on discount of bills or otherwise at a moderate rate of interest, there
is a steady bounty on trading with borrowed capital, and a constant discouragement to confine
yourself solely or mainly to your own capital.
This increasingly democratic structure of English commerce is very unpopular in many quarters, and
its effects are no doubt exceedingly mixed. On the one hand, it prevents the long duration of great
families of merchant princes, such as those of Venice and Genoa, who inherited nice cultivation as
well as great wealth, and who, to some extent, combined the tastes of an aristocracy with the insight
and verve of men of business. These are pushed out, so to say, by the dirty crowd of little men. After
a generation or two they retire into idle luxury. Upon their immense capital they can only obtain low
profits, and these they do not think enough to compensate them for the rough companions and rude
manners they must meet in business. This constant levelling of our commercial houses is, too,
unfavourable to commercial morality. Great firms, with a reputation which they have received from
the past, and which they wish to transmit to the future, cannot be guilty of small frauds. They live by
a continuity of trade, which detected fraud would spoil. When we scrutinise the reason of the
impaired reputation of English goods, we find it is the fault of new men with little money of their own,
created by bank `discounts.' These men want business at once, and they produce an inferior article
to get it. They rely on cheapness, and rely successfully.
But these defects and others in the democratic structure of commerce are compensated by one
great excellence. No country of great hereditary trade, no European country at least, was ever so
little `sleepy,' to use the only fit word, as England; no other was ever so prompt at once to seize new
advantages. A country dependent mainly on great `merchant princes' will never be so prompt; their
commerce perpetually slips more and more into a commerce of routine. A man of large wealth,
however intelligent, always thinks, more or less'I have a great income, and I want to keep it. If things
go on as they are I shall certainly keep it; but if they change I may not keep it.' Consequently he
considers every change of circumstance a `bore,' and thinks of such changes as little as he can. But
a new man, who has his way to make in the world, knows that such changes are his opportunities;
he is always on the look-out for them, and always heeds them when he finds them. The rough and
vulgar structure of English commerce is the secret of its life; for it contains `the propensity to
variation,' which, in the social as in the animal kingdom, is the principle of progress.
In this constant and chronic borrowing, Lombard Street is the great go-between. It is a sort of
standing broker between quiet saving districts of the country and the active employing districts. Why
particular trades settled in particular places it is often difficult to say; but one thing is certain, that
when a trade has settled in any one spot, it is very difficult for another to oust itimpossible unless the
second place possesses some very great intrinsic advantage. Commerce is curiously conservative
in its homes, unless it is imperiously obliged to migrate. Partly from this cause, and partly from
others, there are whole districts in England which cannot and do not employ their own money. No
purely agricultural county does so. The savings of a county with good land but no manufactures and
no trade much exceed what can be safely lent in the county. These savings are first lodged in the
local banks, are by them sent to London, and are deposited with London bankers, or with the bill
brokers. In either case the result is the same. The money thus sent up from the accumulating
districts is employed in discounting the bills of the industrial districts. Deposits are made with the
bankers and bill brokers in Lombard Street by the bankers of such counties as Somersetshire and
Hampshire, and those bill brokers and bankers employ them in the discount of bills from Yorkshire
and Lancashire. Lombard Street is thus a perpetual agent between the two great divisions of
England, between the rapidly-growing districts, where almost any amount of money can be well and
easily employed, and the stationary and the declining districts, where there is more money than can
be used.
This organisation is so useful because it is so easily adjusted. Political economists say that capital
sets towards the most profitable trades, and that it rapidly leaves the less profitable and non-paying
trades. But in ordinary countries this is a slow process, and some persons who want to have ocular
demonstration of abstract truths have been inclined to doubt it because they could not see it. In
England, however, the process would be visible enough if you could only see the books of the bill
brokers and the bankers. Their bill cases as a rule are full of the bills drawn in the most profitable
trades, and caeteris paribus and in comparison empty of those drawn in the less profitable. If the
iron trade ceases to be as profitable as usual, less iron is sold; the fewer the sales the fewer the
bills; and in consequence the number of iron bills in Lombard street is diminished. On the other
hand, if in consequence of a bad harvest the corn trade becomes on a sudden profitable,
immediately `corn bills' are created in great numbers, and if good are discounted in Lombard Street.
Thus English capital runs as surely and instantly where it is most wanted, and where there is most
to be made of it, as water runs to find its level.
This efficient and instantly-ready organisation gives us an enormous advantage in competition with
less advanced countriesless advanced, that is, in this particular respect of credit. In a new trade
English capital is instantly at the disposal of persons capable of understanding the new
opportunities and of making good use of them. In countries where there is little money to lend, and
where that little is lent tardily and reluctantly, enterprising traders are long kept back, because they
cannot at once borrow the capital, without which skill and knowledge are useless. All sudden trades
come to England, and in so doing often disappoint both rational probability and the predictions of
philosophers. The Suez Canal is a curious case of this. All predicted that the canal would undo what
the discovery of the passage to India round the Cape effected. Before that all Oriental trade went to
ports in the South of Europe, and was thence diffused through Europe. That London and Liverpool
should be centres of East Indian commerce is a geographical anomaly, which the Suez Canal, it
was said, would rectify. `The Greeks,' said M. de Tocqueville, `the Styrians, the Italians, the
Dalmatians, and the Sicilians, are the people who will use the Canal if any use it.' But, on the
contrary, the main use of the Canal has been by the English. None of the nations named by
Tocqueville had the capital, or a tithe of it, ready to build the large screw steamers which alone can
use the Canal profitably. Ultimately these plausible predictions may or may not be right, but as yet
they have been quite wrong, not because England has rich peoplethere are wealthy people in all
countriesbut because she possesses an unequalled fund of floating money, which will help in a
moment any merchant who sees a great prospect of new profit.
And not only does this unconscious `organisation of capital,' to use a continental phrase, make the
English specially quick in comparison with their neighbours on the continent at seizing on novel
mercantile opportunities, but it makes them likely also to retain any trade on which they have once
regularly fastened. Mr. Macculloch, following Ricardo, used to teach that all old nations had a
special aptitude for trades in which much capital is required. The interest of capital having been
reduced in such countries, he argued, by the necessity of continually resorting to inferior soils, they
can undersell countries where profit is high in all trades needing great capital. And in this theory
there is doubtless much truth, though it can only be applied in practice after a number of limitations
and with a number of deductions of which the older school of political economists did not take
enough notice. But the same principle plainly and practically applies to England, in consequence of
her habitual use of borrowed capital. As has been explained, a new man, with a small capital of his
own and a large borrowed capital, can undersell a rich man who depends on his own capital only.
The rich man wants the full rate of mercantile profit on the whole of the capital employed in his
trade, but the poor man wants only the interest of money (perhaps not a third of the rate of profit) on
very much of what he uses, and therefore an income will be an ample recompense to the poor man
which would starve the rich man out of the trade. All the common notions about the new competition
of foreign countries with England and its dangersnotions in which there is in other aspects much
truth require to be reconsidered in relation to this aspect. England has a special machinery for
getting into trade new men who will be content with low prices, and this machinery will probably
secure her success, for no other country is soon likely to rival it effectually.
There are many other points which might be insisted on, but it would be tedious and useless to
elaborate the picture. The main conclusion is very plainthat English trade is become essentially a
trade on borrowed capital, and that it is only by this refinement of our banking system that we are
able to do the sort of trade we do, or to get through the quantity of it.
But in exact proportion to the power of this system is its delicacy I should hardly say too much if I
said its danger. Only our familiarity blinds us to the marvellous nature of the system. There never
was so much borrowed money collected in the world as is now collected in London. Of the many
millions in Lombard street, infinitely the greater proportion is held by bankers or others on short
notice or on demand; that is to say, the owners could ask for it all any day they please: in a panic
some of them do ask for some of it. If any large fraction of that money really was demanded, our
banking system and our industrial system too would be in great danger.
Some of those deposits too are of a peculiar and very distinct nature. Since the Franco-German
war, we have become to a much larger extent than before the Bankers of Europe. A very large sum
of foreign money is on various accounts and for various purposes held here. And in a time of panic it
might be asked for. In 1866 we held only a much smaller sum of foreign money, but that smaller
sum was demanded and we had to pay it at great cost and suffering, and it would be far worse if we
had to pay the greater sums we now hold, without better resources than we had then.
It may be replied, that though our instant liabilities are great, our present means are large; that
though we have much we may be asked to pay at any moment, we have very much always ready to
pay it with. But, on the contrary, there is no country at present, and there never was any country
before, in which the ratio of the cash reserve to the bank deposits was so small as it is now in
England.
(1)
So far from our being able to rely on the proportional magnitude of our cash in hand, the
amount of that cash is so exceedingly small that a bystander almost trembles when he compares its
minuteness with the immensity of the credit which rests upon it.
Again, it may be said that we need not be alarmed at the magnitude of our credit system or at its
refinement, for that we have learned by experience the way of controlling it, and always manage it
with discretion. But we do not always manage it with discretion. There is the astounding instance of
Overend, Gurney, and Co. to the contrary. Ten years ago that house stood next to the Bank of
England in the City of London; it was better known abroad than any similar firm known, perhaps,
better than any purely English firm. The partners had great estates, which had mostly been made in
the business. They still derived an immense income from it. Yet in six years they lost all their own
wealth, sold the business to the company, and then lost a large part of the company's capital. And
these losses were made in a manner so reckless and so foolish, that one would think a child who
had lent money in the City of London would have lent it better. After this example, we must not
confide too surely in long-established credit, or in firmly-rooted traditions of business. We must
examine the system on which these great masses of money are manipulated, and assure ourselves
that it is safe and right.
But it is not easy to rouse men of business to the task. They let the tide of business float before
them; they make money or strive to do so while it passes, and they are unwilling to think where it is
going. Even the great collapse of Overends, though it caused a panic, is beginning to be forgotten.
Most men of business think'Anyhow this system will probably last my time. It has gone on a long
time, and is likely to go on still.' But the exact point is, that it has not gone on a long time. The
collection of these immense sums in one place and in few hands is perfectly new. In 1844 the
liabilities of the four great London Joint Stock Banks were 10,637,000 l.; they now are more than
60,000,000 l. The private deposits of the Bank of England then were 9,000,000 l.; they now are
8,000,000 l. There was in throughout the country but a fraction of the vast deposit business which
now exists. We cannot appeal, therefore, to experience to prove the safety of our system as it now
is, for the present magnitude of that system is entirely new. Obviously a system may be fit to
regulate a few millions, and yet quite inadequate when it is set to cope with many millions. And thus
it may be with `Lombard Street,' so rapid has been its growth, and so unprecedented is its nature.
I am by no means an alarmist. I believe that our system, though curious and peculiar, may be
worked safely; but if we wish so to work it, we must study it. We must not think we have an easy
task when we have a difficult task, or that we are living in a natural state when we are really living in
an artificial one. Money will not manage itself, and Lombard street has a great deal of money to
manage.
CHAPTER II - A General View of Lombard Street
I.
The objects which you see in Lombard Street, and in that money world which is grouped about it,
are the Bank of England, the Private Banks, the Joint Stock Banks, and the bill brokers. But before
describing each of these separately we must look at what all have in common, and at the relation of
each to the others.
The distinctive function of the banker, says Ricardo, `begins as soon as he uses the money of
others;' as long as he uses his own money he is only a capitalist. Accordingly all the banks in
Lombard Street (and bill brokers are for this purpose only a kind of bankers) hold much money
belonging to other people on running account and on deposit. In continental language, Lombard
Street is an organization of credit, and we are to see if it is a good or bad organization in its kind, or
if, as is most likely, it turn out to be mixed, what are its merits and what are its defects?
The main point on which one system of credit differs from another is `soundness.' Credit means that
a certain confidence is given, and a certain trust reposed. Is that trust justified? and is that
confidence wise? These are the cardinal questions. To put it more simplycredit is a set of promises
to pay; will those promises be kept? Especially in banking, where the `liabilities,' or promises to pay,
are so large, and the time at which to pay them, if exacted, is so short, an instant capacity to meet
engagements is the cardinal excellence.
All which a banker wants to pay his creditors is a sufficient supply of the legal tender of the country,
no matter what that legal tender may be. Different countries differ in their laws of legal tender, but for
the primary purposes of banking these systems are not material. A good system of currency will
benefit the country, and a bad system will hurt it. Indirectly, bankers will be benefited or injured with
the country in which they live; but practically, and for the purposes of their daily life, they have no
need to think, and never do think, on theories of currency. They look at the matter simply. They say
`I am under an obligation to pay such and such sums of legal currency; how much have I in my till,
or have I at once under my command, of that currency?' In America, for example, it is quite enough
for a banker to hold `greenbacks,' though the value of these changes as the Government chooses to
enlarge or contract the issue. But a practical New York banker has no need to think of the goodness
or badness of this system at all; he need only keep enough `greenbacks' to pay all probable
demands, and then he is fairly safe from the risk of failure.
By the law of England the legal tenders are gold and silver coin (the last for small amounts only),
and Bank of England notes. But the number of our attainable bank notes is not, like American
`greenbacks,' dependent on the will of the State; it is limited by the provisions of the Act of 1844.
That Act separates the Bank of England into two halves. The Issue Department only issues notes,
and can only issue 15,000,000 l. on Government securities; for all the rest it must have bullion
deposited. Take, for example an account, which may be considered an average specimen of those
of the last few yearsthat for the last week of 1869:
An account pursuant to the Act 7th and 8th Victoria, cap. 32, for the week ending on Wednesday,
the 29th day of December, 1869.
ISSUE DEPARTMENT.
£ £
Notes issued 33,288,640 Government debt 11,015,100
Other securities 3,984,900
Gold coin and bullion 18,288,640
Silver bullion
33,288,640 33,288,640
BANKING DEPARTMENT.
£ £
Proprietors' capital 14,553,000 Government
securities
13,811,953
Rest 3,103,301 Other securities 19,781,988
Public deposits, including Exchequer, Savings' Banks,
Commissioners of National Debt, and dividend
accounts
8,585,215 Gold and silver
coins
907,982
Other deposits 18,204,607 Notes 10,389,690
Seven-day and other bills 445,490
44,891,613 44,891,613
GEO. FORBES, Chief Cashier. Dated the 30th December, 1869.
There are here 15,000,000 l. bank notes issued on securities, and 18,288,640 l. represented by
bullion. The Bank of England has no power by law to increase the currency in any other manner. It
holds the stipulated amount of securities, and for all the rest it must have bullion. This is the `cast
iron' systemthe `hard and fast' line which the opponents of the Act say ruins us, and which the
partizans of the Act say saves us. But I have nothing to do with its expediency here. All which is to
my purpose is that our paper `legal tender,' our bank notes, can only be obtained in this manner. If,
therefore, an English banker retains a sum of Bank of England notes or coin in due proportion to his
liabilities, he has a sufficient amount of the legal tender of this country, and he need not think of
anything more.
But here a distinction must be made. It is to be observed that properly speaking we should not
include in the `reserve' of a bank `legal tenders,' or cash, which the Bank keeps to transact its daily
business. That is as much a part of its daily stock-in-trade as its desks or offices; or at any rate,
whatever words we may choose to use, we must carefully distinguish between this cash in the till
which is wanted every day, and the safety-fund, as we may call it, the special reserve held by the
bank to meet extraordinary and unfrequent demands.
What then, subject to this preliminary explanation, is the amount of legal tender held by our bankers
against their liabilities? The answer is remarkable, and is the key to our whole system. It may be
broadly said that no bank in London or out of it holds any considerable sum in hard cash or legal
tender (above what is wanted for its daily business) except the Banking Department of the Bank of
England. That department had on the 29th day of December, 1869, liabilities as follows:
£
Public deposits 8,585,000
Private deposits 18,205,000
Seven-day and other bills 445,000
Total 27,235,000
and a cash reserve of 11,297,0001. And this is all the cash reserve, we must carefully remember,
which, under the law, the Banking Department of the Bank of Englandas we cumbrously call it the
Bank of England for banking purposespossesses. That department can no more multiply or
manufacture bank notes than any other bank can multiply them. At that particular day the Bank of
England had only 11,297,000 l. in its till against liabilities of nearly three times the amount. It had
`Consols' and other securities which it could offer for sale no doubt, and which, if sold, would
augment its supply of bank notesand the relation of such securities to real cash will be discussed
presently; but of real cash, the Bank of England for this purposethe banking bankhad then so much
and no more.
And we may well think this a great deal, if we examine the position of other banks. No other bank
holds any amount of substantial importance in its own till beyond what is wanted for daily purposes.
All London banks keep their principal reserve on deposit at the Banking Department of the Bank of
England. This is by far the easiest and safest place for them to use. The Bank of England thus has
the responsibility of taking care of it. The same reasons which make it desirable for a private person
to keep a banker make it also desirable for every banker, as respects his reserve, to bank with
another banker if he safely can. The custody of very large sums in solid cash entails much care, and
some cost; everyone wishes to shift these upon others if he can do so without suffering.
Accordingly, the other bankers of London, having perfect confidence in the Bank of England, get
that bank to keep their reserve for them.
The London bill brokers do much the same. Indeed, they are only a special sort of bankers who
allow daily interest on deposits, and who for most of their money give security. But we have no
concern now with these differences of detail. The bill brokers lend most of their money, and deposit
the remnant either with the Bank of England or some London banker. That London banker lends
what he chooses of it, the rest he leaves at the Bank of England. You always come back to the Bank
of England at last. But those who keep immense sums with a banker gain a convenience at the
expense of a danger. They are liable to lose them if the bank fail. As all other bankers keep their
banking reserve at the Bank of England, they are liable to fail if it fails. They are dependent on the
management of the Bank of England in a day of difficulty and at a crisis for the spare money they
keep to meet that difficulty and crisis. And in this there is certainly considerable risk. Three times
`Peel's Act' has been suspended because the Banking Department was empty. Before the Act was
broken
£
In 1847, the Banking Department was reduced to 1,994,000
1857 " " 1,462,000
1866 " 3,000,000
In fact, in none of those years could the Banking Department of the Bank of England have survived
if the law had not been broken. Nor must it be fancied that this danger is unreal, artificial, and
created by law. There is a risk of our thinking so, because we hear that the danger can be cured by
breaking an Act; but substantially the same danger existed before the Act. In 1825, when only coin
was a legal tender, and when there was only one department in the Bank, the Bank had reduced its
reserve to 1,027,000 l., and was within an ace of stopping payment.
But the danger to the depositing banks is not the sole or the principal consequence of this mode of
keeping the London reserve. The main effect is to cause the reserve to be much smaller in
proportion to the liabilities than it would otherwise be. The reserve of the London bankers being on
deposit in the Bank of England, the Bank always lends a principal part of it. Suppose, a favourable
supposition, that the Banking Department holds more than two-fifths of its liabilities in cashthat it
lends three-fifths of its deposits and retains in reserve only two-fifths. If then the aggregate of the
bankers' deposited reserve be 5,000,000 l., 3,000,000 l. of it will be lent by the Banking Department,
and 2,000,000 l. will be kept in the till. In consequence, that 2,000,000 l. is all which is really held in
actual cash as against the liabilities of the depositing banks. If Lombard Street were on a sudden
thrown into liquidation, and made to pay as much as it could on the spot, that 2,000,000 l. would be
all which the Bank of England could pay to the depositing banks, and consequently all, besides the
small cash in the till, which those banks could on a sudden pay to the persons who have deposited
with them.
We see then that the banking reserve of the Bank of England some o,ooo,oool. on an average of
years now, and formerly much lessis all which is held against the liabilities of Lombard Street; and if
that were all, we might well be amazed at the immense development of our credit systemin plain
English. at the immense amount of our debts payable on demand, and the smallness of the sum of
actual money which we keep to pay them if demanded. But there is more to come. Lombard Street
is not only a place requiring to keep a reserve, it is itself a place where reserves are kept. All country
bankers keep their reserve in London. They only retain in each country town the minimum of cash
necessary to the transaction of the current business of that country town. Long experience has told
them to a nicety how much this is, and they do not waste capital and lose profit by keeping more
idle. They send the money to London, invest a part of it in securities, and keep the rest with the
London bankers and the bill brokers. The habit of Scotch and Irish bankers is much the same. All
their spare money is in London, and is invested as all other London money now is; and, therefore,
the reserve in the Banking Department of the Bank of England is the banking reserve not only of the
Bank of England, but of all Londonand not only of all London, but of all England, Ireland, and
Scotland too.
Of late there has been a still further increase in our liabilities. Since the Franco-German war, we
may be said to keep the European reserve also. Deposit Banking is indeed so small on the
Continent, that no large reserve need be held on account of it. A reserve of the same sort which is
needed in England and Scotland is not needed abroad. But all great communities have at times to
pay large sums in cash, and of that cash a great store must be kept somewhere. Formerly there
were two such stores in Europe, one was the Bank of France, and the other the Bank of England.
But since the suspension of specie payments by the Bank of France, its use as a reservoir of specie
is at an end. No one can draw a cheque on it and be sure of getting gold or silver for that cheque.
Accordingly the whole liability for such international payments in cash is thrown on the Bank of
England. No doubt foreigners cannot take from us our own money; they must send here `value in
some shape or other for all they take away. But they need not send `cash;' they may send good bills
and discount them in Lombard Street and take away any part of the produce, or all the produce, in
bullion. It is only putting the same point in other words to say that all exchange operations are
centering more and more in London. Formerly for many purposes Paris was a European settling-
house, but now it has ceased to be so. The note of the Bank of France has not indeed been
depreciated enough to disorder ordinary transactions. But any depreciation, however smalleven the
liability to depreciation without its realityis enough to disorder exchange transactions. They are
calculated to such an extremity of fineness that the change of a decimal may be fatal, and may turn
a profit into a loss. Accordingly London has become the sole great settling-house of exchange
transactions in Europe, instead of being formerly one of two. And this pre-eminence London will
probably maintain, for it is a natural pre-eminence. The number of mercantile bills drawn upon
London incalculably surpasses those drawn on any other European city; London is the place which
receives more than any other place, and pays more than any other place, and therefore it is the
natural `clearing house.' The pre-eminence of Paris partly arose from a distribution of political
power, which is already disturbed; but that of London depends on the regular course of commerce,
which is singularly stable and hard to change.
Now that London is the clearing-house to foreign countries, London has a new liability to foreign
countries. At whatever place many people have to make payments, at that place those people must
keep money. A large deposit of foreign money in London is now necessary for the business of the
world. During the immense payments from France to Germany, the sum in transituthe sum in
London has perhaps been unusually large. But it will ordinarily be very great. The present political
circumstances no doubt will soon change. We shall soon hold in Lombard Street far less of the
money of foreign governments; but we shall hold more and more of the money of private persons;
for the deposit at a clearing-house necessary to settle the balance of commerce must tend to
increase as that commerce itself increases.
And this foreign deposit is evidently of a delicate and peculiar nature. It depends on the good
opinion of foreigners, and that opinion may diminish or may change into a bad opinion. After the
panic of 1866, especially after the suspension of Peel's Act (which many foreigners confound with a
suspension of cash payments), a large amount of foreign money was withdrawn from London. And
we may reasonably presume that in proportion as we augment the deposits of cash by foreigners in
London, we augment both the chances and the disasters of a `run' upon England.
And if that run should happen, the bullion to meet it must be taken from the Bank. There is no other
large store in the country. The great exchange dealers may have a little for their own purposes, but
they have no store worth mentioning in comparison with this. If a foreign creditor is so kind as to wait
his time and buy the bullion as it comes into the country, he may be paid without troubling the Bank
or distressing the money market. The German Government has recently been so kind; it was in no
respect afraid. But a creditor who takes fright will not wait, and if he wants bullion in a hurry he must
come to the Bank of England.
In consequence all our credit system depends on the Bank of England for its security. On the
wisdom of the directors of that one Joint Stock Company, it depends whether England shall be
solvent or insolvent. This may seem too strong, but it is not. All banks depend on the Bank of
England, and all merchants depend on some banker. If a merchant have 10,000 l. at his bankers,
and wants to pay it to some one in Germany, he will not be able to pay it unless his banker can pay
him, and the banker will not be able to pay if the Bank of England should be in difficulties and
cannot produce his `reserve.'
The directors of the Bank are, therefore, in fact, if not in name, trustees for the public, to keep a
banking reserve on their behalf; and it would naturally be expected either that they distinctly
recognized this duty and engaged to perform it, or that their own self-interest was so strong in the
matter that no engagement was needed. But so far from there being a distinct undertaking on the
part of the Bank directors to perform this duty, many of them would scarcely acknowledge it, and
some altogether deny it. Mr. Hankey, one of the most careful and most experienced of them, says in
his book on the Bank of England, the best account of the practice and working of the Bank which
anywhere exists'I do not intend here to enter at any length on the subject of the general
management of the Bank, meaning the Banking Department, as the principle upon which the
business is conducted does not differ, as far as I am aware, from that of any wellconducted bank in
London.' But, as anyone can see by the published figures, the Banking Department of the Bank of
England keeps as a great reserve in bank notes and coin between 30 and 50 per cent of its
liabilities, and the other banks only keep in bank notes and coin the bare minimum they need to
open shop with. And such a constant difference indicates, I conceive, that the two are not managed
on the same principle.
The practice of the Bank has, as we all know, been much and greatly improved. They do not now
manage like the other Banks in Lombard Street. They keep an altogether different kind and quantity
of reserve; but though the practice is mended the theory is not. There has never been a distinct
resolution passed by the Directors of the Bank of England, and communicated by them to the public,
stating even in the most general manner, how much reserve they mean to keep or how much they
do not mean, or by what principle in this important matter they will be guided.
The position of the Bank directors is indeed most singular. On the one side a great city opiniona
great national opinion, I may say, for the nation has learnt much from many panicsrequires the
directors to keep a large reserve. The newspapers, on behalf of the nation, are always warning the
directors to keep it, and watching that they do keep it; but, on the other hand, another less visible but
equally constant pressure pushes the directors in exactly the reverse way, and inclines them to
diminish the reserve.
This is the natural desire of all directors to make a good dividend for their shareholders. The more
money lying idle the less, caeteris paribus, is the dividend; the less money lying idle the greater is
the dividend. And at almost every meeting of the proprietors of the Bank of England, there is a
conversation on this subject. Some proprietor says that he does not see why so much money is kept
idle, and hints that the dividend ought to be more.
Indeed, it cannot be wondered at that the Bank proprietors do not quite like their position. Theirs is
the oldest bank in the City, but their profits do not increase, while those of other banks most rapidly
increase. In 1844, the dividend on the stock of the Bank of England was 7 per cent, and the price of
the stock itself 212; the dividend now is 9 per cent, and the price of the stock 232. But in the same
time the shares of the London and Westminster Bank, in spite of an addition of 100 per cent to the
capital, have risen from 27 to 66, and the dividend from 6 per cent to 20 per cent. That the Bank
proprietors should not like to see other companies getting richer than their company is only natural.
Some part of the lowness of the Bank dividend, and of the consequent small value of Bank stock, is
undoubtedly caused by the magnitude of the Bank capital; but much of it is also due to the great
amount of unproductive cashof cash which yields no interestthat the Banking Department of the
Bank of England keeps lying idle. If we compare the London and Westminster Bankwhich is the first
of the joint-stock banks in the public estimation and known to be very cautiously and carefully
managedwith the Bank of England, we shall see the difference at once. The London and
Westminster has only 13 per cent of its liabilities lying idle. The Banking Department of the Bank of
England has over 40 per cent. So great a difference in the management must cause, and does
cause, a great difference in the profits. Inevitably the shareholders of the Bank of England will
dislike this great difference; more or less, they will always urge their directors to diminish (as far as
possible) the unproductive reserve, and to augment as fall as possible their own dividend.
In most banks there would be a wholesome dread restraining the desire of the shareholders to
reduce the reserve; they would fear to impair the credit of the bank. But fortunately or unfortunately,
no one has any fear about the Bank of England. The English world at least believes that it will not,
almost that it cannot, fail. Three times since 1844 the Banking Department has received assistance,
and would have failed without it. In 1825, the entire concern almost suspended payment; in 1797, it
actually did so. But still there is a faith in the Bank, contrary to experience, and despising evidence.
No doubt in every one of these years the condition of the Bank, divided or undivided, was in a
certain sense most sound; it could ultimately have paid all its creditors all it owed, and returned to its
shareholders all their own capital. But ultimate payment is not what the creditors of a bank want;
they want present, not postponed, payment; they want to be repaid according to agreement; the
contract was that they should be paid on demand, and if they are not paid on demand they may be
ruined. And that instant payment, in the years I speak of, the Bank of England certainly could not
have made. But no one in London ever dreams of questioning the credit of the Bank, and the Bank
never dreams that its own credit is in danger. Somehow everybody feels the Bank is sure to come
right. In 1797, when it had scarcely any money left, the Government said not only that it need not
pay away what remained, but that it must not. The `effect of letters of licence' to break Peel's Act
has confirmed the popular conviction that the Government is close behind the Bank, and will help it
when wanted. Neither the Bank nor the Banking Department have ever had an idea of being put
`into liquidation;' most men would think as soon of `winding up' the English nation.
Since then the Bank of England, as a bank, is exempted from the perpetual apprehension that
makes other bankers keep a large reserve the apprehension of discreditit would seem particularly
necessary that its managers should be themselves specially interested in keeping that reserve, and
specially competent to keep it. But I need not say that the Bank directors have not their personal
fortune at stake in the management of the Bank. They are rich City merchants, and their stake in the
Bank is trifling in comparison with the rest of their wealth. If the Bank were wound up, most of them
would hardly in their income feel the difference. And what is more, the Bank directors are not trained
bankers; they were not bred to the trade, and do not in general give the main power of their minds to
it. They are merchants, most of whose time and most of whose real mind are occupied in making
money in their own business and for themselves.
It might be expected that as this great public duty was cast upon the Banking Department of the
Bank, the principal statesmen (if not Parliament itself) would have enjoined on them to perform it.
But no distinct resolution of Parliament has ever enjoined it; scarcely any stray word of any
influential statesman. And, on the contrary, there is a whole catena of authorities, beginning with Sir
Robert Peel and ending with Mr. Lowe, which say that the Banking Department of the Bank of
England is only a Bank like any other banka Company like other companies; that in this capacity it
has no peculiar position, and no public duties at all. Nine-tenths of English statesmen, if they were
asked as to the management of the Banking Department of the Bank of England, would reply that it
was no business of theirs or of Parliament at all; that the Banking Department alone must look to it.
The result is that we have placed the exclusive custody of our entire banking reserve in the hands of
a single board of directors not particularly trained for the dutywho might be called `amateurs,' who
have no particular interest above other people in keeping it undiminishedwho acknowledge no
obligation to keep it undiminished who have never been told by any great statesman or public
authority that they are so to keep it or that they have anything to do with it who are named by and
are agents for a proprietary which would have a greater income if it was diminished,who do not fear,
and who need not fear, ruin, even if it were all gone and wasted.
That such an arrangement is strange must be plain; but its strangeness can only be comprehended
when we know what the custody of a national banking reserve means, and how delicate and difficult
it is.
II.
Such a reserve as we have seen is kept to meet sudden and unexpected demands. If the bankers of
a country are asked for much more than is commonly wanted, then this reserve must be resorted to.
What then are these extra demands? and how is this extra reserve to be used? Speaking broadly,
these extra demands are of two kindsone from abroad to meet foreign payments requisite to pay
large and unusual foreign debts, and the other from at home to meet sudden apprehension or panic
arising in any manner, rational or irrational.
No country has ever been so exposed as England to a foreign demand on its banking reserve, not
only because at present England is a large borrower from foreign nations, but also (and much more)
because no nation has ever had a foreign trade of such magnitude, in such varied objects, or so
ramified through the world. The ordinary foreign trade of a country requires no cash; the exports on
one side balance the imports on the other. But a sudden trade of import like the import of foreign
corn after a bad harvestor (what is much less common, though there are cases of it) the cessation of
any great export,causes a balance to become due, which must be paid in cash.
Now, the only source from which large sums of cash can be withdrawn in countries where banking
is at all developed, is a `bank reserve.' In England especially, except a few sums of no very
considerable amount held by bullion dealers in the course of their business, there are no sums
worth mentioning in cash out of the banks; an ordinary person could hardly pay a serious sum
without going to some bank, even if he spent a month in trying. All persons who wish to pay a large
sum in cash trench of necessity on the banking reserve. But then what is `cash?' Within a country
the action of a Government can settle the quantity, and therefore the value, of its currency; but
outside its own country, no Government can do so. Bullion is the cash' of international trade; paper
currencies are of no use there, and coins pass only as they contain more or less bullion.
When then the legal tender of a country is purely metallic, all that is necessary is that banks should
keep a sufficient store of that `legal tender.' But when the `legal tender' is partly metal and partly
paper, it is necessary that the paper `legal tender'the bank noteshould be convertible into bullion.
And here I should pass my limits, and enter on the theory of Peel's Act if I began to discuss the
conditions of convertibility. I deal only with the primary pre-requisite of effectual foreign paymentsa
sufficient supply of the local legal tender; with the afterstepthe change of the local legal tender into
the universally acceptable commodityI cannot deal.
What I have to deal with is, for the present, ample enough. The Bank of England must keep a
reserve of `legal tender' to be used for foreign payments if itself fit, and to be used in obtaining
bullion if itself unfit. And foreign payments are sometimes very large, and often very sudden. The
`cotton drain,' as it is calledthe drain to the East to pay for Indian cotton during the American Civil
War took many millions from this country for a series of years. A bad harvest must take millions in a
single year. In order to find such great sums, the Bank of England requires the steady use of an
effectual instrument.
That instrument is the elevation of the rate of interest. If the interest of money be raised, it is proved
by experience that money does come to Lombard Street, and theory shows that it ought to come. To
fully explain the matter I must go deep into the theory of the exchanges, but the general notion is
plain enough. Loanable capital, like every other commodity, comes where there is most to be made
of it. Continental bankers and others instantly send great sums here, as soon as the rate of interest
shows that it can be done profitably. While English credit is good, a rise of the value of money in
Lombard Street immediately by a banking operation brings money to Lombard Street. And there is
also a slower mercantile operation. The rise in the rate of discount acts immediately on the trade of
this country. Prices fall here; in consequence imports are diminished, exports are increased, and,
therefore, there is more likelihood of a balance in bullion coming to this country after the rise in the
rate than there was before.
Whatever personsone bank or many banksin any country hold the banking reserve of that country,
ought at the very beginning of an unfavourable foreign exchange at once to raise the rate of interest,
so as to prevent their reserve from being diminished farther, and so as to replenish it by imports of
bullion.
This duty, up to about the year 1860, the Bank of England did not perform at all, as I shall show
farther on. A more miserable history can hardly be found than that of the attempts of the Bankif
indeed they can be called attemptsto keep a reserve and to manage a foreign drain between the
year 1819 (when cash payments were resumed by the Bank, and when our modern Money Market
may be said to begin) and the year 1857. The panic of that year for the first time taught the Bank
directors wisdom, and converted them to sound principles. The present policy of the Bank is an
infinite improvement on the policy before 1857: the two must not be for an instant confounded; but
nevertheless, as I shall hereafter show, the present policy is now still most defective, and much
discussion and much effort. will be wanted before that policy becomes what it ought to be.
A domestic drain is very different. Such a drain arises from a disturbance of credit within the country,
and the difficulty of dealing with it is the greater, because it is often caused, or at least often
enhanced, by a foreign drain. Times without number the public have been alarmed mainly because
they saw that the Banking reserve was already low, and that it was daily getting lower. The two
maladiesan external drain and an internal-often attack the money market at once. What then ought
to be done?
In opposition to what might be at first sight supposed, the best way for the bank or banks who have
the custody of the bank reserve to deal with a drain arising from internal discredit, is to lend freely.
The first instinct of everyone is the contrary. There being a large demand on a fund which you want
to preserve, the most obvious way to preserve it is to hoard itto get in as much as you can, and to let
nothing go out which you can help. But every banker knows that this is not the way to diminish
discredit. This discredit means, `an opinion that you have not got any money,' and to dissipate that
opinion, you must, if possible, show that you have money: you must employ it for the public benefit
in order that the public may know that you have it. The time for economy and for accumulation is
before. A good banker will have accumulated in ordinary times the reserve he is to make use of in
extraordinary times.
Ordinarily discredit does not at first settle on any particular bank, still less does it at first concentrate
itself on the bank or banks holding the principal cash reserve. These banks are almost sure to be
those in best credit, or they would not be in that position, and, having the reserve, they are likely to
look stronger and seem stronger than any others. At first, incipient panic amounts to a kind of vague
conversation: Is A. B. as good as he used to be? Has not C. D. lost money? and a thousand such
questions. A hundred people are talked about, and a thousand think,'Am I talked about, or am I
not?' `Is my credit as good as it used to be, or is it less?' And every day, as a panic grows, this
floating suspicion becomes both more intense and more diffused; it attacks more persons; and
attacks them all more virulently than at first. All men of experience, therefore, try to strengthen
themselves,' as it is called, in the early stage of a panic; they borrow money while they can; they
come to their banker and offer bills for discount, which commonly they would not have offered for
days or weeks to come. And if the merchant be a regular customer, a banker does not like to refuse,
because if he does he will be said, or may be said, to be in want of money, and so may attract the
panic to himself. Not only merchants but all persons under pecuniary liabilitiespresent or
imminentfeel this wish to `strengthen themselves,' and in proportion to those liabilities. Especially is
this the case with what may be called the auxiliary dealers in credit. Under any system of banking
there will always group themselves about the main bank or banks (in which is kept the reserve) a
crowd of smaller money dealers, who watch the minutae of bills, look into special securities which
busy bankers have not time for, and so gain a livelihood. As business grows, the number of such
subsidiary persons augments. The various modes in which money may be lent have each their
peculiarities, and persons who devote themselves to one only lend in that way more safely, and
therefore more cheaply. In time of panic, these subordinate dealers in money will always come to
the principal dealers. In ordinary times, the intercourse between the two is probably close enough.
The little dealer is probably in the habit of pledging his `securities' to the larger dealer at a rate less
than he has himself charged, and of running into the market to lend again. His time and brains are
his principal capital, and he wants to be always using them. But in times of incipient panic, the minor
money dealer always becomes alarmed. His credit is never very established or very wide; he always
fears that he may be the person on whom current suspicion will fasten, and often he is so.
Accordingly he asks the larged dealer for advances. A number of such persons ask all the large
dealersthose who have the moneythe holders of the reserve. And then the plain problem before the
great dealers comes to be `How shall we best protect ourselves? No doubt the immediate advance
to these second-class dealers is annoying, but may not the refusal of it even be dangerous? A panic
grows by what it feeds on; if it devours these second-class men, shall we, the first class, be safe?'
A panic, in a word, is a species of neuralgia, and according to the rules of science you must not
starve it. The holders of the cash reserve must be ready not only to keep it for their own liabilities,
but to advance it most freely for the liabilities of others. They must lend to merchants, to minor
bankers, to `this man and that man,' whenever the security is good. In wild periods of alarm, one
failure makes many, and the best way to prevent the derivative failures is to arrest the primary
failure which causes them. The way in which the panic of 1825 was stopped by advancing money
has been described in so broad and graphic a way that the passage has become classical. `We lent
it,' said Mr. Harman, on behalf of the Bank of England, `by every possible means and in modes we
had never adopted before; we took in stock on security, we purchased Exchequer bills, we made
advances on Exchequer bills, we not only discounted outright, but we made advances on the
deposit of bills of exchange to an immense amount, in short, by every possible means consistent
with the safety of the Bank, and we were not on some occasions over-nice. Seeing the dreadful
state in which the public were, we rendered every assistance in our power.' After a day or two of this
treatment, the entire panic subsided, and the `City' was quite calm.
The problem of managing a panic must not be thought of as mainly a `banking' problem. It is
primarily a mercantile one. All merchants are under liabilities; they have bills to meet soon, and they
can only pay those bills by discounting bills on other merchants. In other words, all merchants are
dependent on borrowing money, and large merchants are dependent on borrowing much money. At
the slightest symptom of panic many merchants want to borrow more than usual; they think they will
supply themselves with the means of meeting their bills while those means are still forthcoming. If
the bankers gratify the merchants, they must lend largely just when they like it least; if they do not
gratify them, there is a panic.
On the surface there seems a great inconsistency in all this. First, you establish in some bank or
banks a certain reserve; you make of it or them a kind of ultimate treasury, where the last shilling of
the country is deposited and kept. And then you go on to say that this final treasury is also to be the
last lending-house; that out of it unbounded, or at any rate immense, advances are to be made
when no once else lends. This seems like sayingfirst, that the reserve should be kept, and then that
it should not be kept. But there is no puzzle in the matter. The ultimate banking reserve of a country
(by whomsoever kept) is not kept out of show, but for certain essential purposes, and one of those
purposes is the meeting a demand for cash caused by an alarm within the country. It is not
unreasonable that our ultimate treasure in particular cases should be lent; on the contrary, we keep
that treasure for the very reason that in particular cases it should be lent.
When reduced to abstract principle, the subject comes to this. An `alarm' is an opinion that the
money of certain persons will not pay their creditors when those creditors want to be paid. If
possible, that alarm is best met by enabling those persons to pay their creditors to the very moment.
For this purpose only a little money is wanted. If that alarm is not so met, it aggravates into a panic,
which is an opinion that most people, or very many people, will not pay their creditors; and this too
can only be met by enabling all those persons to pay what they owe, which takes a great deal of
money. No one has enough money, or anything like enough, but the holders of the bank reserve.
Not that the help so given by the banks holding that reserve necessarily diminishes it. Very
commonly the panic extends as far, or almost as far, as the bank or banks which hold the reserve,
but does not touch it or them at all. In this case it is enough if the dominant bank or banks, so to
speak, pledge their credit for those who want it. Under our present system it is often quite enough
that a merchant or a banker gets the advance made to him put to his credit in the books of the Bank
of England; he may never draw a cheque on it, or, if he does, that cheque may come in again to the
credit of some other customer, who lets it remain on his account. An increase of loans at such times
is often an increase of the liabilities of the bank, not a diminution of its reserve. Just so before 1844,
an issue of notes, as in to quell a panic entirely internal did not diminish the bullion reserve. The
notes went out, but they did not return. They were issued as loans to the public, but the public
wanted no more; they never presented them for payment; they never asked that sovereigns should
be given for them. But the acceptance of a great liability during an augmenting alarm, though not as
bad as an equal advance of cash, is the thing next worst. At any moment the cash may be
demanded. Supposing the panic to grow, it will be demanded, and the reserve will be lessened
accordingly.
No doubt all precautions may, in the end, be unavailing. `On extraordinary occasions,' says Ricardo,
`a general panic may seize the country, when every one becomes desirous of possessing himself of
the precious metals as the most convenient mode of realising or concealing his property,against
such panic banks have no security on any system.' The bank or banks which hold the reserve may
last a little longer than the others; but if apprehension pass a certain bound, they must perish too.
The use of credit is, that it enables debtors to use a certain part of the money their creditors have
lent them. If all those creditors demand all that money at once, they cannot have it, for that which
their debtors have used, is for the time employed, and not to be obtained. With the advantages of
credit we must take the disadvantages too; but to lessen them as much as we can, we must keep a
great store of ready money always available, and advance out of it very freely in periods of panic,
and in times of incipient alarm.
The management of the Money Market is the more difficult, because, as has been said, periods of
internal panic and external demand for bullion commonly occur together. The foreign drain empties
the Bank till, and that emptiness, and the resulting rise in the rate of discount, tend to frighten the
market. The holders of the reserve have, therefore, to treat two opposite maladies at onceone
requiring stringent remedies, and especially a rapid rise in the rate of interest; and the other, an
alleviative treatment with large and ready loans.
Before we had much specific experience, it was not easy to prescribe for this compound disease;
but now we know how to deal with it. We must look first to the foreign drain, and raise the rate of
interest as high as may be necessary. Unless you can stop the foreign export, you cannot allay the
domestic alarm. The Bank will get poorer and poorer, and its poverty will protract or renew the
apprehension. And at the rate of interest so raised, the holdersone or more-of the final Bank reserve
must lend freely. Very large loans at very high rates are the best remedy for the worst malady of the
money market when a foreign drain is added to a domestic drain. Any notion that money is not to be
had, or that it may not be had at any price, only raises alarm to panic and enhances panic to
madness. But though the rule is clear, the greatest delicacy, the finest and best skilled judgment,
are needed to deal at once with such great and contrary evils.
And great as is the delicacy of such a problem in all countries, it is far greater in England now than it
was or is elsewhere. The strain thrown by a panic on the final bank reserve is proportional to the
magnitude of a country's commerce, and to the number and size of the dependent banksbanks, that
is, holding no cash reservethat are grouped around the central bank or banks. And in both respects
our system causes a stupendous strain. The magnitude of our commerce, and the number and
magnitude of the banks which depend on the Bank of England, are undeniable. There are very
many more persons under great liabilities than there are, or ever were, anywhere else. At the
commencement of every panic, all persons under such liabilities try to supply themselves with the
means of meeting those liabilities while they can. This causes a great demand for new loans. And
so far from being able to meet it, the bankers who do not keep an extra reserve at that time borrow
largely, or do not renew large loansvery likely do both.
London bankers, other than the Bank of England, effect this in several ways. First, they have
probably discounted bills to a large amount for the bill brokers, and if these bills are paid, they
decline discounting any others to replace them. The directors of the London and Westminster Bank
had, in the panic of 1857, discounted millions of such bills, and they justly said that if those bills
were paid they would have an amount of cash far more than sufficient for any demand.
(2)
But how
were those bills to be paid? Some one else must lend the money to pay them. The mercantile
community could not on a sudden bear to lose so large a sum of borrowed money; they have been
used to rely on it, and they could not carry on their business without it. Least of all could they bear it
at the beginning of a panic, when everybody wants more money than usual. Speaking broadly,
those bills can only be paid by the discount of other bills. When the bills (suppose) of a Manchester
warehouseman which he gave to the manufacturer become due, he cannot, as a rule, pay for them
at once in cash; he has bought on credit, and he has sold on credit. He is but a middleman. To pay
his own bill to the maker of the goods, he must discount the bills he has received from the
shopkeepers to whom he has sold the goods; but if there is a sudden cessation in the means of
discount, he will not be able to discount them. All our mercantile community must obtain new loans
to pay old debts. If some one else did not pour into the market the money which the banks like the
London and Westminster Bank take out of it, the bills held by the London and Westminster Bank
could not be paid.
Who then is to pour in the new money? Certainly not the bill brokers. They have been used to re-
discount with such banks as the London and Westminster millions of bills, and if they see that they
are not likely to be able to re-discount those bills, they instantly protect themselves and do not
discount them. Their business does not allow them to keep much cash unemployed. They give
interest for all the money deposited with theman interest often nearly approaching the interest they
can charge; as they can only keep a small reserve a panic tells on them more quickly than on
anyone else. They stop their discounts, or much diminish their discounts, immediately. There is no
new money to be had from them, and the only place at which they can have it is the Bank of
England.
There is even a simpler case: the banker who is uncertain of his credit, and wants to increase his
cash, may have money on deposit at the bill brokers. If he wants to replenish his reserve, he may
ask for it, suppose, just when the alarm is beginning. But if a great number of persons do this very
suddenly, the bill brokers will not at once be able to pay without borrowing. They have excellent bills
in their case, but these will not be due for some days; and the demand from the more or less
alarmed bankers is for payment at once and to-day. Accordingly the bill broker takes refuge at the
Bank of England the only place where at such a moment new money is to be had.
The case is just the same if the banker wants to sell Consols, or to call in money lent on Consols.
These he reckons as part of his reserve. And in ordinary times nothing can be better. According to
the saying, you `can sell Consols on a Sunday.' In a time of no alarm, or in any alarm affecting that
particular banker only, he can rely on such reserve without misgiving. But not so in a general panic.
Then, if he wants to sell 500,000 l. worth of Consols, he will not find 500,000 l. of fresh money ready
to come into the market. All ordinary bankers are wanting to sell, or thinking they may have to sell.
The only resource is the Bank of England. In a great panic, Consols cannot be sold unless the Bank
of England will advance to the buyer, and no buyer can obtain advances on Consols at such a time
unless the Bank of England will lend to him.
The case is worse if the alarm is not confined to the great towns, but is diffused through the country.
As a rule, country bankers only keep so much barren cash as is necessary for their common
business. All the rest they leave at the bill brokers, or at the interest-giving banks, or invest in
Consols and such securities. But in a panic they come to London and want this money. And it is only
from the Bank of England that they can get it, for all the rest of London want their money for
themselves.
If we remember that the liabilities of Lombard Street payable on demand are far larger than those of
any like market, and that the liabilities of the country are greater still, we can conceive the
magnitude of the pressure on the Bank of England when both Lombard Street and the country
suddenly and at once come upon it for aid. No other bank was ever exposed to a demand so
formidable, for none ever before kept the banking reserve for such a nation as the English. The
mode in which the Bank of England meets this great responsibility is very curious. It unquestionably
does make enormous advances in every panic
£ £
In 1847 the loans on `private securities' increased from 18,963,000 to 20,409,000
1857 ditto ditto 20,404,000 to 31,350,000
1866 ditto ditto 18,507,000 to 33,447,000
But, on the other hand, as we have seen, though the Bank, more or less, does its duty, it does not
distinctly acknowledge that it is its duty. We are apt to be solemnly told that the Banking Department
of the Bank of England is only a bank like other banksthat it has no peculiar duty in times of
panicthat it then is to look to itself alone, as other banks look. And there is this excuse for the Bank.
Hitherto questions of banking have been so little discussed in comparison with questions of
currency, that the duty of the Bank in time of panic has been put on a wrong ground.
It is imagined that because bank notes are a legal tender, the Bank has some peculiar duty to help
other people. But bank notes are only a legal tender at the Issue Department, not at the Banking
Department, and the accidental combination of the two departments in the same building gives the
Banking Department no aid in meeting a panic. If the Issue Department were at Somerset House,
and if it issued Government notes there, the position of the Banking Department under the present
law would be exactly what it is now. No doubt, formerly the Bank of England could issue what it
pleased, but that historical reminiscence makes it no stronger now that it can no longer so issue. We
must deal with what is, not with what was.
And a still worse argument is also used. It is said that because the Bank of England keeps the
`State account' and is the Government banker, it is a sort of `public institution' and ought to help
everybody. But the custody of the taxes which have been collected and which wait to be expended
is a duty quite apart from panics. The Government money may chance to be much or little when the
panic comes. There is no relation or connection between the two. And the State, in getting the Bank
to keep what money it may chance to have, or in borrowing of it what money it may chance to want,
does not hire it to stop a panic or much help it if it tries.
The real reason has not been distinctly seen. As has been already saidbut on account of its
importance and perhaps its novelty it is worth saying againwhatever bank or banks keep the
ultimate banking reserve of the country must lend that reserve most freely in time of apprehension,
for that is one of the characteristic uses of the bank reserve, and the mode in which it attains one of
the main ends for which it is kept. Whether rightly or wrongly, at present and in fact the Bank of
England keeps our ultimate bank reserve, and therefore it must use it in this manner.
And though the Bank of England certainly do make great advances in time of panic, yet as they do
not do so on any distinct principle, they naturally do it hesitatingly, reluctantly, and with misgiving. In
1847, even in 1866the latest panic, and the one in which on the whole the Bank acted the bestthere
was nevertheless an instant when it was believed the Bank would not advance on Consols, or at
least hesitated to advance on them. The moment this was reported in the City and telegraphed to
the country, it made the panic indefinitely worse. In fact, to make large advances in this faltering way
is to incur the evil of making them without obtaining the advantage. What is wanted and what is
necessary to stop a panic is to diffuse the impression, that though money may be dear, still money
is to be had. If people could be really convinced that they could have money if they wait a day or
two, and that utter ruin is not coming, most likely they would cease to run in such a mad way for
money. Either shut the Bank at once, and say it will not lend more than it commonly lends, or lend
freely, boldly, and so that the public may feel you mean to go on lending. To lend a great deal, and
yet not give the public confidence that you will lend sufficiently and effectually, is the worst of all
policies; but it is the policy now pursued.
In truth, the Bank do not lend from the motives which should make a bank lend. The holders of the
Bank reserve ought to lend at once and most freely in an incipient panic, because they fear
destruction in the panic. They ought not to do it to serve others; they ought to do it to serve
themselves. They ought to know that this bold policy is the only safe one, and for that reason they
ought to choose it. But the Bank directors are not afraid. Even at the last moment they say that
`whatever happens to the community, they can preserve themselves.' Both in 1847 and 1857 (I
believe also in 1866, though there is no printed evidence of it) the Bank directors contended that the
Banking Department was quite safe though its reserve was nearly all gone, and that it could
strengthen itself by selling securities and by refusing to discount. But this is a complete dream. The
Bank of England could not sell `securities,' for in an extreme panic there is no one else to buy
securities. The Bank cannot stay still and wait till its bills are paid, and so fill its coffers, for unless it
discounts equivalent bills, the bills which it has already discounted will not be paid. `When the
reserve in the ultimate bank or banksthose keeping the reserveruns low, it cannot be augmented by
the same means that other and dependent banks commonly adopt to maintain their reserve, for the
dependent banks trust that at such moments the ultimate banks will be discounting more than usual
and lending more than usual. But ultimate banks have no similar rear-guard to rely upon.
I shall have failed in my purpose if I have not proved that the system of entrusting all our reserve to
a single board, like that of the Bank directors, is very anomalous; that it is very dangerous; that its
bad consequences, though much felt, have not been fully seen; that they have been obscured by
traditional arguments and hidden in the dust of ancient controversies.
But it will be saidWhat would be better? What other system could there be? We are so accustomed
to a system of banking, dependent for its cardinal function on a single bank, that we can hardly
conceive of any other. But the natural systemthat which would have sprung up if Government had let
banking aloneis that of many banks of equal or not altogether unequal size. In all other trades
competition brings the traders to a rough approximate equality. In cotton spinning, no single firm far
and permanently outstrips the others. There is no tendency to a monarchy in the cotton world; nor,
where banking has been left free, is there any tendency to a monarchy in banking either. In
Manchester, in Liverpool, and all through England, we have a great number of banks, each with a
business more or less good, but we have no single bank with any sort of predominance; nor is there
any such bank in Scotland. In the new world of Joint Stock Banks outside the Bank of England, we
see much the same phenomenon. One or more get for a time a better business than the others, but
no single bank permanently obtains an unquestioned predominance. None of them gets so much
before the others that the others voluntarily place their reserves in its keeping. A republic with many
competitors of a size or sizes suitable to the business, is the constitution of every trade if left to
itself, and of banking as much as any other. A monarchy in any trade is a sign of some anomalous
advantage, and of some intervention from without.
I shall be at once askedDo you propose a revolution? Do you propose to abandon the one-reserve
system, and create anew a many-reserve system? My plain answer is that I do not propose it. I
know it would be childish. Credit in business is like loyalty in Government. You must take what you
can find of it, and work with it if possible. A theorist may easily map out a scheme of Government in
which Queen Victoria could be dispensed with. He may make a theory that, since we admit and we
know that the House of Commons is the real sovereign, any other sovereign is superfluous; but for
practical purposes, it is not even worth while to examine these arguments. Queen Victoria is loyally
obeyedwithout doubt, and without reasoningby millions of human beings. If those millions began to
argue, it would not be easy to persuade them to obey Queen Victoria, or anything else. Effectual
arguments to convince the people who need convincing are wanting. Just so, an immense system of
credit, founded on the Bank of England as its pivot and its basis, now exists. The English people,
and foreigners too, trust it implicitly. Every banker knows that if he has to prove that he is worthy of
credit, however good may be his arguments, in fact his credit is gone: but what we have requires no
proof. The whole rests on an instinctive confidence generated by use and years. Nothing would
persuade the English people to abolish the Bank of England; and if some calamity swept it away,
generations must elapse before at all the same trust would be placed in any other equivalent. A
many-reserve system, if some miracle should put it down in Lombard Street, would seem monstrous
there. Nobody would understand it, or confide in it. Credit is a power which may grow, but cannot be
constructed. Those who live under a great and firm system of credit must consider that if they break
up that one they will never see another, for it wrn take years upon years to make a successor to it.
On this account, I do not suggest that we should return to a natural or many-reserve system of
banking. I should only incur useless ridicule if I did suggest it. Nor can I propose that we should
adopt the simple and straightforward expedient by which the French have extricated themselves
from the same difficulty. In France all banking rests on the Bank of France, even more than in
England all rests on the Bank of England. The Bank of France keeps the final banking reserve, and
it keeps the currency reserve too. But the State does not trust such a function to a board of
merchants, named by shareholders. The nation itselfthe Executive Governmentnames the governor
and deputy-governor of the Bank of France. These officers have, indeed, beside them a council of
`regents,' or directors, named by the shareholders. But they need not attend to that council unless
they think fit; they are appointed to watch over the national interest, and, in so doing, they may
disregard the murmurs of the `regents' if they like. And in theory, there is much to be said for this
plan. The keeping the single banking reserve being a national function, it is at least plausible to
argue that Government should choose the functionaries. No doubt such a political intervention is
contrary to the sound economical doctrine that `banking is a trade, and only a trade.' But
Government forgot that doctrine when, by privileges and monopolies, it made a single bank
predominant over all others, and established the one-reserve system. As that system exists, a
logical Frenchman consistently enough argues that the State should watch and manage it. But no
such plan would answer in England. We have not been trained to care for logical sequence in our
institutions, or rather we have been trained not to care for it. And the practical result for which we do
care would in this case be bad. The governor of the Bank would be a high Parliamentary official,
perhaps in the Cabinet, and would change as chance majorities and the strength of parties decide.
A trade peculiarly requiring consistency and special attainment would be managed by a shifting and
untrained ruler. In fact, the whole plan would seem to an Englishman of business palpably absurd;
he would not consider it, he would not think it worth considering. That it works fairly well in France,
and that there are specious arguments of theory for it, would not be sufficient to his mind.
All such changes being out of the question, I can propose only three remedies.
First. There should be a clear understanding between the Bank and the public that, since the Bank
hold out ultimate banking reserve, they will recognise and act on the obligations which this implies;
that they will replenish it in times of foreign demand as fully, and Lend it in times of internal panic as
freely and readily, as plain principles of banking require.
This looks very different from the French plan, but it is not so different in reality. In England we can
often effect, by the indirect compulsion of opinion, what other countries must effect by the direct
compulsion of Government. We can do so in this case. The Bank directors now fear public opinion
exceedingly; probably no kind of persons are so sensitive to newspaper criticism. And this is very
natural. Our statesmen, it is true, are much more blamed, but they have generally served a long
apprenticeship to sharp criticism. If they still care for it (and some do after years of experience much
more than the world thinks), they care less for it than at first, and have come to regard it as an
unavoidable and incessant irritant, of which they shall never be rid. But a bank director undergoes
no similar training and hardening. His functions at the Bank fill a very small part of his time; all the
rest of his life (unless he be in Parliament) is spent in retired and mercantile industry. He is not
subjected to keen and public criticism, and is not taught to bear it. Especially when once in his life
he becomes, by rotation, governor, he is most anxious that the two years of office shall `go off well.'
He is apt to be irritated even by objections to principles on which he acts, and cannot bear with
equanimity censure which is pointed and personal. At present I am not sure if this sensitiveness is
beneficial. As the exact position of the Bank of England in the Money Market is indistinctly seen,
there is no standard to which a Bank governor can appeal. He is always in fear that `something may
be said;' but not quite knowing on what side that `something' may be, his fear is but an indifferent
guide to him. But if the cardinal doctrine were accepted, if it were acknowledged that the Bank is
charged with the custody of our sole banking reserve, and is bound to deal with it according to
admitted principles, then a governor of the Bank could look to those principles. He would know
which way criticism was coming. If he was guided by the code, he would have a plain defence. And
then we may be sure that old men of business would not deviate from the code. At present the
Board of Directors are a sort of semi-trustees for the nation. I would have them real trustees, and
with a good trust deed.
Secondly. The government of the Bank should be improved in a manner to be explained. We should
diminish the `amateur' element; we should augment the trained banking element; and we should
ensure more constancy in the administration.
Thirdly. As these two suggestions are designed to make the Bank as strong as possible, we should
look at the rest of our banking system, and try to reduce the demands on the Bank as much as we
can. The central machinery being inevitably frail, we should carefully and as much as possible
diminish the strain upon it.
But to explain these proposals, and to gain a full understanding of many arguments that have been
used, we must look more in detail at the component parts of Lombard street, and at the curious set
of causes which have made it assume its present singular structure.
CHAPTER III - How Lombard Street Came to Exist, and Why It Assumed Its Present Form
In the last century, a favourite subject of literary ingenuity was `conjectural history,' as it was then
called. Upon grounds of probability a fictitious sketch was made of the possible origin of things
existing. If this kind of speculation were now applied to banking, the natural and first idea would be
that large systems of deposit banking grew up in the early world, just as they grow up now in any
large English colony. As soon as any such community becomes rich enough to have much money,
and compact enough to be able to lodge its money in single banks, it at once begins so to do.
English colonists do not like the risk of keeping their money, and they wish to make an interest on it.
They carry from home the idea and the habit of banking, and they take to it as soon as they can in
their new world. Conjectural history would be inclined to say that all banking began thus: but such
history is rarely of any value. The basis of it is false. It assumes that what works most easily when
established is that which it would be the most easy to establish, and that what seems simplest when
familiar would be most easily appreciated by the mind though unfamiliar. But exactly the contrary is
true. Many things which seem simple and which work well when firmly established, are very hard to
establish among new people, and not very easy to explain to them. Deposit banking is of this sort.
Its essence is that a very large number of persons agree to trust a very few persons, or some one
person. Banking would not be a profitable trade if bankers were not a small number, and depositors
in comparison an immense number. But to get a great number of persons to do exactly the same
thing is always very difficult, and nothing but a very palpable necessity will make them on a sudden
begin to do it. And there is no such palpable necessity in banking. If you take a country town in
France, even now, you will not find any such system of banking as ours. Cheque-books are
unknown, and money kept on running account by bankers is rare. People store their money in a
caisse at their houses. Steady savings, which are waiting for investment, and which are sure not to
be soon wanted, may be lodged with bankers; but the common floating cash of the community is
kept by the community themselves at home. They prefer to keep it so, and it would not answer a
banker's purpose to make expensive arrangements for keeping it otherwise. If a `branch,' such as
the National Provincial Bank opens in an English country town, were opened in a corresponding
French one, it would not pay its expenses. You could not get any sufficient number of Frenchmen to
agree to put their money there. And so it is in all countries not of British descent, though in various
degrees. Deposit banking is a very difficult thing to begin, because people do not like to let their
money out of their sight, especially do not like to let it out of sight without securitystill more, cannot
all at once agree on any single person to whom they are content to trust it unseen and unsecured.
Hypothetical history, which explains the past by. what is simplest and commonest in the present, is
in banking, as in most things, quite untrue.
The real history is very different. New wants are mostly supplied by adaptation, not by creation or
foundation. Something having been created to satisfy an extreme want, it is used to satisfy less
pressing wants, or to supply additional conveniences. On this account, political Governmentthe
oldest institution in the worldhas been the hardest worked. At the beginning of history, we find it
doing everything which society wants done, and forbidding everything which society does not wish
done. In trade, at present, the first commerce in a new place is a general shop, which, beginning
with articles of real necessity, comes shortly to supply the oddest accumulation of petty comforts.
And the history of banking has been the same. The first banks were not founded for our system of
deposit banking, or for anything like it. They were founded for much more pressing reasons, and
having been founded, they, or copies from them, were applied to our modern uses.
The earliest banks of Italy, where the name began, were finance companies. The Bank of St.
George, at Genoa, and other banks founded in imitation of it, were at first only companies to make
loans to, and float loans for, the Governments of the cities in which they were formed. The want of
money is an urgent want of Governments at most periods, and seldom more urgent than it was in
the tumultuous Italian Republics of the Middle Ages. After these banks had been long established,
they began to do what we call banking business; but at first they never thought of it. The great banks
of the North of Europe had their origin in a want still more curious. The notion of its being a prime
business of a bank to give good coin has passed out of men's memories; but wherever it is felt,
there is no want of business more keen and urgent. Adam Smith describes it so admirably that it
would be stupid not to quote his words:`The currency of a great state, such as France or England,
generally consists almost entirely of its own coin. Should this currency, therefore, be at any time
worn, clipt, or otherwise degraded below its standard value, the state by a reformation of its coin can
effectually re-establish its currency. But the currency of a small state, such as Genoa or Hamburgh,
can seldom consist altogether in its own coin, but must be made up, in a great measure, of the coins
of all the neighbouring states with which its inhabitants have a continual intercourse. Such a state,
therefore, by reforming its coin, will not always be able to reform its currency. If foreign bills of
exchange are paid in this currency, the uncertain value of any sum, of what is in its own nature so
uncertain, must render the exchange always very much against such a state, its currency being, in
all foreign states, necessarily valued even below what it is worth.
`In order to remedy the inconvenience to which this disadvantageous exchange must have
subjected their merchants, such small states, when they began to attend to the interest of trade,
have frequently enacted, that foreign bills of exchange of a certain value should be paid, not in
common currency, but by an order upon, or by a transfer in, the books of a certain bank, established
upon the credit, and under the protection of the state, this bank being always obliged to pay, in good
and true money, exactly according to the standard of the state. The banks of Venice, Genoa,
Amsterdam, Hamburgh and Nuremburg, seem to have been all originally established with this view,
though some of them may have afterwards been made subservient to other purposes. The money of
such banks, being better than the common currency of the country, necessarily bore an agio, which
was greater or smaller, according as the currency was supposed to be more or less degraded below
the standard of the state. The agio of the bank of Hamburgh, for example, which is said to be
commonly about fourteen per cent, is the supposed difference between the good standard money of
the state, and the clipt, worn, and diminished currency poured into it from all the neighbouring
states.
`Before 1609 the great quantity of clipt and worn foreign coin, which the extensive trade of
Amsterdam brought from all parts of Europe, reduced the value of its currency about 9 per cent
below that of good money fresh from the mint. Such money no sooner appeared than it was melted
down or carried away, as it always is in such circumstances. The merchants, with plenty of currency,
could not always find a sufficient quantity of good money to pay their bills of exchange; and the
value of those bills, in spite of several regulations which were made to prevent it, became in a great
measure uncertain.
`In order to remedy these inconveniences, a bank was established in 1609 under the guarantee of
the City. This bank received both foreign coin, and the light and worn coin of the country at its real
intrinsic value in the good standard money of the country, deducting only so much as was necessary
for defraying the expense of coinage, and the other necessary expense of management. For the
value which remained, after this small deduction was made, it gave a credit in its books. This credit
was called bank money, which, as it represented money exactly according to the standard of the
mint, was always of the same real value, and intrinsically worth more than current money. It was at
the same time enacted, that all bills drawn upon or negotiated at Amsterdam of the value of six
hundred guilders and upwards should be paid in bank money, which at once took away all
uncertainty in the value of those bills. Every merchant, in consequence of this regulation, was
obliged to keep an account with the bank in order to pay his foreign bills of exchange, which
necessarily occasioned a certain demand for bank money.'
(3)
Again, a most important function of early banks is one which the present banks retain, though it is
subsidiary to their main use; viz. the function of remitting money. A man brings money to the bank to
meet a payment which he desires to make at a great distance, and the bank, having a connection
with other banks, sends it where it is wanted. As soon as bills of exchange are given upon a large
scale, this remittance is a very pressing requirement. Such bills must be made payable at a place
convenient to the seller of the goods in payment of which they are given, perhaps at the great town
where his warehouse is. But this may be very far from the retail shop of the buyer who bought those
goods to sell them again in the country. For these, and a multitude of purposes, the instant and
regular remittance of money is an early necessity of growing trade; and that remittance it was a first
object of early banks to accomplish.
These are all uses other than those of deposit banking which banks supplied that afterwards
became in our English sense deposit banks. By supplying these uses, they gained the credit that
afterwards enabled them to gain a living as deposit banks. Being trusted for one purpose, they
came to be trusted for a purpose quite different, ultimately far more important, though at first less
keenly pressing. But these wants only affect a few persons, and therefore bring the bank under the
notice of a few only. The real introductory function which deposit banks at first perform is much
more popular, and it is only when they can perform this more popular kind of business that deposit
banking ever spreads quickly and extensively. This function is the supply of the paper circulation to
the country, and it will be observed that I am not about to overstep my limits and discuss this as a
question of currency. In what form the best paper currency can be supplied to a country is a
question of economical theory with which I do not meddle here. I am only narrating unquestionable
history, not dealing with an argument where every step is disputed. And part of this certain history is
that the best way to diffuse banking in a community is to allow the banker to issue banknotes of
small amount that can supersede the metal currency. This amounts to a subsidy to each banker to
enable him to keep open a bank till depositors choose to come to it. The country where deposit
banking is most diffused is Scotland, and there the original profits were entirely derived from the
circulation. The note issue is now a most trifling part of the liabilities of the Scotch banks, but it was
once their mainstay and source of profit. A curious book, lately published, has enabled us to follow
the course of this in detail. The Bank of Dundee, now amalgamated with the Royal Bank of
Scotland, was founded in 1763, and had become before its amalgamation, eight or nine years since,
a bank of considerable deposits. But for twenty-five years from its foundation it had no deposits at
all. It subsisted mostly on its note issue, and a little on its remittance business. Only in 1792, after
nearly thirty years, it began to gain deposits, but from that time they augmented very rapidly.
(4)
The
banking history of England has been the same, though we have no country bank accounts in detail
which go back so far. But probably up to 1830 in England, or thereabouts, the main profit of banks
was derived from the circulation, and for many years after that the deposits were treated as very
minor matters, and the whole of so-called banking discussion turned on questions of circulation. We
are still living in the dèbris of that controversy, for, as I have so often said, people can hardly think of
the structure of Lombard Street, except with reference to the paper currency and to the Act of 1844,
which regulates it now. The French are still in the same epoch of the subject. The great enquête of
1865 is almost wholly taken up with currency matters, and mere banking is treated as subordinate.
And the accounts of the Bank of France show why. The last weekly statement before the German
war showed that the circulation of the Bank of France was as much as 59,244,000 l., and that the
private deposits were only 17,127,000 l. Now the private deposits are about the same, and the
circulation is 112,000,000 l. So difficult is it in even a great country like France for the deposit
system of banking to take root, and establish itself with the strength and vigour that it has in
England.
The experience of Germany is the same. The accounts preceding the war in North Germany
showed the circulation of the issuing banks to be 39,875,000 l., and the deposits to be 6,472,000 l.
while the corresponding figures at the present moment arecirculation, 60,000,000 l. and deposits
8,000,000 l. It would be idle to multiply Instances.
The reason why the use of bank paper commonly precedes the habit of making deposits in banks is
very plain. It is a far easier habit to establish. In the issue of notes the banker, the person to be most
benefited, can do something. He can pay away his own `promises' in loans, in wages, or in payment
of debts. But in the getting of deposits he is passive. His issues depend on himself; his deposits on
the favour of others. And to the public the change is far easier too. To collect a great mass of
deposits with the same banker, a great number of persons must agree to do something. But to
establish a note circulation, a large number of persons need only do nothing. They receive the
banker's notes in the common course of their business, and they have only not to take those notes
to the banker for payment. If the public refrain from taking trouble, a paper circulation is immediately
in existence. A paper circulation is begun by the banker, and requires no effort on the part of the
public; on the contrary, it needs an effort of the public to be rid of notes once issued; but deposit
banking cannot be begun by the banker, and requires a spontaneous and consistent effort in the
community. And therefore paper issue is the natural prelude to deposit banking.
The way in which the issue of notes by a banker prepares the way for the deposit of money with him
is very plain. When a private person begins to possess a great heap of bank-notes, it will soon strike
him that he is trusting the banker very much, and that in re turn he is getting nothing. He runs the
risk of loss and robbery just as if he were hoarding coin. He would run no more risk by the failure of
the bank if he made a deposit there, and he would be free from the risk of keeping the cash. No
doubt it takes time before even this simple reasoning is understood by uneducated minds. So strong
is the wish of most people to see their money that they for some time continue to hoard bank-notes:
for a long period a few do so. But in the end common sense conquers. The circulation of bank-notes
decreases, and the deposit of money with the banker increases. The credit of the banker having
been efficiently advertised by the note, and accepted by the public, he lives on the credit so gained
years after the note issue itself has ceased to be very important to him.
The efficiency of this introduction is proportional to the diffusion of the right of note issue. A single
monopolist issuer, like the Bank of France, works its way with difficulty through a country, and
advertises banking very slowly. Even now the Bank of France, which, I believe, by law ought to have
a branch in each Department, has only branches in sixty out of eighty-six. On the other hand, the
Swiss banks, where there is always one or more to every Canton, diffuse banking rapidly. We have
seen that the liabilities of the Bank of France stand thus:
Notes
£ 112,000,000
Deposits £15,000,000
But the aggregate Swiss banks, on the contrary, stand:
Notes £ 761,000
Deposits £4,709,000
(5)
The reason is that a central bank which is governed in the capital and descends on a country
district, has much fewer modes of lending money safely than a bank of which the partners belong to
that district, and know the men and things in it. A note issue is mainly begun by loans; there are then
no deposits to be paid. But the mass of loans in a rural district are of small amount; the bills to be
discounted are trifling; the persons borrowing are of small means and only local repute; the value of
any property they wish to pledge depends on local changes and local circumstances. A banker who
lives in the district, who has always lived there, whose whole mind is a history of the district and its
changes, is easily able to lend money safely there. But a manager deputed by a single central
establishment does so with difficulty. The worst people will come to him and ask for loans. His
ignorance is a mark for all the shrewd and crafty people thereabouts. He will have endless
difficulties in establishing the circulation of the distant bank, because he has not the local knowledge
which alone can teach him how to issue that circulation with safety.
A system of note issues is therefore the best introduction to a large system of deposit banking. As
yet, historically, it is the only introduction: no nation as yet has arrived at a great system of deposit
banking without going first through the preliminary stage of note issue, and of such note issues the
quickest and most efficient in this way is one made by individuals resident in the district, and
conversant with it.
And this explains why deposit banking is so rare. Such a note issue as has been described is
possible only in a country exempt from invasion, and free from revolution. During an invasion note-
issuing banks must stop payment; a run is nearly inevitable at such a time, and in a revolution too.
In such great and close civil dangers a nation is always demoralised; everyone looks to himself, and
everyone likes to possess himself of the precious metals. These are sure to be valuable, invasion or
no invasion, revolution or no revolution. But the goodness of bank-notes depends on the solvency of
the banker, and that solvency may be impaired if the invasion is not repelled or the revolution
resisted.
Hardly any continental country has been till now exempt for long periods both from invasion and
revolution. In Holland and Germanytwo countries where note issue and deposit banking would seem
as natural as in England and Scotlandthere was never any security from foreign war. A profound
apprehension of external invasion penetrated their whole habits, and men of business would have
thought it insane not to contemplate a contingency so frequent in their history, and perhaps
witnessed by themselves.
France indeed, before 1789, was an exception. For many years under the old régime she was
exempt from serious invasion or attempted revolution. Her Government was fixed, as was then
thought, and powerful; it could resist any external enemy, and the prestige on which it rested
seemed too firm to fear any enemy from within. But then it was not an honest Government, and it
had shown its dishonesty in this particular matter of note issue. The regent in Law's time had given
a monopoly of note issue to a bad bank, and had paid off the debts of the nation in worthiess paper.
The Government had created a machinery of ruin, and had thriven on it. Among so apprehensive a
race as the French the result was fatal. For many years no attempt at note issue or deposit banking
was possible in France. So late as the foundation of the Caisse d'Escompte, in Turgot's time, the
remembrance of Law's failure was distinctly felt, and impeded the commencement of better
attempts.
This therefore is the reason why Lombard Street exists; that is, why England is a very great Money
Market, and other European countries but small ones in comparison. In England and Scotland a
diffused system of note issues started banks all over the country; in these banks the savings of the
country have been lodged, and by these they have been sent to London. No similar system arose
elsewhere, and in consequence London is full of money, and all continental cities are empty as
compared with it.
II.
The monarchical form of Lombard Street is due also to the note issue. The origin of the Bank of
England has been told by Macaulay, and it is never wise for an ordinary writer to tell again what he
has told so much better. Nor is it necessary, for his writings are in everyone s hands. Still I must
remind my readers of the curious story.
Of all institutions in the world the Bank of England is now probably the most remote from party
politics and from `financing.' But in its origin it was not only a finance company, but a Whig finance
company. It was founded by a Whig Government because it was in desperate want of money, and
supported by the `City' because the `City' was Whig. Very briefly, the story was this. The
Government of Charles II. (under the Cabal Ministry) had brought the credit of the English State to
the lowest possible point. It had perpetrated one of those monstrous frauds, which are likewise
gross blunders. The goldsmiths, who then carried on upon a trifling scale what we should now call
banking, used to deposit their reserve of treasure in the `Exchequer,' with the sanction and under
the care of the Government. In many European countries the credit of the State had been so much
better than any other credit, that it had been used to strengthen the beginnings of banking. The
credit of the state had been so used in England: though there had lately been a civil war and several
revolutions, the honesty of the English Government was trusted implicitly. But Charles II. showed
that it was trusted undeservedly. He shut up the `Exchequer,' would pay no one, and so the
`goldsmiths' were ruined.
The credit of the Stuart Government never recovered from this monstrous robbery, and the
Government created by the Revolution of 1688 could hardly expect to be more trusted with money
than its predecessor. A Government created by a revolution hardly ever is. There is a taint of
violence which capitalists dread instinctively, and there is always a rational apprehension that the
Government which one revolution thought fit to set up another revolution may think fit to pull down.
In 1694, the credit of William III.'s Government was so low in London that it was impossible for it to
borrow any large sum; and the evil was the greater, because in consequence of the French war the
financial straits of the Government were extreme. At last a scheme was hit upon which would relieve
their necessities. `The plan,' says Macaulay, `was that twelve hundred thousand pounds should be
raised at what was then considered as the moderate rate of 8 per cent.' In order to induce the
subscribers to advance the money promptly on terms so unfavourable to the public, the subscribers
were to be incorporated by the name of the Governor and Company of the Bank of England. They
were so incorporated, and the 1,200,000 l. was obtained.
On many succeeding occasions, their credit was of essential use to the Government. Without their
aid, our National Debt could not have been borrowed; and if we had not been able to raise that
money we should have been conquered by France and compelled to take back James II. And for
many years afterwards the existence of that debt was a main reason why the industrial classes
never would think of recalling the Pretender, or of upsetting the revolution settlement. The `fund-
holder' is always considered in the books of that time as opposed to his `legitimate' sovereign,
because it was to be feared that this sovereign would repudiate the debt which was raised by those
who dethroned him, and which was spent in resisting him and his allies. For a long time the Bank of
England was the focus of London Liberalism, and in that capacity rendered to the State inestimable
services. In return for these substantial benefits the Bank of England received from the Government,
either at first or afterwards, three most important privileges.
First. The Bank of England had the exclusive possession of the Government balances. In its first
period, as I have shown, the Bank gave credit to the Government, but afterwards it derived credit
from the Government. There is a natural tendency in men to follow the example of the Government
under which they live. The Government is the largest, most important, and most conspicuous entity
with which the mass of any people are acquainted; its range of knowledge must always be infinitely
greater than the average of their knowledge, and therefore, unless there is a conspicuous warning
to the contrary, most men are inclined to think their Government right, and, when they can, to do
what it does. Especially in money matters a man might fairly reason'If the Government is right in
trusting the Bank of England with the great balance of the nation, I cannot be wrong in trusting it with
my little balance.'
Second. The Bank of England had, till lately, the monopoly of limited liability in England. The
common law of England knows nothing of any such principle. It is only possible by Royal Charter or
Statute Law. And by neither of these was any real bank (I do not count absurd schemes such as
Chamberlayne's Land Bank) permitted with limited liability in England till within these few years.
Indeed, a good many people thought it was right for the Bank of England, but not right for any other
bank. I remember hearing the conversation of a distinguished merchant in the City of London, who
well represented the ideas then most current He was declaiming against banks of limited liability,
and some one asked'Why, what do you say, then, to the Bank of England, where you keep your
own account?' `Oh!' he replied, `that is an exceptional case.' And no doubt it was an exception of
the greatest value to the Bank of England, because it induced many quiet and careful merchants to
be directors of the Bank, who certainly would not have joined any bank where all their fortunes were
liable, and where the liability was not limited.
Thirdly. The Bank of England had the privilege of being the sole joint stock company permitted to
issue bank notes in England. Private London bankers did indeed issue notes down to the middle of
the last century, but no joint stock company could do so. The explanatory clause of the Act of 1742
sounds most curiously to our modern ears. `And to prevent any doubt that may arise concerning the
privilege or power given to the said governor and company' that is, the Bank of England'OF
EXCLUSIVE BANKING; and also in regard to creating any other bank or banks by Parliament, or
restraining other persons from banking during the continuance of the said privilege granted to the
governor and company of the Bank of England, as before recited;it is hereby further enacted and
declared by the authority aforesaid, that it is the true intent and meaning of the said Act that no other
bank shall be created, established, or allowed by Parliament, and that it shall not be lawful for any
body politic or corporate whatsoever created or to be created, or for any other persons whatsoever
united or to be united in covenants or partnership exceeding the number of six persons in that part
of Great Britain called England, to borrow, owe, or take up any sum or sums of money on their bills
or notes payable on demand or at any less time than six months from the borrowing thereof during
the continuance of such said privilege to the said governor and company, who are hereby declared
to be and remain a corporation with the privilege of exclusive banking, as before recited.' To our
modern ears these words seem to mean more than they did. The term banking was then applied
only to the issue of notes and the taking up of money on bills on demand. Our present system of
deposit banking, in which no bills or promissory notes are issued, was not then known on a great
scale, and was not called banking. But its effect was very important. It in time gave the Bank of
England the monopoly of the note issue of the Metropolis. It had at that time no branches, and so it
did not compete for the country circulation. But in the Metropolis, where it did compete, it was
completely victorious. No company but the Bank of England could issue notes, and unincorporated
individuals gradually gave way, and ceased to do so. Up to 1844 London private bankers might
have issued notes if they pleased, but almost a hundred years ago they were forced out of the field.
The Bank of England has so long had a practical monopoly of the circulation, that it is commonly
believed always to have had a legal monopoly.
And the practical effect of the clause went further: it was believed to make the Bank of England the
only joint stock company that could receive deposits, as well as the only company that could issue
notes. The gift of `exclusive banking' to the Bank of England was read in its most natural modern
sense: it was thought to prohibit any other banking company from carrying on our present system of
banking. After joint stock banking was permitted in the country, people began to inquire why it
should not exist in the Metropolis too? And then it was seen that the words I have quoted only forbid
the issue of negotiable instruments, and not the receiving of money when no such instrument is
given. Upon this construction, the London and Westminster Bank and all our older joint stock banks
were founded. But till they began, the Bank of England had among companies not only the
exclusive privilege of note issue, but that of deposit banking too. It was in every sense the only
banking company in London.
With so many advantages over all competitors, it is quite natural that the Bank of England should
have far outstripped them all. Inevitably it became the bank in London; all the other bankers
grouped themselves round it, and lodged their reserve with it. Thus our one reserve system of
banking was not deliberately founded upon definite reasons; it was the gradual consequence of
many singular events, and of an accumulation of legal privileges on a single bank which has now
been altered, and which no one would now defend.
CHAPTER IV - The Position of the Chancellor of the Exchequer in the Money Market
Nothing can be truer in theory than the economical principle that banking is a trade and only a trade,
and nothing can be more surely established by a larger experience than that a Government which
interferes with any trade injuries that trade. The best thing undeniably that a Government can do
with the Money Market is to let it take care of itself.
But a Government can only carry out this principle universally if it observe one condition: it must
keep its own money. The Government is necessarily at times possessed of large sums in cash. It is
by far the richest corporation in the country; its annual revenue payable in money far surpasses that
of any other body or person. And if it begins to deposit this immense income as it accrues at any
bank, at once it becomes interested in the welfare of that bank. It cannot pay the interest on its debt
if that bank cannot produce the public deposits when that interest becomes due; it cannot pay its
salaries, and defray its miscellaneous expenses, if that bank fail at any time. A modern Government
is like a very rich man with very great debts which he cannot well pay; its credit is necessary to its
prosperity, almost to its existence, and if its banker fail when one of its debts becomes due its
difficulty is intense.
Another banker, it will be said, may take up the Government account. He may advance, as is so
often done in other bank failures, what the Government needs for the moment in order to secure the
Government account in future. But the imperfection of this remedy is that it fails in the very worst
case. In a panic, and at a general collapse of credit, no such banker will probably be found. The old
banker who possesses the Government deposit cannot repay it, and no banker not having that
deposit will, at a bad crisis, be able to find the 5,000,000 l. or 6,000,000 l. which the quarter day of a
Government such as ours requires. If a finance Minister, having entrusted his money to a bank,
begins to act strictly, and say he will in all cases let the Money Market take care of itself, the reply is
that in one case the Money Market will take care of him too, and he will be insolvent.
In the infancy of Banking it is probably much better that a Government should as a rule keep its own
money. If there are not Banks in which it can place secure reliance, it should not seem to rely upon
them. Still less should it give peculiar favour to any one, and by entrusting it with the Government
account secure to it a mischievous supremacy above all other banks. The skill of a financier in such
an age is to equalise the receipt of taxation, and the outgoing of expenditure; it should be a principal
care with him to make sure that more should not be locked up at a particular moment in the
Government coffers than is usually locked up there. If the amount of dead capital so buried in the
Treasury does not at any time much exceed the common average, the evil so caused is
inconsiderable: it is only the loss of interest on a certain sum of money, which would not be much of
a burden on the whole nation; the additional taxation it would cause would be inconsiderable. Such
an evil is nothing in comparison with that of losing the money necessary for inevitable expence by
entrusting it to a bad Bank, or that of recovering this money by identifying the national credit with the
bad Bank and so propping it up and perpetuating it. So long as the security of the Money Market is
not entirely to be relied on, the Goverment of a country had much better leave it to itself and keep its
own money. If the banks are bad, they will certainly continue bad and will probably become worse if
the Government sustains and encourages them. The cardinal maxim is, that any aid to a present
bad Bank is the surest mode of preventing the establishment of a future good Bank.
When the trade of Banking began to be better understood, when the Banking system was
thoroughly secure, the Government might begin to lend gradually; especially to lend the unusually
large sums which even under the most equable system of finance will at times accumulate in the
public exchequer.
Under a natural system of banking it would have every facility. Where there were many banks
keeping their own reserve, and each most anxious to keep a sufficient reserve, because its own life
and credit depended on it, the risk of the Government in keeping a banker would be reduced to a
minimum. It would have the choice of many bankers, and would not be restricted to any one.
Its course would be very simple, and be analogous to that of other public bodies in the country. The
Metropolitan Board of Works, which collects a great revenue in London, has an account at the
London and Westminster Bank, for which that bank makes a deposit of Consols as a security. The
Chancellor of the Exchequer would have no difficulty in getting such security either. If, as is likely,
his account would be thought to be larger than any single bank ought to be entrusted with, the public
deposits might be divided between several. Each would give security, and the whole public money
would be safe. If at any time the floating money in the hands of Government were exceptionally
large, he might require augmented security to be lodged, and he might obtain an interest. He would
be a lender of such magnitude and so much influence, that he might command his own terms. He
might get his account kept safe if anyone could.
If, on the other hand, the Chancellor of the Exchequer were a borrower, as at times he is, he would
have every facility in obtaining what he wanted. The credit of the English Government is so good
that he could borrow better than anyone else in the world. He would have greater facility, indeed,
than now, for, except with the leave of Parliament, the Chancellor of the Exchequer cannot borrow
by our present laws in the open market. He can only borrow from the Bank of England on what are
called `deficiency bills.' In a natural system, he would borrow of any one out of many competing
banks, selecting the one that would lend cheapest; but under our present artificial system, he is
confined to a single bank, which can fix its own charge.
If contrary to expectation a collapse occurred, the Government might withdraw, as the American
Government actually has withdrawn, its balance from the bankers. It might give its aid, lend
Exchequer bills, or otherwise pledge its credit for the moment, but when the exigency was passed it
might let the offending banks suffer. There would be a penalty for their misconduct. New and better
banks, who might take warning from that misconduct, would arise. As in all natural trades, what is
old and, rotten would perish, what is new and good would replace it. And till the new banks had
proved, by good conduct, their fitness for State confidence, the State need not give it. The
Government could use its favour as a bounty on pmdence, and the withdrawal of that favour as a
punishment for culpable folly.
Under a good system of banking, a great collapse, except from rebellion or invasion, would probably
not happen. A large number of banks, each feeling that their credit was at stake in keeping a good
reserve, probably would keep one; if any one did not, it would be criticised constantly, and would
soon lose its standing, and in the end disappear. And such banks would meet an incipient panic
freely, and generously; they would advance out of their reserve boldly and largely, for each
individual bank would fear suspicion, and know that at such periods it must `show strength,' if at
such times it wishes to be thought to have strength. Such a system reduces to a minimum the risk
that is caused by the deposit. If the national money can safely be deposited in banks in any way,
this is the way to make it safe.
But this system is nearly the opposite to that which the law and circumstances have created for us in
England. The English Government, far from keeping cash from the money market till the position of
that market was reasonably secure, at a very early moment, and while credit of all kinds was most
insecure, for its own interests entered into the Money Market. In order to effect loans better, it gave
the custody and profit of its own money (along with other privileges) to a single bank, and therefore
practically and in fact it is identified with the Bank of this hour. It cannot let the money market take
care of itself because it has deposited much money in that market, and it cannot pay its way if it
loses that money.
Nor would any English statesman propose to `wind up' the Bank of England. A theorist might put
such a suggestion on paper, but no responsible government would think of it. At the worst crisis and
in the worst misconduct of the Bank, no such plea has been thought of: in 1825 when its till was
empty, in 1837 when it had to ask aid from the Bank of France, no such idea was suggested. By
irresistible tradition the English Government was obliged to deposit its money in the money market
and to deposit with this particular Bank.
And this system has plain and grave evils.
1st. Because being created by state aid, it is more likely than a natural system to require state help.
2ndly. Because, being a one-reserve system, it reduces the spare cash of the Money Market to a
smaller amount than any other system, and so makes that market more delicate. There being a less
hoard to meet liabilities, any error in the management of that reserve has a proportionately greater
effect.
3rdly. Because, our one reserve is, by the necessity of its nature, given over to one board of
directors, and we are therefore dependent on the wisdom of that one only, and cannot, as in most
trades, strike an average of the wisdom and the folly, the discretion and the indiscretion, of many
competitors.
Lastly. Because that board of directors is, like every other board, pressed on by its shareholders to
make a high dividend, and therefore to keep a small reserve, whereas the public interest
imperatively requires that they shall keep a large one.
These four evils were inseparable from the system, but there is besides an additional and accidental
evil. The English Government not only created this singular system, but it proceeded to impair it,
and demoralise all the public opinion respecting it. For more than a century after its creation
(notwithstanding occasional errors) the Bank of England, in the main, acted with judgment and with
caution. Its business was but small as we should now reckon, but for the most part it conducted that
business with prudence and discretion. In 1696, it had been involved in the most serious difficulties,
and had been obliged to refuse to pay some of its notes. For a long period it was in wholesome
dread of public opinion, and the necessity of retaining public confidence made it cautious. But the
English Government removed that necessity. In 1797, Mr. Pitt feared that he might not be able to
obtain sufficient species for foreign payments, in consequence of the low state of the Bank reserve,
and he therefore required the Bank not to pay in cash. He removed the preservative apprehension
which is the best security of all Banks.
For this reason the period under which the Bank of England did not pay gold for its notesthe period
from 1797 to 1819is always called the period of the Bank restriction. As the Bank during that period
did not perform, and was not compelled by law to perform, its contract of paying its notes in cash, it
might apparently have been well called the period of Bank license. But the word `restriction' was
quite right, and was the only proper word as a description of, the policy of 1797. Mr. Pitt did not say
that the Bank of England need not pay its notes in specie; he `restricted' them from doing so; he
said that they must not.
In consequence, from 1797 to 1844 (when a new era begins), there never was a proper caution on
the part of the Bank directors. At heart they considered that the Bank of England had a kind of
charmed life, and that it was above the ordinary banking anxiety to pay its way. And this feeling was
very natural. A bank of issue, which need not pay its notes in cash, has a charmed life; it can lend
what it wishes, and issue what it likes, with no fear of harm to itself, and with no substantial check
but its own inclination. For nearly a quarter of a century, the Bank of England was such a bank, for
all that time it could not be in any danger. And naturally the public mind was demoralised also. Since
1797, the public have always expected the Government to help the Bank if necessary. I cannot fully
discuss the suspensions of the Act of 1844 in 1847, 1857, and 1866; but indisputably one of their
effects is to make people think that Government will always help the Bank if the Bank is in extremity.
And this is the sort of anticipation which tends to justify itself, and to cause what it expects.
On the whole, therefore, the position of the Chancellor of the Exchequer in our Money Market is that
of one who deposits largely in it, who created it, and who demoralised it. He cannot, therefore,
banish it from his thoughts, or decline responsibility for it. He must arrange his finances so as not to
intensify panics, but to mitigate them. He must aid the Bank of England in the discharge of its duties;
he must not impede or prevent it.
His aid may be most efficient. He is, on finance, the natural exponent of the public opinion of
England. And it is by that opinion that we wish the Bank of England to be guided. Under a natural
system of banking we should have relied on self-interest, but the State prevented that; we now rely
on opinion instead; the public approval is a reward, its disapproval a severe penalty, on the Bank
directors; and of these it is most important that the finance minister should be a sound and felicitous
exponent.
CHAPTER V - The Mode in Which the Value of Money Is Settled in Lombard Street
Many persons believe that the Bank of England has some peculiar power of fixing the value of
money. They see that the Bank of England varies its minimum rate of discount from time to time,
and that, more or less, all other banks follow its lead, and charge much as it charges; and they are
puzzled why this should be. `Money,' as economists teach, `is a commodity, and only a commodity;'
why then, it is asked, is its value fixed in so odd a way, and not the way in which the value of all
other commodities is fixed?
There is at bottom, however, no difficulty in the matter. The value of money is settled, like that of all
other commodities, by supply and demand, and only the form is essentially different. In other
commodities all the large dealers fix their own price; they try to underbid one another, and that
keeps down the price; they try to get as much as they can out of the buyer, and that keeps up the
price. Between the two what Adam Smith calls the higgling of the market settles it. And this is the
most simple and natural mode of doing business, but it is not the only mode. If circumstances make
it convenient another may be adopted. A single large holderespecially if he be by far the greatest
holdermay fix his price, and other dealers may say whether or not they will undersell him, or whether
or not they will ask more than he does. A very considerable holder of an article may, for a time,
vitally affect its value if he lay down the minimum price which he will take, and obstinately adhere to
it. This is the way in which the value of money in Lombard Street is settled. The Bank of England
used to be a predominant, and is still a most important, dealer in money. It lays down the least price
at which alone it will dispose of its stock, and this, for the most part, enables other dealers to obtain
that price, or something near it.
The reason is obvious. At all ordinary moments there is not money enough in Lombard Street to
discount all the bills in Lombard Street without taking some money from the Bank of England. As
soon as the Bank rate is fixed, a great many persons who have bills to discount try how much
cheaper than the Bank they can get these bills discounted. But they seldom can get them
discounted very much cheaper, for if they did everyone would leave the Bank, and the outer market
would have more bills than it could bear.
In practice, when the Bank finds this process beginning, and sees that its business is much
diminishing, it lowers the rate, so as to secure a reasonable portion of the business to itself, and to
keep a fair part of its deposits employed. At Dutch auctions an upset or maximum price used to be
fixed by the seller, and he came down in his bidding till he found a buyer. The value of money is
fixed in Lombard Street in much the same way, only that the upset price is not that of all sellers, but
that of one very important seller, some part of whose supply is essential.
The notion that the Bank of England has a control over the Money Market, and can fix the rate of
discount as it likes, has survived from the old days before 1844, when the Bank could issue as
many notes as it liked. But even then the notion was a mistake. A bank with a monopoly of note
issue has great sudden power in the Money Market, but no permanent power: it can affect the rate
of discount at any particular moment, but it cannot affect the average rate. And the reason is, that
any momentary fall in money, caused by the caprice of such a bank, of itself tends to create an
immediate and equal rise, so that upon an average the value is not altered.
What happens is this. If a bank with a monopoly of note issue suddenly lends (suppose)
2,000,0001. more than usual, it causes a proportionate increase of trade and increase of prices. The
persons to whom that 2,000,000 l. was lent, did not borrow it to lock it up; they borrow it, in the
language of the market, to `operate with'that is, they try to buy with it; and that new attempt to
buythat new demand raises prices. And this rise of prices has three consequences. First. It makes
everybody else want to borrow money. Money is not so efficient in buying as it was, and therefore
operators require more money for the same dealings. If railway stock is 10 per cent dearer this year
than last, a speculator who borrows money to enable him to deal must borrow 0 per cent more this
year than last, and in consequence there is an augmented demand for loans. Secondly. This is an
effectual demand, for the increased price of railway stock enables those who wish it to borrow more
upon it. The common practice is to lend a certain portion of the market value of such securities, and
if that value increases, the amount of the usual loan to be obtained on them increases too. In this
way, therefore, any artificial reduction in the value of money causes a new augmentation of the
demand for money, and thus restores that value to its natural level. In all business this is well known
by experience: a stimulated market soon becomes a tight market, for so sanguine are enterprising
men, that as soon as they get any unusual ease they always fancy that the relaxation is greater than
it is, and speculate till they want more than they can obtain.
In these two ways sudden loans by an issuer of notes, though they may temporarily lower the value
of money, do not lower it permanently, because they generate their own counteraction. And this they
do whether the notes issued are convertible into coin or not. During the period of Bank restriction,
from 1797 to 1819, the Bank of England could not absolutely control the Money Market, any more
than it could after 1819, when it was compelled to pay its notes in coin. But in the case of convertible
notes there is a third effect, which works in the same direction, and works more quickly. A rise of
prices, confined to one country, tends to increase imports, because other countries can obtain more
for their goods if they send them there, and it discourages exports, because a merchant who would
have gained a profit before the rise by buying here to sell again will not gain so much, if any, profit
after that rise. By this augmentation of imports the indebtedness of this country is augmented, and
by this diminution of exports the proportion of that indebtedness which is paid in the usual way is
decreased also. In consequence, there is a larger balance to be paid in bullion; the store in the bank
or banks keeping the reserve is diminished, and the rate of interest must be raised by them to stay
the effiux. And the tightness so produced is often greater than, and always equal to, the preceding
unnatural laxity.
There is, therefore, no ground for believing, as is so common, that the value of money is settled by
different causes than those which affect the value of other commodities, or that the Bank of England
has any despotism in that matter. It has the power of a large holder of money, and no more. Even
formerly, when its monetary powers were greater and its rivals weaker, it had no absolute control. It
was simply a large corporate dealer, making bids and much influencing though in no sense
compellingother dealers thereby.
But though the value of money is not settled in an exceptional way, there is nevertheless a
peculiarity about it, as there is about many articles. It is a commodity subject to great fluctuations of
value, and those fluctuations are easily produced by a slight excess or a slight deficiency of quantity.
Up to a certain point money is a necessity. If a merchant has acceptances to meet to-morrow,
money he must and will find today at some price or other. And it is this urgent need of the whole
body of merchants which runs up the value of money so wildly and to such a height in a great panic.
On the other hand, money easily becomes a `drug,' as the phrase is, and there is soon too much of
it. The number of accepted securities is limited, and cannot be rapidly increased; if the amount of
money seeking these accepted securities is more than can be lent on them the value of money soon
goes down. You may often hear in the market that bills are not to be had,meaning good bills of
course,and when you hear this you may be sure that the value of money is very low.
If money were all held by the owners of it, or by banks which did not pay an interest for it, the value
of money might not fall so fast. Money would, in the market phrase, be `well held.' The possessors
would be under no necessity to employ it all; they might employ part at a high rate rather than all at
a low rate. But in Lombard Street money is very largely held by those who do pay an interest for it,
and such persons must employ it all, or almost all, for they have much to pay out with one hand, and
unless they receive much with the other they will be ruined. Such persons do not so much care what
is the rate of interest at which they employ their money: they can reduce the interest they pay in
proportion to that which they can make. The vital points to them is to employ it at some rate. If you
hold (as in Lombard Street some persons do) millions of other people's money at interest, arithmetic
teaches that you will soon be ruined if you make nothing of it even if the interest you pay is not high.
The fluctuations in the value of money are therefore greater than those on the value of most other
commodities. At times there is an excessive pressure to borrow it, and at times an excessive
pressure to lend it, and so the price is forced up and down.
These considerations enable us to estimate the responsibility which is thrown on the Bank of
England by our system, and by every system on the bank or banks who by it keep the reserve of
bullion or of legal tender exchangeable for bullion. These banks can in no degree control the
permanent value of money, but they can completely control its momentary value. They cannot
change the average value, but they can determine the deviations from the average. If the dominant
banks manage ill, the rate of interest will at one time be excessively high, and at another time
excessively low: there will be first a pernicious excitement, and next a fatal collapse. But if they
manage well, the rate of interest will not deviate so much from the average rate; it will neither
ascend so high nor descend so low. As far as anything can be steady the value of money will then
be steady, and probably in consequence trade will be steady tooat least a principal cause of
periodical disturbance will have been withdrawn from it.
CHAPTER VI - Why Lombard Street Is Often Very Dull, and Sometimes Extremely Excited
Any sudden event which creates a great demand for actual cash may cause, and will tend to cause,
a panic in a country where cash is much economised, and where debts payable on demand are
large. In such a country an immense credit rests on a small cash reserve, and an unexpected and
large diminution of that reserve may easily break up and shatter very much, if not the whole, of that
credit. Such accidental events are of the most various nature: a bad harvest, an apprehension of
foreign invasion, the sudden failure of a great firm which everybody trusted, and many other similar
events, have all caused a sudden demand for cash. And some writers have endeavoured to classify
panics according to the nature of the particular accidents producing them. But little, however, is, I
believe, to be gained by such classifications. There is little difference in the effect of one accident
and another upon our credit system. We must be prepared for all of them, and we must prepare for
all of them in the same wayby keeping a large cash reserve.
But it is of great importance to point out that our industrial organisation is liable not only to irregnlar
external accidents, but likewise to regnlar internal changes; that these changes make our credit
system much more delicate at some times than at others; and that it is the recurrence of these
periodical seasons of delicacy which has given rise to the notion that panics come according to a
fixed rule, that every ten years or so we must have one of them.
Most persons who begin to think of the subject are puzzled on the threshold. They hear much of
`good times' and `bad times,' meaning by `good' times in which nearly everyone is very well off, and
by `bad' times in which nearly everyone is comparatively ill off. And at first it is natural to ask why
should everybody, or almost everybody, be well off together? Why should there be any great tides of
industry, with large diffused profit by way of flow, and large diffused want of profit, or loss, by way of
ebb? The main answer is hardly given distinctly in our common books of political economy. These
books do not tell you what is the fund out of which large general profits are paid in good times, nor
do they ex plain why that fund is not available for the same purpose in bad times. Our current
political economy does not sufficiently take account of time as an element in trade operations; but
as soon as the division of labour has once established itself in a community, two principles at once
begin to be important, of which time is the very essence. These are
First. That as goods are produced to be exchanged, it is good that they should be exchanged as
quickly as possible.
Secondly. That as every producer is mainly occupied in producing what others want, and not what
he wants himself, it is desirable that he should always be able to find, without effort, without delay,
and without uncertainty, others who want what he can produce.
In themselves these principles are self-evident. Everyone will admit it to be expedient that all goods
wanting to be sold should be sold as soon as they are ready; that every man who wants to work
should find employment as soon as he is ready for it. Obviously also, as soon as the `division of
labour' is really established, there is a difficulty about both of these principles. A produces what he
thinks B wants, but it may be a mistake, and B may not want it. A may be able and willing to produce
what B wants, but he may not be able to find Bhe may not know of his existence.
The general truth of these principles is obvious, but what is not obvious is the extreme greatness of
their effects. Taken together, they make the whole difference between times of brisk trade and great
prosperity, and times of stagnant trade and great adversity, so far as that prosperity and that
adversity are real and not illusory. If they are satisfied, everyone knows whom to work for, and what
to make, and he can get immediately in exchange what he wants'himself. There is no idle labour
and no sluggish capital in the whole community, and, in consequence, all which can be produced is
produced, the effectiveness of human industry is augmented, and both kinds of producers both
capitalists and labourersare much richer than usual, because the amount to be divided between
them is also much greater than usual.
And there is a partnership in industries. No single large industry can be depressed without injury to
other industries; still less can any great group of industries. Each industry when prosperous buys
and consumes the produce probably of most (certainly of very many) other industries, and if industry
A fail and is in difficulty, industries B, and C, and D, which used to sell to it, will not be able to sell
that which they had produced in reliance on A's demand, and in future they will stand idle till industry
A recovers, because in default of A there will be no one to buy the commodities which they create.
Then as industry B buys of C, D, &c., the adversity of B tells on C, D, &c., and as these buy of E, F,
&c., the effect is propagated through the whole alphabet. And in a certain sense it rebounds. Z feels
the want caused by the diminished custom of A, B, & C, and so it does not earn so much; in
consequence, it cannot lay out as much on the produce of A, B, & C, and so these do not earn as
much either. In all this money is but an instrument. The same thing would happen equally well in a
trade of barter, if a state of barter on a very large scale were not practically impossible, on account
of the time and trouble which it would necessarily require. As has been explained, the fundamental
cause is that under a system in which everyone is dependent on the labour of everyone else, the
loss of one spreads and multiplies through all, and spreads and multiplies the faster the higher the
previous perfection of the system of divided labour, and the more nice and effectual the mode of
interchange. And the entire effect of a depression in any single large trade requires a considerable
time before it can be produced. It has to be propagated, and to be returned through a variety of
industries, before it is complete. Short depressions, in consequence, have scarcely any discernible
consequences; they are over before we think of their effects. It is only in the case of continuous and
considerable depressions that the cause is in action long enough to produce discernible effects.
The most common, and by far the most important, case where the depression in one trade causes
depression in all others, is that of depressed agriculture. When the agriculture of the world is ill off,
food is dear. And as the amount of absolute necessaries which a people consumes cannot be much
diminished, the additional amount which has to be spent on them is so much subtracted from what
used to be spent on other things. All the industries, A, B, C, D, up to Z, are somewhat affected by an
augmentation in the price of corn, and the most affected are the large ones, which produce the
objects in ordinary times most consumed by the working classes. The clothing trades feel the
difference at once, and in this country the liquor trade (a great source of English revenue) feels it
almost equally soon. Especially when for two or three years harvests have been bad, and corn has
long been dear, every industry is impoverished, and almost every one, by becoming poorer, makes
every other poorer too. All trades are slack from diminished custom, and the consequence is a vast
stagnant capital, much idle labour, and a greatly retarded production.
It takes two or three years to produce this full calamity, and the recovery from it takes two or three
years also. If corn should long be cheap, the labouring classes have much to spend on what they
like besides. The producers of those things become prosperous, and have a greater purchasing
power. They exercise it, and that creates in the class they deal with another purchasing power, and
so all through society. The whole machine of industry is stimulated to its maximum of energy, just as
before much of it was slackened almost to its minimum.
A great calamity to any great industry will tend to produce the same effect, but the fortunes of the
industries on which the wages of labour are expended are much more important than those of all
others, because they act much more quickly upon a larger mass of purchasers. On principle, if there
was a perfect division of labour, every industry would have to be perfectly prosperous in order that
any one might be so. So far, therefore, from its being at all natural that trade should develop
constantly, steadily, and equably, it is plain, without going farther, from theory as well as from
experience, that there are inevitably periods of rapid dilatation, and as inevitably periods of
contraction and of stagnation.
Nor is this the only changeable element in modern industrial societies. Creditthe disposition of one
man to trust anotheris singularly varying. In England, after a great calamity, everybody is suspicious
of everybody; as soon as that calamity is forgotten, everybody again confides in everybody. On the
Continent there has been a stiff controversy as to whether credit should or should not be called
capital:' in England, even the little attention once paid to abstract economics is now diverted, and no
one cares in the least for refined questions of this kind: the material practical point is that, in M.
Chevalier's language, credit is `additive,' or additionalthat is, in times when credit is good productive
power is more efficient, and in times when credit is bad productive power is less efficient. And the
state of credit is thus influential, because of the two principles which have just been explained. In a
good state of credit, goods lie on hand a much less time than when credit is bad; sales are quicker;
intermediate dealers borrow easily to augment their trade, and so more and more goods are more
quickly and more easily transmitted from the producer to the consumer.
These two variable causes are causes of real prosperity. They augment trade and production, and
so are plainly beneficial, except where by mistake the wrong things are produced, or where also by
mistake misplaced credit is given, and a man who cannot produce anything which is wanted gets
the produce of other people's labour upon a false idea that he will produce it. But there is another
variable cause which produces far more of apparent than of real prosperity and of which the effect is
in actual life mostly confused with those of the others.
In our common speculations we do not enough remember that interest on money is a refined idea,
and not a universal one. So far indeed is it from being universal, that the majority of saving persons
in most countries would reject it. Most savings in most countries are held in hoarded specie. In Asia,
in Africa, in South America, largely even in Europe, they are thus held, and it would frighten most of
the owners to let them out of their keeping. An Englishman a modern Englishman at leastassumes
as a first principle that he ought to be able to `put his money into something safe that will yield 5 per
cent;' but most saving persons in most countries are afraid to `put their money' into anything.
Nothing is safe to their minds; indeed, in most countries, owing to a bad Government and a
backward industry, no investment, or hardly any, really is safe. In most countries most men are
content to forego interest; but in more advanced countries, at some times there are more savings
seeking investment than there are known investments for; at other times there is no such
superabundance. Lord Macaulay has graphically described one of the periods of excess. He
says'During the interval between the Restoration and the Revolution the riches of the nation had
been rapidly increasing. Thousands of busy men found every Christmas that, after the expenses of
the year's housekeeping had been defrayed out of the year's income, a surplus remained; and how
that surplus was to be employed was a question of some difficulty. In our time, to invest such a
surplus, at something more than three per cent, on the best security that has ever been known in the
world, is the work of a few minutes. But in the seventeenth century, a lawyer, a physician, a retired
merchant, who had saved some thousands, and who wished to place them safely and profitably,
was often greatly embarrassed. Three generations earlier, a man who had accumulated wealth in a
profession generally purchased real property, or lent his savings on mortgage. But the number of
acres in the kingdom had remained the same; and the value of those acres, though it had greatly
increased, had by no means increased so fast as the quantity of capital which was seeking for
employment. Many too wished to put their money where they could find it at an hour's notice, and
looked about for some species of property which could be more readily transferred than a house or
a field. A capitalist might lend on bottomry or on personal security; but, if he did so, he ran a great
risk of losing interest and principal. There were a few joint stock companies, among which the East
India Company held the foremost place; but the demand for the stock of such companies was far
greater than the supply. Indeed the cry for a new East India Company was chiefly raised by persons
who had found difficulty in placing their savings at interest on good security. So great was that
difficulty that the practice of hoarding was common. We are told that the father of Pope, the poet,
who retired from business in the City about the time of the Revolution, carried to a retreat in the
country a strong box containing near twenty thousand pounds, and took out from time to time what
was required for household expenses; and it is highiy probable that this was not a solitary case. At
present the quantity of coin which is hoarded by private persons is so small, that it would, if brought
forth, make no perceptible addition to the circulation. But, in the earlier part of the reign of William
the Third, all the greatest writers on currency were of opinion that a very considerable mass of gold
and silver was hidden in secret drawers and behind wainscots.
`The natural effect of this state of things was that a crowd of projectors, ingenious and absurd,
honest and knavish, employed themselves in devising new schemes for the employment of
redundant capital. It was about the year 1688 that the word stockjobber was first heard in London. In
the short space of four years a crowd of companies, every one of which confidently held out to
subscribers the hope of immense gains, sprang into existencethe Insurance Company, the Paper
Company, the Lutestring Company, the Pearl Fishery Company, the Glass Bottle Company, the
Alum Company, the Blythe Coal Company, the Swordblade Company. There was a Tapestry
Company, which would soon furnish pretty hangings for all the parlours of the middle class, and for
all the bedchambers of the higher. There was a Copper Company, which proposed to explore the
mines of England, and held out a hope that they would prove not less valuable than those of Potosi.
There was a Diving Company, which undertook to bring up precious effects from shipwrecked
vessels, and which announced that it had laid in a stock of wonderful machines resembling
complete suits of armour. In front of the helmet was a huge glass eye like that of a Cyclops; and out
of the crest went a pipe through which the air was to be admitted. The whole process was exhibited
on the Thames. Fine gentlemen and fine ladies were invited to the show, were hospitably regaled,
and were delighted by seeing the divers in their panoply descend into the river and return laden with
old iron and ship's tackle. There was a Greenland Fishing Company, which could not fail to drive the
Dutch whalers and herring busses out of the Northern Ocean. There was a Tanning Company,
which promised to furnish leather superior to the best that was brought from Turkey or Russia.
There was a society which undertook the office of giving gentlemen a liberal education on low
terms, and which assumed the sounding name of the Royal Academies Company. In a pompous
advertisement it was announced that the directors of the Royal Academies Company had engaged
the best masters in every branch of knowledge, and were about to issue twenty thousand tickets at
twenty shillings each. There was to be a lotterytwo thousand prizes were to be drawn; and the
fortunate holders of the prizes were to be taught, at the charge of the Company, Latin, Greek,
Hebrew, French, Spanish, conic sections, trigonometry, heraldry, japaning, fortification,
bookkeeping, and the art of playing the theorbo.'
The panic was forgotten till Lord Macaulay revived the memory of it. But, in fact, in the South Sea
Bubble, which has always been remembered, the form was the same, only a little more extravagant;
the companies in that mania were for objects such as these:' "Wrecks to be fished for on the Irish
CoastInsurance of Horses and other Cattle (two millions) Insurance of Losses by ServantsTo make
Salt Water FreshFor building of Hospitals for Bastard ChildrenFor building of Ships against
PiratesFor making of Oil from Sun-flower SeedsFor improving of Malt LiquorsFor recovery of
Seamen's WagesFor extracting of Silver from LeadFor the transmuting of Quicksilver into a
malleable and fine MetalFor making of Iron with Pit-coalFor importing a Number of large Jack Asses
from Spain For trading in Human HairFor fatting of HogsFor a Wheel of Perpetual Motion." But the
most strange of all, perhaps, was "For an Undertaking which shall in due time be revealed." Each
subscriber was to pay down two gnineas, and hereafter to receive a share of one hundred, with a
disclosure of the object; and so tempting was the offer, that 1,000 of these subscriptions were paid
the same morning, with which the projector went off in the afternoon.' In 1825 there were
speculations in companies nearly as wild, and just before 1866 there were some of a like nature,
though not equally extravagant. The fact is, that the owners of savings not finding, in adequate
quantities, their usual kind of investments, rush into anything that promises speciously, and when
they find that these specious investments can be disposed of at a high profit, they rush into them
more and more. The first taste is for high interest, but that taste soon becomes secondary. There is
a second appetite for large gains to be made by selling the principal which is to yield the interest. So
long as such sales can be effected the mania continues; when it ceases to be possible to effect
them, ruin begins.
So long as the savings remain in possession of their owners, these hazardous gamblings in
speculative undertakings are almost the whole effect of an excess of accumulation over tested
investment. Little effect is produced on the general trade of the country. The owners of the savings
are too scattered and far from the market to change the majority of mercantile transactions. But
when these savings come to be lodged in the hands of bankers, a much wider result is produced.
Bankers are close to mercantile life; they are always ready to lend on good mercantile securities;
they wish to lend on such securities a large part of the money entrusted to them. When, therefore,
the money so entrusted is unusually large, and when it long continues so, the general trade of the
country is, in the course of time, changed. Bankers are daily more and more ready to lend money to
mercantile men; more is lent to such men; more bargains are made in consequence; commodities
are more sought after; and, in consequence, prices rise more and more.
The rise of prices is quickest in an improving state of credit. Prices in general are mostly determined
by wholesale transactions. The retail dealer adds a percentage to the wholesale prices, not, of
course, always the same percentage, but still mostly the same. Given the wholesale price of most
articles, you can commonly tell their retail price. Now wholesale transactions are commonly not cash
transactions, but bill transactions. The duration of the bill varies with the custom of the trade; it may
be two, three months, or six weeks, but there is always a bill. Times of credit mean times in which
the bills of many people are taken readily; times of bad credit, times when the bills of much fewer
people are taken, and even of those suspiciously. In times of good credit there are a great number
of strong purchasers, and in times of bad credit only a smaller number of weak ones; and, therefore,
years of improving credit, if there be no disturbing cause, are years of rising price, and years of
decaying credit, years of falling price.
This is the meaning of the saying `John Bull can stand many things, but he cannot stand two per
cent:' it means that the greatest effect of the three great causes is nearly peculiar to England; here,
and here almost alone, the excess of savings over investments is deposited in banks; here, and
here only, is it made use of so as to affect trade at large; here, and here only, are prices gravely
affected. In these circumstances, a low rate of interest, long protracted, is equivalent to a total
depreciation of the precious metals. In his book on the effect of the great gold discoveries, Professor
Jevons showed, and so far as I know, was the first to show, the necessity of eliminating these
temporary changes of value in gold before you could judge properly of the permanent depreciation.
He proved, that in the years preceding both 1847 and 1857 there was a general rise of prices; and
in the years succeeding these years, a great fall. The same might be shown of the years before and
after 866, mutatis mutandis.
And at the present moment we have a still more remarkable example, which was thus analysed in
the Economist of the 30th December, 1871, in an article which I venture to quote as a whole:
`THE GREAT RISE IN THE PRICE OF COMMODITIES.
`Most persons are aware that the trade of the country is in a state of great activity. All the usual tests
indicate thatthe state of the Revenue, the Bankers' Clearing-house figures, the returns of exports
and imports are all plain, and all speak the same language. But few have, we think, considered one
most remarkable feature of the present time, or have sufficiently examined its consequences. That
feature is the great rise in the price of most of the leading articles of trade during the past year. We
give at the foot of this paper a list of articles, comprising most first-rate articles of commerce, and it
will be seen that the rise of price, though not universal and not uniform, is nevertheless very striking
and very general. The most remarkable cases are
January December
£, s. d. £, s. d.
WoolSouth Down hogs per pack 13 0 0 21 15 0
CottonUpland ordinary per lb. 0 0 0 0 8
No. 40 mule yarn, &c. per lb. 0 1 0 1
IronBars, British per ton 7 2 6 8 17 6
Pig, No. 1 Clyde per ton 2 13 3 3 16 0
Lead per ton 18 7 6 8 17 6
Tin per ton 137 0 0 157 0 0
CopperSheeting per ton 75 10 0 95 0 0
Wheat (GAZETTE average) per qr. 2 12 0 2 15 8
and in other cases there is a tendency upwards in price much more often than there is a tendency
downwards.
`This general rise of price must be due either to a diminution in the supply of the quoted articles, or
to an increased demand for them. In some cases there has no doubt been a short supply. Thus in
wool, the diminution in the home breed of sheep has had a great effect on the price
In 1869 the home stock of sheep was 29,538,000
In 1871 27,133,000
Diminution Equal to 8.1 per cent 2,405,000
and in the case of some other articles there may be a similar cause operating. But taking the whole
mass of the supply of commodities in this country, as shown by the plain test of the quantities
imported, it has not diminished, but augmented. The returns of the Board of Trade prove this in the
most striking manner, and we give below a table of some of the important articles. The rise in prices
must, therefore, be due to an increased demand, and the first question is, to what is that demand
due?
`We believe it to be due to the combined operation of three causes cheap money, cheap corn, and
improved credit. As to the first indeed, it might be said at first sight that so general an increase must
be due to a depreciation of the precious metals. Certainly in many controversies facts far less
striking have been alleged as proving it. And indeed there plainly is a diminution in the purchasing
power of money, though that diminution is not general and permanent, but local and temporary. The
peculiarity of the precious metals is that their value depends for unusually long periods on the
quantity of them which is in the market. In the long run, their value, like that of all others, is
determined by the cost at which they can be brought to market. But for all temporary purposes, it is
the supply in the market which governs the price, and that supply in this country is exceedingly
variable. After a commercial crisis1866 for exampletwo things happen: first, we call in the debts
which are owing to us in foreign countries; and we require these debts to be paid to us, not in
commodities, but in money. From this cause principally, and omitting minor causes, the bullion in
the Bank of England, which was 13,1 56,000 l. in May 1866, rose to 19,413,000 l. in January 1867,
being an increase of over 6,000,000 l. And then there comes also a second cause, tending in the
same direction. During a depressed period the savings of the country increase considerably faster
than the outlet for them. A person who has made savings does not know what to do with them. And
this new unemployed saving means additional money. Till a saving is invested or employed it exists
only in the form of money: a farmer who has sold his wheat and has 100 l. `to the good,' holds that
100 l. in money, or some equivalent for money, till he sees some advantageous use to be made of
it. Probably he places it in a bank, and this enables it to do more work. If 3,000,000!. of coin be
deposited in a bank, and it need only keep 1,000,000 l. as a reserve, that sets 2,000,- 000 l. free,
and is for the time equivalent to an increase of so much coin. As a principle it may be laid down that
all new unemployed savings require either an increased stock of the precious metals, or an increase
in the efficiency of the banking expedients by which these metals are economised. In other words, in
a saving and uninvesting period of the national industry, we accumulate gold, and augment the
efficiency of our gold. If therefore such a saving period follows close upon an occasion when foreign
credits have been diminished and foreign debts called in, the augmentation in the effective quantity
of gold in the country is extremely great. The old money called in from abroad and the new money
representing the new saving co-operate with one another. And their natural tendency is to cause a
general rise in price, and what is the same thing, a diffused diminution in the purchasing power of
money.
`Up to this point there is nothing special in the recent history of the money market. Similar events
happened both after the panic of 1847, and after that of 1857. But there is another cause of the
same kind, and acting in the same direction, which is peculiar to the present time; this cause is the
amount of the foreign money, and especially of the money of foreign Governments, now in London.
No Government probably ever had nearly as much at its command as the German Government now
has. Speaking broadly, two things happened: during the war England was the best place of shelter
for foreign money, and this made money more cheap here than it would otherwise have been; after
the war England became the most convenient paying place, and the most convenient resting place
for money, and this again has made money cheaper. The commercial causes, for which there are
many precedents, have been aided by a political cause for the efficacy of which there is no
precedent.
`But though plentiful money is necessary to high prices, and though it has a natural tendency to
produce these prices, yet it is not of itself sufficient to produce them. In the cases we are dealing
with, in order to lower prices there must not only be additional money, but a satisfactory mode of
employing that additional money. This is obvious if we remember whence that augmented money is
derived. It is derived from the savings of the people, and will only be invested in the manner which
the holders for the time being consider suitable to such savings. It will not be used in mere
expenditure; it would be contrary to the very nature of it so to use it. A new channel of demand is
required to take off the new money, or that new money will not raise prices. It will lie idle in the
banks, as we have often seen it. We should still see the frequent, the common phenomenon of dull
trade and cheap money existing side by side.
`The demand in this case arose in the most effective of all ways. In 1867 and the first half of 1868
corn was dear, as the following figures show:
GAZETTE AVERAGE PRICE OF WHEAT.
s. d. S. d.
December, 1866 60 3 October 1867 66 6
January, 1867 61 4 November 69 5
February 60 10 December 67 4
March 59 9 January, 1868 70 3
April 61 6 February 73 0
May 64 8 March 73 0
June 65 8 April 73 3
July 65 0 May 73 9
August 67 8 June 67 11
September 62 8 July 65 5
From that time it fell, and it was very cheap during the whole of 1869 and 1870. The effect of this
cheapness is great in every department of industry. The working classes, having cheaper food,
need to spend so much less on that food, and have more to spend on other things. In consequence,
there is a gentle augmentation of demand through almost all departments of trade. And this almost
always causes a great augmentation in what may be called the instrumental tradesthat is, in the
trades which deal in machines and instruments used in many branches of commerce, and in the
materials for such. Take, for instance, the iron trade
tons tons
In the year 1869 we exported 2,568,000
In 1870 " 2,716,000
5,284,000
In 1867
"
1,881,000
In 1868
"
1,944,000
3,826,000
Increase 1,458,000
that is to say, cheap corn operating throughout the world, created a new demand for many kinds of
articles; the production of a large number of such articles being aided by iron in some one of its
many forms, iron to that extent was exported. And the effect is cumulative. The manufacture of iron
being stimulated, all persons concerned in that great manufacture are well off, have more to spend,
and by spending it encourage other branches of manufacture, which again propagate the demand;
they receive and so encourage industries in a third degree dependent and removed.
`It is quite true that corn has not been quite so cheap during the present year. But even if it had been
dearer than it is, it would not all at once arrest the great trade which former cheapness had created.
The "ball," if we may so say, "was set rolling" in i869 and 1870, and a great increase of demand was
then created in certain trades and propagated through all trades. A continuance of very high prices
would produce the reverse effect; it would slacken demand in certain trades, and the effect would be
gradually diffused through all trades. But a slight rise such as that of this year has no perceptible
effect.
`When the stimulus of cheap corn is added to that of cheap money, the full conditions of a great and
diffused rise of prices are satisfied. This new employment supplies a mode in which money can be
invested. Bills are drawn of greater number and greater magnitude, and through the agencies of
banks and discount houses, the savings of the country are invested in such bills. There is thus a
new want and a new purchase-money to supply that want, and the consequence is the diffused and
remarkable rise of price which the figures show to have occurred.
`The rise has also been aided by the revival of credit. This, as need not be at length explained, is a
great aid to buying, and consequently a great aid to a rise of price. Since 1866, credit has been
gradually, though very slowly, recovering, and it is probably as good as it is reasonable or proper
that it should be. We are now trusting as many people as we ought to trust, and as yet there is no
wild excess of misplaced confidence which would make us trust those whom we ought not to trust.'
The process thus explained is the common process. The surplus of loanable capital which lies in the
hands of bankers is not employed by them in any original way; it is almost always lent to a trade
already growing and already improving. The use of it develops that trade yet farther, and this again
augments and stimulates other trades. Capital may long lie idle in a stagnant condition of industry;
the mercantile securities which experienced bankers know to be good do not augment, and they will
not invent other securities, or take bad ones.
In most great periods of expanding industry, the three great causes much loanable capital, good
credit, and the increased profits derived from better-used labour and better-used capitalhave acted
simultaneously; and though either may act by itself, there is a permanent reason why mostly they
will act together. They both tend to grow together, if you begin from a period of depression. In such
periods credit is bad, and industry unemployed; very generally provisions are high in price, and their
dearness was one of the causes which made the times bad. Whether there was or was not too
much loanable capital when that period begins, there soon comes to be too much. Quiet people
continue to save part of their incomes in bad times as well as in good; indeed, of the two, people of
slightly-varying and fixed incomes have better means of saving in bad times because prices are
lower. Quiescent trade affords no new securities in which the new saving can be invested, and
therefore there comes soon to be an excess of loanable capital. In a year or two after a crisis credit
usually improves, as the remembrance of the disasters which at the crisis impaired credit is
becoming fainter and fainter. Provisions get back to their usual price, or some great industry makes,
from some temporary cause, a quick step forward. At these moments, therefore, the three agencies
which, as has been explained, greatly develope trade, combine to develope it simultaneously.
The certain result is a bound of national prosperity; the country leaps forward as if by magic. But
only part of that prosperity has a solid reason. As far as prosperity is based on a greater quantity of
production, and that of the right articlesas far as it is based on the increased rapidity with which
commodities of every kind reach those who want themits basis is good. Human industry is more
efficient, and therefore there is more to be divided among mankind. But in so far as that prosperity is
based on a general rise of prices, it is only imaginary. A general rise of prices is a rise only in name;
whatever anyone gains on the article which he has to sell he loses on the articles which he has to
buy, and so he is just where he was. The only real effects of a general rise of prices are these: first,
it straitens people of fixed incomes, who suffer as purchasers, but who have no gain to correspond;
and secondly, it gives an extra profit to fixed capital created before the rise happened. Here the
sellers gain, but without any equivalent loss as buyers. Thirdly, this gain on fixed capital is greatest
in what may be called the industrial `implements,' such as coal and iron. These are wanted in all
industries, and in any general increase of prices, they are sure to rise much more than other things.
Everybody wants them; the supply of them cannot be rapidly augmented, and therefore their price
rises very quickly. But to the country as a whole, the general rise of prices is no benefit at all; it is
simply a change of nomenclature for an identical relative value in the same commodities.
Nevertheless, most people are happier for it; they think they are getting richer, though they are not.
And as the rise does not happen on all articles at the same moment, but is propagated gradually
through society, those to whom it first comes gain really; and as at first every one believes that he
will gain when his own article is rising, a buoyant cheerfulness overflows the mercantile world.
This prosperity is precarious as far as it is real, and transitory in so far as it is fictitious. The
augmented production, which is the reason of the real prosperity, depends on the full working of the
whole industrial organisationof all capitalists and labourers; that prosperity was caused by that full
working, and will cease with it. But that full working is liable to be destroyed by the occurrence of
any great misfortune to any considerable industry. This would cause misfortune to the industries
dependent on that one, and, as has been explained, all through society and back again. But every
such industry is liable to grave fluctuations, and the most importantthe provisionindustriesto the
gravest and the suddenest. They are dependent on the casualties of the seasons. A single bad
harvest diffused over the world, a succession of two or three bad harvests, even in England only, will
raise the price of corn exceedingly, and will keep it high. And a great and protracted rise in the price
of corn will at once destroy all the real part of the unusual prosperity of previous good times. It will
change the full working of the industrial machine into an imperfect working; it will make the produce
of that machine less than usual instead of more than usual; instead of there being more than the
average of general dividend to be distributed between the producers, there will immediately be less
than the average.
And in so far as the apparent prosperity is caused by an unusual plentifulness of loanable capital
and a consequent rise in prices, that prosperity is not only liable to reaction, but certain to be
exposed to reaction. The same causes which generate this prosperity will, after they have been
acting a little longer, generate an equivalent adversity. The process is this: the plentifulness of
loanable capital causes a rise of prices; that rise of prices makes it necessary to have more
loanable capital to carry on the same trade. 100,000 l. will not buy as much when prices are high as
it will when prices are low, it will not be so effectual for carrying on business; more money is
necessary in dear times than in cheap times to produce the same changes in the same
commodities. Even supposing trade to have remained stationary, a greater capital would be
required to carry it on after such a rise of prices as has been described than was necessary before
that rise. But in this case the trade will not have remained stationary; it will have increasedcertainly
to some extent, probably to a great extent. The `loanable capital,' the lending of which caused the
rise of prices, was lent to enable itto augment. The loanable capital lay idle in the banks till some
trade started into prosperity, and then was lent in order to develope that trade; that trade caused
other secondary developments; those secondary developments enabled more loanable capital to be
lent; and that lending caused a tertiary development of trade; and so on through society.
In consequence, a long-continued low rate of interest is almost always followed by a rapid rise in
that rate. Till the available trade is found it lies idle, and can scarcely be lent at all; some of it is not
lent. But the moment the available trade is discoveredthe moment that prices have risenthe demand
for loanable capital becomes keen. For the most part, men of business must carry on their regular
trade; if it cannot be carried on without borrowing io per cent more capital, 10 per cent more capital
they must borrow. Very often they have incurred obligations which must be met; and if that is so the
rate of interest which they pay is comparatively indifferent. What is necessary to meet their
acceptances they will borrow, pay for it what they may; they had better pay any price than permit
those acceptances to be dishonoured. And in less extreme eases men of business have a fixed
capital, which cannot lie idle except at a great loss; a set of labourers which must be, if possible,
kept together; a steady connection of customers, which they would very unwillingly lose. To keep all
these, they borrow; and in a period of high prices many merchants are peculiarly anxious to borrow,
because the augmentation of the price of the article in which they deal makes them really see, or
imagine that they see, peculiar opportunities of profit. An immense new borrowing soon follows
upon the new and great trade, and the rate of interest rises at once, and generally rises rapidly.
This is the surer to happen that Lombard Street is, as has been shown before, a very delicate
market. A large amount of money is held there by bankers and by bill-brokers at interest: this they
must employ, or they will be ruined. It is better for them to reduce the rate they charge, and
compensate themselves by reducing the rate they pay, rather than to keep up the rate of charge, if
by so doing they cannot employ all their money. It is vital to them to employ all the money on which
they pay interest. A little excess therefore forces down the rate of interest very much. But if that low
rate of interest should cause, or should aid in causing, a great growth of trade, the rise is sure to be
quick, and is apt to be violent. The figures of trade are reckoned by hundreds of millions, where
those of loanable capital count only by millions. A great increase in the borrowing demands of
English commerce almost always changes an excess of loanable capital above the demand to a
greater deficiency below the demand. That deficiency causes adversity, or apparent adversity, in
trade, just as, and in the same manner, that the previous excess caused prosperity, or apparent
prosperity. It causes a fall of price that runs through society; that fall causes a decline of activity and
a diminution of profitsa painful contraction instead of the previous pleasant expansion.
The change is generally quicker because some check to credit happens at an early stage of it. The
mercantile community will have been unusually fortunate if during the period of rising prices it has
not made great mistakes. Such a period naturally excites the sanguine and the ardent; they fancy
that the prosperity they see will last always, that it is only the beginning of a greater prosperity. They
altogether over-estimate the demand for the article they deal in, or the work they do. They all in their
degreeand the ablest and the cleverest the mostwork much more than they should, and trade far
above their means. Every great crisis reveals the excessive speculations of many houses which no
one before suspected, and which commonly indeed had not begun or had not carried very far those
speculations, till they were tempted by the daily rise of price and the surrounding fever.
The case is worse, because at most periods of great commercial excitement there is some mixture
of the older and simpler kind of investing mania. Though the money of saving persons is in the
hands of banks, and though, by offering interest, banks retain the command of much of it, yet they
do not retain the command of the whole, or anything near the whole; all of it can be used, and much
of it is used, by its owners. They speculate with it in bubble companies and in worthless shares, just
as they did in the time of the South Sea mania, when there were no banks, and as they would again
in England supposing that banks ceased to exist. The mania of 1825 and the mania of 1866 were
striking examples of this; in their case to a great extent, as in most similar modern periods to a less
extent, the delirium of ancient gambling co-operated with the milder madness of modern
overtrading. At the very beginning of adversity, the counters in the gambling mama, the shares in
the companies created to feed the mania, are discovered to be worthless; down they all go, and with
them much of credit.
The good times too of high price almost always engender much fraud. All people are most
credulous when they are most happy; and when much money has just been made, when some
people are really making it, when most people think they are making it, there is a happy opportunity
for ingenious mendacity. Almost everything will be believed for a little while, and long before
discovery the worst and most adroit deceivers are geographically or legally beyond the reach of
punishment. But the harm they have done diffuses harm, for it weakens credit still farther.
When we understand that Lombard Street is subject to severe alternations of opposite causes, we
should cease to be surprised at its seeming cycles. We should cease too to be surprised at the
sudden panics. During the period of reaction and adversity, just even at the last instant of prosperity,
the whole structure is delicate. The peculiar essence of our banking system is an unprecedented
trust between man and man: and when that trust is much weakened by hidden causes, a small
accident may greatly hurt it, and a great accident for a moment may almost destroy it.
Now too that we comprehend the inevitable vicissitudes of Lombard Street, we can also thoroughly
comprehend the cardinal importance of always retaining a great banking reserve. Whether the times
of adversity are well met or ill met depends far more on this than on any other single circumstance.
If the reserve be large, its magnitude sustains credit; and if it be small, its diminution stimulates the
gravest apprehensions. And the better we comprehend the importance of the banking reserve, the
higher we shall estimate the responsibility of those who keep it.
CHAPTER VII - A More Exact Account of the Mode in Which the Bank of England Has
Discharged Its Duty of Retaining a Good Bank Reserve, and of Administering It Effectually
The preceding chapters have in some degree enabled us to appreciate the importance of the duties
which the Bank of England is bound to discharge as to its banking reserve.
If we ask how the Bank of England has discharged this great responsibility, we shall be struck by
three things: first, as has been said before, the Bank has never by any corporate act or authorised
utterance acknowledged the duty, and some of its directors deny it; second (what is even more
remarkable), no resolution of Parliament, no report of any Committee of Parliament (as far as I
know), no remembered speech of a responsible statesman, has assigned or enforced that duty on
the Bank; third (what is more remarkable still), the distinct teaching of our highest authorities has
often been that no public duty of any kind is imposed on the Banking Department of the Bank; that,
for banking purposes, it is only a joint stock bank like any other bank; that its managers should look
only to the interest of the proprietors and their dividend; that they are to manage as the London and
Westminster Bank or the Union Bank manages.
At first, it seems exceedingly strange that so important a responsibility should be unimposed,
unacknowledged, and denied; but the explanation is this. We are living amid the vestiges of old
controversies, and we speak their language, though we are dealing with different thoughts and
different facts. For more than fifty yearsfrom 1793 down to 1844there was a keen controversy as to
the public duties of the Bank. It was said to be the `manager' of the paper currency, and on that
account many expected much good from it; others said it did great harm; others again that it could
do neither good nor harm. But for the whole period there was an incessant and fierce discussion.
That discussion was terminated by the Act of 1 844. By that Act the currency manages itself; the
entire working is automatic. The Bank of England plainly does not managecannot even be said to
managethe currency any more. And naturally, but rashly, the only reason upon which a public
responsibility used to be assigned to the Bank having now clearly come to an end, it was inferred by
many that the Bank had no responsibility. The complete uncertainty as to the degree of
responsibility acknowledged by the Bank of England is best illustrated by what has been said by the
Bank directors themselves as to the panic of 866. The panic of that year, it will be remembered,
happened, contrary to precedent, in the spring, and at the next meeting of the Court of Bank
proprietorsthe September meetingthere was a very remarkable discussion, which I give at length
below,
(6)
and of which all that is most material was thus described in the `Economist':
`THE GREAT IMPORTANCE OF THE LATE MEETING
OF THE PROPRIETORS OF THE BANK OF ENGLAND.
`The late meeting of the proprietors of the Bank of England has a very unusual importance. There
can be no effectual inquiry now into the history of the late crisis. A Parliamentary committee next
year would, unless something strange occur in the interval, be a great waste of time. Men of
business have keen sensations but short memories, and they will care no more next February for
the events of last May than they now care for the events of October 1864. A pro forma inquiry, on
which no real mind is spent, and which everyone knows will lead to nothing, is far worse than no
inquiry at all. Under these circumstances the official statements of the Governor of the Bank are the
only authentic expositions we shall have of the policy of the Bank Directors, whether as respects the
past or the future. And when we examine the proceedings with care, we shall find that they contain
matter of the gravest import.
`This meeting may be considered to admit and recognise the fact that the Bank of England keeps
the sole banking reserve of the country. We do not now mix up this matter with the country
circulation, or the question whether there should be many issuers of notes or only one. We speak
not of the currency reserve, but of the banking reservethe reserve held against deposits, and not the
reserve held against notes. We have often insisted in these columns that the Bank of England does
keep the sole real reservethe sole considerable unoccupied mass of cash in the country; but there
has been no universal agreement about it. Great authorities have been unwilling to admit it. They
have not, indeed, formally and explicitly contended against it. If they had, they must have pointed
out some other great store of unused cash besides that at the Bank, and they could not find such
store. But they have attempted distinctions;have said that the doctrine that the Bank of England
keeps the sole banking reserve of the country was "not a good way of putting it," was exaggerated,
and was calculated to mislead.
`But the late meeting is a complete admission that such is the fact. The Governor of the Bank said:
"`A great strain has within the last few months been put upon the resources of this house, and of the
whole banking community of London; and I think I am entitled to say that not only this house, but the
entire banking body, acquitted themselves most honourably and creditably throughout that very
trying period. Banking is a very peculiar business, and it depends so much upon credit that the least
blast of suspicion is sufficient to sweep away, as it were, the harvest of a whole year. But the
manner in which the banking establishments generally in London met the demands made upon
them during the greater portion of the past half-year affords a most satisfactory proof of the
soundness of the principles on which their business is conducted. This house exerted itself to the
utmostand exerted itself most successfullyto meet the crisis. We did not flinch from our post. When
the storm came upon us, on the morning on which it became known that the house of Overend and
Co. had failed, we were in as sound and healthy a position as any banking establishment could
hold, and on that day and throughout the succeeding week we made advances which would hardly
be credited. I do not believe that anyone would have thought of predicting, even at the shortest
period beforehand, the greatness of those advances. It was not unnatural that in this state of things
a certain degree of alarm should have taken possession of the public mind, and that those who
required accommodation from the Bank should have gone to the Chancellor of the Exchequer and
requested the Government to empower us to issue notes beyond the statutory amount, if we should
think that such a measure was desirable. But we had to act before we could receive any such
power, and before the Chancellor of the Exchequer was perhaps out of his bed we had advanced
one-half of our reserves, which were certainly thus reduced to an amount which we could not
witness without regret. But we would not flinch from the duty which we conceived was imposed upon
us of supporting the banking community, and I am not aware that any legitimate application made
for assistance to this house was refused. Every gentleman who came here with adequate security
was liberally dealt with, and if accommodation could not be afforded to the full extent which was
demanded, no one who offered proper security failed to obtain relief from this house."
`Now this is distinctly saying that the other banks of the country need not keep any such banking
reserveany such sum of actual cashof real sovereigns and bank notes, as will help them through a
sudden panic. It acknowledges a "duty" on the part of the Bank of England to "support the banking
community," to make the reserve of the Bank of England do for them as well as for itself.
`In our judgment this language is most just, and the Governor of the Bank could scarcely have done
a greater public service than by using language so businesslike and so distinct. Let us know
precisely who is to keep the banking reserve. If the joint stock banks and the private banks and the
country banks are to keep their share, let us determine on that; Mr. Gladstone appeared not long
since to say in Parliament that it ought to be so. But at any rate there should be no doubt whose
duty it is. Upon grounds which we have often stated, we believe that the anomaly of one bank
keeping the sole banking reserve is so fixed in our system that we cannot change it if we would. The
great evil to be feared was an indistinct conception of the fact, and that is now avoided.
`The importance of these declarations by the Bank is greater, because after the panic of 1857 the
bank did not hold exactly the same language. A person who loves concise expressions said lately
"that Overends broke the Bank in 1866 because it went, and in 1857 because it was not let go." We
need not too precisely examine such language; the element of truth in it is very plainthe great
advances made to Overends were a principal event in the panic of 1857; the bill-brokers were then
very much what the bankers were lately they were the borrowers who wanted sudden and
incalculable advances. But the bill-brokers were told not to expect the like again. But Alderman
Salomons, on the part of the London bankers, said, "he wished to take that opportunity of stating
that he believed nothing could be more satisfactory to the managers and shareholders of joint stock
banks than the testimony which the Governor of the Bank of England had that day borne to the
sound and honourable manner in which their business was conducted. It was manifestly desirable
that the joint stock banks and the banking interest generally should work in harmony with the Bank
of England; and he sincerely thanked the Governor of the Bank for the kindly manner in which he
had alluded to the mode in which the joint stock banks had met the late monetary crisis." The Bank
of England agrees to give other banks the requisite assistance in case of need, and the other banks
agree to ask for it.
`Secondly. The Bank agrees, in fact, if not in name, to make limited advances on proper security to
anyone who applies for it. On the present occasion 45,000,000 l. was so advanced in three months.
And the Bank do not say to the mercantile community, or to the bankers, "Do not come to us again.
We helped you once. But do not look upon it as a precedent. We will not help you again." On the
contrary, the evident and intended implication is that under like circumstances the Bank would act
again as it has now acted.'
This article was much disliked by many of the Bank directors, and especially by some whose
opinion is of great authority. They thought that the `Economist' drew `rash deductions' from a
speech which was in itself `open to some objection'which was, like all such speeches, defective in
theoretical precision, and which was at best only the expression of an opinion by the Governor of
that day, which had not been authorised by the Court of Directors, which could not bind the Bank.
However the article had at least this use, that it brought out the facts. All the directors would have
felt a difficulty in commenting upon, or limiting, or in differing from, a speech of a Governor from the
chair. But there was no difficulty or delicacy in attacking the `Economist.' Accordingly Mr. Hankey,
one of the most experienced bank directors, not long after, took occasion to observe: `The
"Economist" newspaper has put forth what in my opinion is the most mischievous doctrine ever
broached in the monetary or banking world in this country; viz, that it is the proper function of the
Bank of England to keep money available at all times to supply the demands of bankers who have
rendered their own assets unavailable. Until such a doctrine is repudiated by the banking interest,
the difficulty of pursuing any sound principle of banking in London will be always very great. But I do
not believe that such a doctrine as that bankers are justified in relying on the Bank of England to
assist them in time of need is generally held by the bankers in London.
`I consider it to be the undoubted duty of the Bank of England to hold its banking deposits (reserving
generally about one-third in cash) in the most available securities; and in the event of a sudden
pressure in the money market, by whatever circumstance it may be caused, to bear its full share of
a drain on its resources. I am ready to admit, however, that a general opinion has long prevailed that
the Bank of England ought to be prepared to do much more than this, though I confess my surprise
at finding an advocate for such an opinion in the "Economist."
(7)
If it were practicable for the Bank to
retain money unemployed to meet such an emergency, it would be a very unwise thing to do so. But
I contend that it is quite impracticable, and if it were possible, it would be most inexpedient; and I
can only express my regret that the Bank, from a desire to do everything in its power to afford
general assistance in times of banking or commercial distress, should ever have acted in a way to
encourage such an opinion. The more the conduct of the affairs of the Bank is made to assimilate to
the conduct of every other well-managed bank in the United Kingdom, the better for the Bank, and
the better for the community at large.'
I am scarcely a judge, but I do not think Mr. Hankey replies to the `Economist' very conclusively.
First. He should have observed that the question is not as to what `ought to be,' but as to what is.
The `Economist' did not say that the system of a single bank reserve was a good system, but that it
was the system which existed, and which must be worked, as you could not change it.
Secondly. Mr. Hankey should have shown `some other store of unused cash' except the reserve in
the Banking Department of the Bank of England out of which advances in time of panic could be
made. These advances are necessary, and must be made by someone. The `reserves' of London
bankers are not such store; they are used cash, not unused; they are part of the Bank deposits, and
lent as such.
Thirdly. Mr. Hankey should have observed that we know by the published figures that the joint stock
banks of London do not keep one-third, or anything like one-third, of their liabilities in `cash' even
meaning by `cash' a deposit at the Bank of England. One-third of the deposits in joint stock banks,
not to speak of the private banks, would be 30,000,000 l.; and the private deposits of the Bank of
England are i 8,000,000 l. According to his own statement, there is a conspicuous contrast. The joint
stock banks, and the private banks, no doubt, too, keep one sort of reserve, and the Bank of
England a different kind of reserve altogether. Mr. Hankey says that the two ought to be managed
on the same principle; but if so, he should have said whether he would assimilate the practice of the
Bank of England to that of the other banks, or that of the other banks to the practice of the Bank of
England.
Fourthly. Mr. Hankey should have observed that, as has been explained, in most panics, the
principal use of a `banking reserve' is not to advance to bankers; the largest amount is almost
always advanced to the mercantile public and to bill-brokers. But the point is, that by our system all
extra pressure is thrown upon the Bank of England. In the worst part of the crisis of 866, 50,000!.
`fresh money' could not be borrowed, even on the best securityeven on Consols except at the Bank
of England. There was no other lender to new borrowers.
But my object now is not to revive a past controversy, but to show in what an unsatisfactory and
uncertain condition that controversy has left a most important subject. Mr. Hankey's is the last
explanation we have had of the policy of the Bank. He is a very experienced and attentive director,
and I think expresses, more or less, the opinions of other directors. And what do we find? Setting
aside and saying nothing about the remarkable speech of the Governor in 1866, which at least
(according to the interpretation of the `Economist') was clear and excellent, Mr. Hankey leaves us in
doubt altogether as to what will be the policy of the Bank of England in the next panic, and as to
what amount of aid the public may then expect from it. His words are too vague. No one can tell
what a `fair share' means; still less can we tell what other people at some future time will say it
means. Theory suggests, and experience proves, that in a panic the holders of the ultimate Bank
reserve (whether one bank or many) should lend to all that bring good securities quickly, freely, and
readily. By that policy they allay a panic; by every other policy they intensify it. The public have a
right to know whether the Bank of Englandthe holders of our ultimate bank reserveacknowledge this
duty, and are ready to perform it. But this is now very uncertain.
If we refer to history, and examine what in fact has been the conduct of the Bank directors, we find
that they have acted exactly as persons of their type, character, and position might have been
expected to act. They are a board of plain, sensible, prosperous English merchants; and they have
both done and left undone what such a board might have been expected to do and not to do.
Nobody could expect great attainments in economical science from such a board; laborious study is
for the most part foreign to the habits of English merchants. Nor could we expect original views on
banking, for banking is a special trade, and English merchants, as a body, have had no experience
in it. A `board' can scarcely ever make improvements, for the policy of a board is determined by the
opinions of the most numerous class of its membersits average membersand these are never
prepared for sudden improvements. A board of upright and sensible merchants will always act
according to what it considers `safe' principlesthat is, according to the received maxims of the
mercantile world then and thereand in this manner the directors of the Bank of England have acted
nearly uniformly. Their strength and their weakness were curiously exemplified at the time when
they had the most power. After the suspension of cash payments in 1797, the directors of the Bank
of England could issue what notes they liked. There was no check; these notes could not come
back upon the Bank for payment; there was a great temptation to extravagant issue, and no present
penalty upon it. But the directors of the Bank withstood the temptation; they did not issue their
inconvertible notes extravagantly. And the proof is, that for more than ten years after the suspension
of cash payments the Bank paper was undepreciated, and circulated at no discount in comparison
with gold. Though the Bank directors of that day at last fell into errors, yet on the whole they acted
with singular judgment and moderation. But when, in 1810, they came to be examined as to their
reasons, they gave answers that have become almost classical by their nonsense. Mr. Pearse, the
Governor of the Bank, said: `In considering this subject, with reference to the manner in which bank-
notes are issued, resulting from the applications made for discounts to supply the necessary want of
bank-notes, by which their issue in amount is so controlled that it can never amount to an excess, I
cannot see how the amount of bank-notes issued can operate upon the price of bullion, or the state
of the exchanges; and therefore I am individually of opinion that the price of bullion, or the state of
the exchanges, can never be a reason for lessening the amount of banknotes to be issued, always
understanding the control which I have already described.
`Is the Governor of the Bank of the same opinion which has now been expressed by the Deputy-
Governor?
`Mr. WhitmoreI am so much of the same opinion, that I never think it necessary to advert to the price
of gold, or the state of the exchange, on the days on which we make our advances.
`Do you advert to these two circumstances with a view to regulate the general amount of your
advances?I do not advert to it with a view to our general advances, conceiving it not to bear upon
the question.
And Mr. Harman, another Bank director, expressed his opinion in these terms: `I must very
materially alter my opinions before I can suppose that the exchanges will be influenced by any
modifications of our paper currency.'
Very few persons perhaps could have managed to commit so many blunders in so few words.
But it is no disgrace at all to the Bank directors of that day to have committed these blunders. They
spoke according to the best mercantile opinion of England. The City of London and the House of
Commons both approved of what they said; those who dissented were said to be abstract thinkers
and unpractical men. The Bank directors adopted the ordinary opinions, and pursued the usual
practice of their time. It was this `routine' that caused their moderation. They believed that so long as
they issued `notes' only at 5 per cent, and only on the discount of good bills, those notes could not
be depreciated. And as the number of `good' billsbills which sound merchants know to be gooddoes
not rapidiy increase, and as the market rate of interest was often less than 5 per cent, these checks
on over-issue were very effective. They failed in time, and the theory upon which they were
defended was nonsense; but for a time their operation was powerful and excellent.
Unluckily, in the management of the matter before usthe management of the Bank reservethe
directors of the Bank of England were neither acquainted with right principles, nor were they
protected by a judicious routine. They could not be expected themselves to discover such principles.
The abstract thinking of the world is never to be expected from persons in high places; the
administration of first-rate current transactions is a most engrossing business, and those charged
with them are usually but little inclined to think on points of theory, even when such thinking most
nearly concerns those transactions. No doubt when men's own fortunes are at stake, the instinct of
the trader does somehow anticipate the conclusions of the closet. But a board has no instincts when
it is not getting an income for its members, and when it is only discharging a duty of office. During
the suspension of cash paymentsa suspension which lasted twenty-two yearsall traditions as to a
cash reserve had died away. After 1819 the Bank directors had to discharge the duty of keeping a
banking reserve, and (as the law then stood) a currency reserve also, without the guidance either of
keen interests, or good principles, or wise traditions.
Under such circumstances, the Bank directors inevitably made mistakes of the gravest magnitude.
The first time of trial came in 1825. In that year the Bank directors allowed their stock of bullion to
fall in the most alarming manner:
On Dec. 24, 1824, the coin and bullion in the Bank was £10,721,000
On Dec. 25, 1825, it was reduced to £1,260,000
and the consequence was a panic so tremendous that its results are well remembered after nearly
fifty years. In the next period of extreme trialin 18379the Bank was compelled to draw for 2,000,000
l. on the Bank of France; and even after that aid the directors permitted their bullion, which was still
the currency reserve as well as the banking reserve, to be reduced to 2,404,000 l.: a great alarm
pervaded society, and generated an eager controversy, out of which ultimately emerged the Act of
1844. The next trial came in 1847, and then the Bank permitted its banking reserve (which the law
had now distinctly separated) to fall to 1,176,000 l.; and so intense was the alarm, that the executive
Government issued a letter of licence, permitting the Bank, if necessary, to break the new law, and,
if necessary, to borrow from the currency reserve, which was full, in aid of the banking reserve,
which was empty. Till 1857 there was an unusual calm in the money market, but in the autumn of
that year the Bank directors let the banking reserve, which even in October was far too small, fall
thus:
£
Oct. 10 4,024,000
17 3,217,000
24 3,485,000
31 2,258,000
Nov. 6 2,155,000
13 957,000
And then a letter of licence like that of 1847 was not only issued, but used. The Ministry of the day
authorised the Bank to borrow from the currency reserve in aid of the banking reserve, and the Bank
of England did so borrow several hundred pounds till the end of the month of November. A more
miserable catalogue than that of the failures of the Bank of England to keep a good banking reserve
in all the seasons of trouble between 1825 and 1857 is scarcely to be found in history.
But since 1857 there has been a great improvement. By painful events and incessant discussions,
men of business have now been trained to see that a large banking reserve is necessary, and to
understand that, in the curious constitution of the English banking world, the Bank of England is the
only body which could effectually keep it. They have never acknowledged the duty; some of them,
as we have seen, deny the duty; still they have to a considerable extent begun to perform the duty.
The Bank directors, being experienced and able men of business, comprehended this like other
men of business. Since 1857 they have always kept, I do not say a sufficient banking reserve, but a
fair and creditable banking reserve, and one altogether different from any which they kept before. At
one period the Bank directors even went farther: they made a distinct step in advance of the public
intelligence; they adopted a particular mode of raising the rate of interest, which is far more efficient
than any other mode. Mr. Goschen observes, in his book on the Exchanges: `Between the rates in
London and Paris, the expense of sending gold to and fro having been reduced to a minimum
between the two cities, the difference can never be very great; but it must not be forgotten that,the
interest being taken at a percentage calculated per annum, and the probable profit having, when an
operation in three-month bills is contemplated, to be divided by four, whereas the percentage of
expense has to be wholly borne by the one transaction, a very slight expense becomes a great
impediment. If the cost is only ½ per cent, there must be a profit of 2 per cent in the rate of interest,
or ½ per cent on three months, before any advantage commences; and thus, supposing that Paris
capitalists calculate that they may send their gold over to England for ½ per cent expense, and
chance their being so favoured by the Exchanges as to be able to draw it back without any cost at
all, there must nevertheless be an excess of more than 2 per cent in the London rate of interest over
that in Paris, before the operation of sending gold over from France, merely for the sake of the
higher interest, will pay.'
Accordingly, Mr. Goschen recommended that the Bank of England should, as a rule, raise their rate
by steps of 1 per cent at a time when the object of the rise was to affect the `foreign Exchanges.'
And the Bank of England, from 86o onward, have acted upon that principle. Before that time they
used to raise their rate almost always by steps of ½ per cent, and there was nothing in the general
state of mercantile opinion to compel them to change their policy. The change was, on the contrary,
most unpopular. On this occasion, and, as far as I know, on this occasion alone, the Bank of
England made an excellent alteration of their policy, which was not exacted by contemporary
opinion, and which was in advance of it. The beneficial results of the improved policy of the Bank
were palpable and speedy. We were enabled by it to sustain the great drain of silver from Europe to
India to pay for Indian cotton in the years between 18621865. In the autumn of 1864 there was
especial danger; but, by a rapid and able use of their new policy, the Bank of England maintained
an adequate reserve, and preserved the country from calamities which, if we had looked only to
precedent, would have seemed inevitable. All the causes which produced the panic of 1857 were in
action in 1864the drain of silver in 1864 and the preceding year was beyond comparison greater
than in 1857 and the years before itand yet in 1864 there was no panic. The Bank of England was
almost immediately rewarded for its adoption of right principles by finding that those principles, at a
severe crisis, preserved public credit.
In 1866 undoubtedly a panic occurred, but I do not think that the Bank of England can be blamed for
it. They had in their till an exceedingly good reserve according to the estimate of that timea sufficient
reserve, in all probability, to have coped with the crises of 1847 and 1857. The suspension of
Overend and Gurneythe most trusted private firm in Englandcaused an alarm, in suddenness and
magnitude, without example. What was the effect of the Act of 1844 on the panic of 1866 is a
question on which opinion will be long divided; but I think it will be generally agreed that, acting
under the provisions of that law, the directors of the Bank of England had in their banking
department in that year a fairly large reserve quite as large a reserve as anyone expected them to
keepto meet unexpected and painful contingencies.
From 1866 to 1870 there was almost an unbroken calm on the money market. The Bank of England
had no difficulties to cope with; there was no opportunity for much discretion. The money market
took care of itself. But in 1870 the Bank of France suspended specie payments, and from that time a
new era begins. The demands on this market for bullion have been greater, and have been more
incessant, than they ever were before, for this is now the only bullion market. This has made it
necessary for the Bank of England to hold a much larger banking reserve than was ever before
required, and to be much more watchful than in former times lest that banking reserve should on a
sudden be dangerously diminished. The forces are greater and quicker than they used to be, and a
firmer protection and a surer solicitude are necessary. But I do not think the Bank of England is
sufficiently aware of this. All the governing body of the Bank certainly are not aware of it. The same
eminent director to whom I have before referred, Mr. Hankey, published in the `Times' an elaborate
letter, saying again that one-third of the liabilities were, even in these altered times, a sufficient
reserve for the Banking Department of the Bank of England, and that it was no part of the business
of the Bank to keep a supply of `bullion for exportation,' which was exactly the most mischievous
doctrine that could be maintained when the Banking Department of the Bank of England had
become the only great repository in Europe where gold could at once be obtained, and when,
therefore, a far greater store of bullion ought to be kept than at any former period.
And besides this defect of the present time, there are some chronic faults in the policy of the Bank
of England, which arise, as will be presently explained, from grave defects in its form of government.
There is almost always some hesitation when a Governor begins to reign. He is the Prime Minister
of the Bank Cabinet; and when so important a functionary changes, naturally much else changes
too. If the Governor be weak, this kind of vacillation and hesitation continues throughout his term of
office. The usual defect then is, that the Bank of England does not raise the rate of interest
sufficiently quickly. It does raise it; in the end it takes the alarm, but it does not take the alarm
sufficiently soon. A cautious man, in a new office, does not like strong measures. Bank Governors
are generally cautious men; they are taken from a most cautious class; in consequence they are
very apt to temporise and delay. But almost always the delay in creating a stringency only makes a
greater stringency inevitable. The effect of a timid policy has been to let the gold out of the Bank,
and that gold must be recovered. It would really have been far easier to have maintained the reserve
by timely measures than to have replenished it by delayed measures; but new Governors rarely see
this.
Secondly. Those defects are apt, in part, or as a whole, to be continued tbroughout the reign of a
weak Governor. The objection to a decided policy, and the indisposition to a timely action, which are
excusable in one whose influence is beginning, and whose reign is new, is continued through the
whole reign of one to whom those defects are natural, and who exhibits those defects in all his
affairs.
Thirdly. This defect is enhanced, because, as has so often been said, there is now no adequate rule
recognised in the management of the banking reserve. Mr. Weguelin, the last Bank Governor who
has been examined, said that it was sufficient for the Bank to keep from one-fourth to one-third of its
banking liabilities as a reserve. But no one now would ever be content if the banking reserve were
near to one-fourth of its liabilities. Mr. Hankey, as I have shown, considers `about a third' as the
proportion of reserve to liability at which the Bank should aim; but he does not say whether he
regards a third as the minimum below which the reserve in the Banking Department should never
be, or as a fair average, about which the reserve may fluctuate, sometimes being greater, or at
others less.
In a future chapter I shall endeavour to show that one-third of its banking liabilities is at present by
no means an adequate reserve for the Banking Departmentthat it is not even a proper minimum, far
less a fair average; and I shall allege what seem to me good reasons for thinking that, unless the
Bank aim by a different method at a higher standard, its own position may hereafter be perilous, and
the public may be exposed to disaster.
II.
But, as has been explained, the Bank of England is bound, according to our system, not only to
keep a good reserve against a time of panic, but to use that reserve effectually when that time of
panic comes. The keepers of the Banking reserve, whether one or many, are obliged then to use
that reserve for their own safety. If they permit all other forms of credit to perish, their own will perish
immediately, and in consequence.
As to the Bank of England, however, this is denied. It is alleged that the Bank of England can keep
aloof in a panic; that it can, if it will, let other banks and trades fail; that if it chooses, it can stand
alone, and survive intact while all else perishes around it. On various occasions, most influential
persons, both in the government of the Bank and out of it, have said that such was their opinion.
And we must at once see whether this opinion is true or false, for it is absurd to attempt to estimate
the conduct of the Bank of England during panics before we know what the precise position of the
Bank in a panic really is.
The holders of this opinion in its most extreme form say, that in a panic the Bank of England can
stay its hand at any time; that, though it has advanced much, it may refuse to advance more; that
though the reserve may have been reduced by such advances, it may refuse to lessen it still further;
that it can refuse to make any further dis counts; that the bills which it has discounted will become
due; that it can refill its reserve by the payment of those bills; that it can sell stock or other securities,
and so replenish its reserve still further. But in this form the notion scarcely merits serious refutation.
If the Bank reserve has once become low, there are, in a panic, no means of raising it again. Money
parted with at such a time is very hard to get back; those who have taken it will not let it gonot, at
least, unless they are sure of getting other money in its place. And at such instant the recovery of
money is as hard for the Bank of England as for any one else, probably even harder. The difficulty is
this: if the Bank decline to discount, the holders of the bills previously discounted cannot pay. As
has been shown, trade in England is largely carried on with borrowed money. If you propose greatly
to reduce that amount, you will cause many failures unless you can pour in from elsewhere some
equivalent amount of new money. But in a panic there is no new money to be had; everybody who
has it clings to it, and will not part with it. Especially what has been advanced to merchants cannot
easily be recovered; they are under immense liabilities, and they will not give back a penny which
they imagine that even possibly they may need to discharge those liabilities. And bankers are in
even greater terror. In a panic they will not discount a host of new bills; they are engrossed with their
own liabilities and those of their own customers, and do not care for those of others. The notion that
the Bank of England can stop discounting in a panic, and so obtain fresh money, is a delusion. It
can stop discounting, of course, at pleasure. But if it does, it will get in no new money; its bill case
will daily be more and more packed with bills `returned unpaid.'
The sale of stock, too, by the Bank of England in the middle of a panic is impossible. The bank at
such a time is the only lender on stock, and it is only by loans from a bank that large purchases, at
such a moment, can be made. Unless the Bank of England lend, no stock will be bought. There is
not in the country any large sum of unused ready money ready to buy it. The only unused sum is the
reserve in the Banking Department of the Bank of England: if, therefore, in a panic that Department
itself attempt to sell stock, the failure would be ridiculous. It would hardly be able to sell any at all.
Probably it would not sell fifty pounds' worth. The idea that the Bank can, during a panic, replenish
its reserve in this or in any other manner when that reserve has once been allowed to become
empty, or nearly empty, is too absurd to be steadily maintained, though I fear that it is not yet wholly
abandoned.
The second and more reasonable conception of the independence of the Bank of England is,
however, this:It may be said, and it is said, that if the Bank of England stop at the beginning of a
panic, if it refuse to advance a shilling more than usual, if it begin the battle with a good banking
reserve, and do not diminish it by extra loans, the Bank of England is sure to be safe. But this form
of the opinion, though more reasonable and moderate, is not, therefore, more true. The panic of
1866 is the best instance to test it. As everyone knows, that panic began quite suddenly, on the fall
of `Overends.' Just before, the Bank had 5,812,000 l. in its reserve; in fact, it advanced 13,000,000 l.
of new money in the next few days, and its reserve went down to nothing, and the Government had
to help. But if the Bank had not made these advances, could it have kept its reserve?
Certainly it could not. It could not have retained its own deposits. A large part of these are the
deposits of bankers, and they would not consent to help the Bank of England in a policy of isolation.
They would not agree to suspend payments themselves, and permit the Bank of England to survive,
and get all their business. They would withdraw their deposits from the Bank; they would not assist it
to stand erect amid their ruin. But even if this were not so, even if the banks were willing to keep
their deposits at the Bank while it was not lending, they would soon find that they could not do it.
They are only able to keep those deposits at the Bank by the aid of the Clearing-house system, and
if a panic were to pass a certain height, that system, which rests on confidence, would be destroyed
by terror.
The common course of business is this. A B having to receive 50,000 l. from C D takes C D's
cheque on a banker crossed, as it is called, and, therefore, only payable to another banker. He pays
that cheque to his own credit with his own banker, who presents itto the banker on whom it is drawn,
and if good it is an item between them in the general clearing or settlement of the afternoon. But this
is evidently a very refined machinery, which a panic will be apt to destroy. At the first stage A B may
say to his debtor C D, `I cannot take your cheque, I must have bank-notes.' If it is a debt on
securities, he will be very apt to say this. The usual practicecredit being goodis for the creditor to
take the debtor's cheque, and to give up the securities. But if the `securities' really secure him in a
time of difficulty, he will not like to give them up, and take a bit of paper a mere cheque, which may
be paid or not paid. He will say to his debtor, `I can only give you your securities if you will give me
banknotes.' And if he does say so, the debtor must go to his bank, and draw out the 50,000 l. if he
has it. But if this were done on a large scale, the bank's `cash in house' would soon be gone; as the
Clearing-house was gradually superseded it would have to trench on its deposit at the Bank of
England; and then the bankers would have to pay so much over the counter that they would be
unable to keep much money at the Bank, even if they wished. They would soon be obliged to draw
out every shilling.
The diminished use of the Clearing-house, in consequence of the panic, would intensify that panic.
By far the greater part of the bargains of the country in moneyed securities is settled on the Stock
Exchange twice a month, and the number of securities then given up for mere cheques, and the
number of cheques then passing at the Clearing-house are enormous. If that system collapse, the
number of failures would be incalculable, and each failure would add to the discredit that caused the
collapse.
The non-banking customers of the Bank of England would be discredited as well as other people;
their cheques would not be taken any more than those of others; they would have to draw out
banknotes, and the Bank reserve would not be enough for a tithe of such payments.
The matter would come shortly to this: a great number of brokers and dealers are under obligations
to pay immense sums, and in common times they obtain these sums by the transfer of certain
securities. If, as we said just now, No. 1 has borrowed 50,0001. of No. 2 on Exchequer bills, he, for
the most part, cannot pay No. z till he has sold or pledged those bills to some one else. But till he
has the bills he cannot pledge or sell them; and if No. 2 will not give them up till he gets his money,
No. 1 will be ruined, because he caunot pay it. And if No. 2 has No. 3 to pay, as is very likely, he
may be ruined because of No. 1's default, and No. 4 only on account of No. 3's default; and so on
without end. On settling day, without the Clearing-house, there would be a mass of failures, and a
bundle of securities. The effect of these failures would be a general run on all bankers, and on the
Bank of England particularly.
It may indeed be said that the money thus taken from the Banking Department of the Bank of
England would return there immediately; that the public who borrowed it would not know where else
to deposit it; that it would be taken out in the morning, and put back in the evening. But, in the first
place, this argument assumes that the Banking Department would have enough money to pay the
demands on it; and this is a mistake: the Banking Department would not have a hundredth part of
the necessary funds. And in the second, a great panic which deranged the Clearing-house would
soon be diffused all through the country. The money therefore taken from the Bank of England could
not be soon returned to the Bank; it would not come back on the evening of the day on which it was
taken out, or for many days; it would be distributed through the length and breadth of the country,
wherever there were bankers, wherever there was trade, wherever there were liabilities, wherever
there was terror.
And even in London, so immense a panic would soon impair the credit of the Banking Department
of the Bank of England. That department has no great prestige. It was only created in 1844, and it
has failed three times since. The world would imagine that what has happened before will happen
again; and when they have got money, they will not deposit it at an establishment which may not be
able to repay it. This did not happen in former panics, because the case we are considering never
arose. The Bank was helping the public, and, more or less confidently, it was believed that the
Government would help the Bank. But if the policy be relinquished which formerly assuaged alarm,
that alarm will be protracted and enhanced, till it touch the Banking Department of the Bank itself.
I do not imagine that it would touch the Issue Department. I think that the public would be quite
satisfied if they obtained banknotes. Generally nothing is gained by holding the notes of a bank
instead of depositing them at a bank. But in the Bank of England there is a great difference: their
notes are legal tender. Whoever holds them can always pay his debts, and, except for foreign
payments, he could want no more. The rush would be for bank-notes; those that could be obtained
would be carried north, south, east, and west, and, as there would not be enough for all the country,
the Banking Department would soon pay away all it had.
Nothing, therefore, can be more certain than that the Bank of England has in this respect no
peculiar privilege; that it is simply in the position of a Bank keeping the Banking reserve of the
country; that it must in time of panic do what all other similar banks must do; that in time of panic it
must advance freely and vigorously to the public out of the reserve.
And with the Bank of England, as with other Banks in the same case, these advances, if they are to
be made at all, should be made so as if possible to obtain the object for which they are made. The
end is to stay the panic; and the advances should, if possible, stay the panic. And for this purpose
there are two rules:First. That these loans should only be made at a very high rate of interest This
will operate as a heavy fine on unreasonable timidity, and will prevent the greatest number of
applications by persons who do not require it. The rate should be raised early in the panic, so that
the fine may be paid early; that no one may borrow out of idle precaution without paying well for it;
that the Banking reserve may be protected as far as possible.
Secondly. That at this rate these advances should be made on all good banking securities, and as
largely as the public ask for them. The reason is plain. The object is to stay alarm, and nothing
therefore should be done to cause alarm. But the way to cause alarm is to refuse some one who
has good security to offer. The news of this will spread in an instant through all the money market at
a moment of terror; no one can say exactly who carries it, but in half an hour it will be carried on all
sides, and will intensify the terror everywhere. No advances indeed need be made by which the
Bank will ultimately lose. The amount of bad business in commercial countries is an infinitesimally
small fraction of the whole business. That in a panic the bank, or banks, holding the ultimate reserve
should refuse bad bills or bad securities will not make the panic really worse; the `unsound' people
are a feeble minority, and they are afraid even to look frightened for fear their unsoundness may be
detected. The great majority, the majority to be protected, are the `sound' people, the people who
have good security to offer. If it is known that the Bank of England is freely advancing on what in
ordinary times is reckoned a good securityon what is then commonly pledged and easily
convertiblethe alarm of the solvent merchants and bankers will be stayed. But if securities, really
good and usually convertible, are refused by the Bank, the alarm will not abate, the other loans
made will fail in obtaining their end, and the panic will become worse and worse.
It may be said that the reserve in the Banking Department will not be enough for all such loans. If
that be so, the Banking Department must fail. But lending is, nevertheless, its best expedient. This is
the method of making its money go the farthest, and of enabling it to get through the panic if
anything will so enable it. Making no loans as we have seen will ruin it; making large loans and
stopping, as we have also seen, will ruin it. The only safe plan for the Bank is the brave plan, to lend
in a panic on every kind of current security, or every sort on which money is ordinarily and usually
lent. This policy may not save the Bank; but if it do not, nothing will save it.
If we examine the manner in which the Bank of England has fulfilled these duties, we shall find, as
we found before, that the true principle has never been grasped; that the policy has been
inconsistent; that, though the policy has much improved, there still remain important particulars in
which it might be better than it is. The first panic of which it is necessary here to speak, is that of
1825: I hardly think we should derive much instruction from those of 1793 and 1797; the world has
changed too much since; and during the long period of inconvertible currency from 1797 to 1819,
the problems to be solved were altogether different from our present ones. In the panic of 1825, the
Bank of England at first acted as unwisely as it was possible to act. By every means it tried to
restrict its advances. The reserve being very small, it endeavoured to protect that reserve by lending
as little as possible. The result was a period of frantic and almost inconceivable violence; scarcely
any one knew whom to trust; credit was almost suspended; the country was, as Mr. Huskisson
expressed it, within twenty-four hours of a state of barter. Applications for assistance were made to
the Government, but though it was well known that the Government refused to act, there was not, as
far as I know, until lately any authentic narrative of the real facts. In the `Correspondence' of the
Duke of Wellington, of all places in the world, there is a full account of them. The Duke was then on
a mission at St. Petersburg, and Sir R. Peel wrote to him a letter of which the following is a part:
`We have been placed in a very unpleasant predicament on the other questionthe issue of
Exchequer Bills by Government. The feeling of the City, of many of our friends, of some of the
Opposition, was decidedly in favour of the issue of Exchequer Bills to relieve the merchants and
manufacturers.
`It was said in favour of the issue, that the same measure had been tried and succeeded in 1793
and 1811. Our friends whispered about that we were acting quite in a different manner from that in
which Mr. Pitt did act, and would have acted had he been alive.
`We felt satisfied that, however plausible were the reasons urged in favour of the issue of
Exchequer Bills, yet that the measure was a dangerous one, and ought to be resisted by the
Government.
`There are thirty millions of Exchequer Bills outstanding. The purchases lately made by the Bank
can hardly maintain them at par. If there were a new issue to such an amount as that contemplated
viz., five millionsthere would be a great danger that the whole mass of Exchequer Bills would be at a
discount, and would be paid into the revenue. If the new Exchequer Bills were to be issued at a
different rate of interest from the outstanding onessay bearing an interest of five per centthe old
ones would be immediately at a great discount unless the interest were raised. If the interest were
raised, the charge on the revenue would be of course proportionate to the increase of rate of
interest. We found that the Bank had the power to lend money on deposit of goods. As our issue of
Exchequer Bills would have been useless unless the Bank cashed them, as therefore the
intervention of the Bank was in any event absolutely necessary, and as its intervention would be
chiefly useful by the effect which it would have in increasing the circulating medium, we advised the
Bank to take the whole affair into their own hands at once, to issue their notes on the security of
goods, instead of issuing them on Exchequer Bills, such bills being themselves issued on that
security.
`They reluctantly consented, and rescued us from a very embarrassing predicament.'
The success of the Bank of England on this occasion was owing to its complete adoption of right
principles. The Bank adopted these principles very late; but when it adopted them it adopted them
completely. According to the official statement which I quoted before, `we,' that is, the Bank
directors, `lent money by every possible means, and in modes which we had never adopted before;
we took in stock on security, we purchased Exchequer Bills, we made advances on Exchequer Bills,
we not only discounted outright, but we made advances on deposits of bills of Exchange to an
immense amountin short, by every possible means consistent with the safety of the Bank.' And for
the complete and courageous adoption of this policy at the last moment the directors of the Bank of
England at that time deserve great praise, for the subject was then less understood even than it is
now; but the directors of the Bank deserve also severe censure, for previously choosing a contrary
policy; for being reluctant to adopt the new one; and for at last adopting it only at the request of, and
upon a joint responsibility with, the Executive Government.
After 1825, there was not again a real panic in the money market till 1847. Both of the crises of 1837
and 1839 were severe, but neither terminated in a panic: both were arrested before the alarm
reached its final intensity; in neither, therefore, could the policy of the Bank at the last stage of fear
be tested.
In the three panics since 1844in 1847, 1857, and 866the policy of the Bank has been more or less
affected by the Act of 1844, and I cannot therefore discuss it fully within the limits which I have pre
scribed for myself. I can only state two things: First, that the directors of the Bank above all things
maintain, that they have not been in the earlier stage of pamc prevented by the Act of i 1844 from
making any advances which they would otherwise have then made. Secondly, that in the last stage
of panic, the Act of 1844 has been already suspended, rightly or wrongly, on these occasions; that
no similar occasion has ever yet occurred in which it has not been suspended; and that, rightly or
wrongly, the world confidently expects and relies that in all similar cases it will be suspended again.
Whatever theory may prescribe, the logic of facts seems peremptory so far. And these principles
taken together amount to saying that, by the doctrine of the directors, the Bank of England ought, as
far as they can, to manage a panic with the Act of 1844, pretty much as they would manage one
without itin the early stage of the panic because then they are not fettered, and in the latter because
then the fetter has been removed.
We can therefore estimate the policy of the Bank of England in the three panics which have
happened since the Act of 1844, without inquiring into the effect of the Act itself. It is certain that in
all of these panics the Bank has made very large advances indeed. It is certain, too, that in all of
them the Bank has been quicker than it was in 1825; that in all of them it has less hesitated to use
its banking reserve in making the advances which it is one principal object of maintaining that
reserve to make, and to make at once. But there is still a considerable evil. No one knows on what
kind of securities the Bank of England will at such periods make the advances which it is necessary
to make.
As we have seen, principle requires that such advances, if made at all for the purpose of curing
panic, should be made in the manner most likely to cure that panic. And for this purpose, they
should be made on everything which in common times is good `banking security.' The evil is, that
owing to terror, what is commonly good security has ceased to be so; and the true policy is so to use
the Banking reserve, that if possible the temporary evil may be stayed, and the common course of
business be restored. And this can only be effected by advancing on all good Banking securities.
Unfortunately, the Bank of England do not take this course. The Discount office is open for the
discount of good bills, and makes immense advances accordingly. The Bank also advances on
consols and India securities, though there was, in the crisis of 1866, believed to be for a moment a
hesitation in so doing. But these are only a small part of the securities on which money in ordinary
times can be readily obtained, and by which its repayment is fully secured. Railway debenture stock
is as good a security as a commercial bill, and many people, of whom I own I am one, think it safer
than India stock; on the whole, a great railway is, we think, less liable to unforeseen accidents than
the strange Empire of India. But I doubt if the Bank of England in a panic would advance on railway
debenture stock, at any rate no one has any authorised reason for saying that it would. And there
are many other such securities.
The amount of the advance is the main consideration for the Bank of England, and not the nature of
the security on which the advance is made, always assuming the security to be good. An idea
prevails (as I believe) at the Bank of England that they ought not to advance during a panic on any
kind of security on which they do not commonly advance. But if bankers for the most part do
advance on such security in common times, and if that security is indisputably good, the ordinary
practice of the Bank of England is immaterial. In ordinary times the Bank is only one of many
lenders, whereas in a panic it is the sole lender, and we want, as far as we can, to bring back the
unusual state of a time of panic to the common state of ordinary times.
In common opinion there is always great uncertainty as to the conduct of the Bank: the Bank has
never laid down any clear and sound policy on the subject. As we have seen, some of its directors
(like Mr. Hankey) advocate an erroneous policy. The public is never sure what policy will be adopted
at the most important moment: it is not sure what amount of advance will be made, or on what
security it will be made. The best palliative to a panic is a confidence in the adequate amount of the
Bank reserve, and in the efficient use of that reserve. And until we have on this point a clear
understanding with the Bank of England, both our liability to crises and our terror at crises will
always be greater than they would otherwise be.
CHAPTER VIII - The Government of the Bank of England
The Bank of England is governed by a board of directors, a Governor, and a Deputy-Governor; and
the mode in which these are chosen, and the time for which they hold office, affect the whole of its
business. The board of directors is in fact self-electing. In theory a certain portion go out annually,
remain out for a year, and are subject to re-election by the proprietors. But in fact they are nearly
always, and always if the other directors wish it, re-elected after a year. Such has been the
unbroken practice of many years, and it would be hardly possible now to break it. When a vacancy
occurs by death or resignation, the whole board chooses the new member, and they do it, as I am
told, with great care. For a peculiar reason, it is important that the directors should be young when
they begin; and accordingly the board run over the names of the most attentive and promising
young men in the old-established firms of London, and select the one who, they think, will be most
suitable for a bank director. There is a considerable ambition to fill the office. The status which is
given by it, both to the individual who fills it and to the firm of merchants to which he belongs, is
considerable. There is surprisingly little favour shown in the selection; there is a great wish on the
part of the Bank directors for the time being to provide, to the best of their ability, for the future good
government of the Bank. Very few selections in the world are made with nearly equal purity. There is
a sincere desire to do the best for the Bank, and to appoint a well-conducted young man who has
begun to attend to business, and who seems likely to be fairly sensible and fairly efficient twenty
years later.
The age is a primary matter. The offices of Governor and DeputyGovernor are given in rotation. The
Deputy-Governor always succeeds the Governor, and usually the oldest director who has not been
m office becomes Deputy-Governor. Sometimes, from personal reasons, such as ill-health or
special temporary occupation, the time at which a director becomes Deputy-Governor may be a little
deferred, and, in some few cases, merchants in the greatest business have been permitted to
decline entirely. But for all general purposes, the rule may be taken as absolute. Save in rare cases,
a director must serve his time as Governor and Deputy-Governor nearly when his turn comes, and
he will not be asked to serve much before his turn. It is usually about twenty years from the time of a
man's first election that he arrives, as it is called, at the chair. And as the offices of Governor and
Deputy-Governor are very important, a man who fills them should be still in the vigour of life.
Accordingly, Bank directors, when first chosen by the board, are always young men.
At first this has rather a singular effect; a stranger hardly knows what to make of it. Many years
since, I remember seeing a very fresh and nice-looking young gentleman, and being struck with
astonishment at being told that he was a director of the Bank of England. I had always imagined
such directors to be men of tried sagacity and long experience, and I was amazed that a cheerful
young man should be one of them. I believe I thought it was a little dangerous. I thought such young
men could not manage the Bank well. I feared they had the power to do mischief.
Further inquiry, however, soon convinced me that they had not the power. Naturally, young men
have not much influence at a board where there, are many older members. And in the Bank of
England there is a special provision for depriving them of it if they get it. Some of the directors, as I
have said, retire annually, but by courtesy it is always the young ones. Those who have passed the
chairthat is, who have served the office of Governoralways remain. The young part of the board is
the fluctuating part, and the old part is the permanent part; and therefore it is not surprising that the
young part has little influence. The Bank directors may be blamed for many things, but they cannot
be blamed for the changeableness and excitability of a neocracy.
Indeed, still better to prevent it, the elder members of the board that is, those who have passed the
chairform a standing committee of indefinite powers, which is called the Committee of Treasury. I
say `indefinite powers,' for I am not aware that any precise description has ever been given of them,
and I doubt if they can be precisely described. They are sometimes said to exercise a particular
control over the relations and negotiations between the Bank and the Government. But I confess
that I believe that this varies very much with the character of the Governor for the time being. A
strong Governor does much mainly upon his own responsibility, and a weak Governor does little.
Still the influence of the Committee of Treasury is always considerable, though not always the
same. They form a a cabinet of mature, declining, and old men, just close to the executive; and for
good or evil such a cabinet must have much power.
By old usage, the directors of the Bank of England cannot be themselves by trade bankers. This is a
relic of old times. Every bank was supposed to be necessarily, more or less, in opposition to every
other bankbanks in the same place to be especially in opposition. In consequence, in London, no
banker has a chance of being a Bank director, or would ever think of attempting to be one. I am
here speaking of bankers in the English sense, and in the sense that would surprise a foreigner.
One of the Rothschilds is on the Bank direction, and a foreigner would be apt to think that they were
bankers if any one was. But this only illustrates the essential difference between our English notions
of banking and the continental. Ours have attained a much fuller development than theirs. Messrs.
Rothschild are immense capitalists, having, doubtless, much borrowed money in their hands. But
they do not take 100 l, payable on demand, and pay it back in cheques of 5 l. each, and that is our
English banking. The borrowed money which they have is in large sums, borrowed for terms more
or less long. English bankers deal with an aggregate of small sums, all of which are repayable on
short notice, or on demand. And the way the two employ their money is different also. A foreigner
thinks `an Exchange business'that is, the buying and selling bills on foreign countriesa main part of
banking. As I have explained, remittance is one of the subsidiary conveniences which early banks
subserve before deposit banking begins. But the mass of English country bankers only give bills on
places in England or on London, and in London the principal remittance business has escaped out
of the hands of the bankers. Most of them would not know how to carry through a great `Exchange
operation,' or to `bring home the returns.' They would as soon think of turning silk merchants. The
Exchange trade is carried on by a small and special body of foreign bill-brokers, of whom Messrs.
Rothschild are the greatest. One of that firm may, therefore, well be on the Bank direction,
notwithstanding the rule forbidding bankers to be there, for he and his family are not English
bankers, either by the terms on which they borrow money, or the mode in which they employ it. But
as to bankers in the English sense of the word, the rule is rigid and absolute. Not only no private
banker is a director of the Bank of England, but no director of any joint stock bank would be allowed
to become such. The two situations would be taken to be incompatible.
The mass of the Bank directors are merchants of experience, employing a considerable capital in
trades in which they have been brought up, and with which they are well acquainted. Many of them
have information as to the present course of trade, and as to the character and wealth of merchants,
which is most valuable, or rather is all but invaluable, to the Bank. Many of them, too, are quiet,
serious men, who, by habit and nature, watch with some kind of care every kind of business in
which they are engaged, and give an anxious opinion on it. Most of them have a good deal of
leisure, for the life of a man of business who employs only his own capital, and employs it nearly
always in the same way, is by no means fully employed. Hardly any capital is enough to employ the
principal partner's time, and if such a man is very busy, it is a sign of something wrong. Either he is
working at detail, which subordinates would do better, and which he had better leave alone, or he is
engaged in too many speculations, is incurring more liabilities than his capital will bear, and so may
be ruined. In consequence, every commercial city abounds in men who have great business ability
and experience, who are not fully occupied, who wish to be occupied, and who are very glad to
become directors of public companies in order to be occupied. The direction of the Bank of England
has, for many generations, been composed of such men.
Such a government for a joint stock company is very good if its essential nature be attended to, and
very bad if that nature be not attended to. That government is composed of men with a high average
of general good sense, with an excellent knowledge of business in general, but without any special
knowledge of the particular business in which they are engaged. Ordinarily, in joint stock banks and
companies this deficiency is cured by the selection of a manager of the company, who has been
specially trained to that particular trade, and who engages to devote all his experience and all his
ability to the affairs of the company. The directors, and often a select committee of them more
especially, consult with the manager, and after hearing what he has to say, decide on the affairs of
the company. There is in all ordinary joint stock companies a fixed executive specially skilled, and a
somewhat varying council not specially skilled. The fixed manager ensures continuity and
experience in the management, and a good board of directors ensures general wisdom.
But in the Bank of England there is no fixed executive. The Governor and Deputy-Governor, who
form that executive, change every two years. I believe, indeed, that such was not the original
intention of the founders. In the old days of few and great privileged companies, the chairman,
though periodically elected, was practically permanent so long as his policy was popular. He was
the head of the ministry, and ordinarily did not change unless the opposition came in. But this idea
has no present relation to the constitution of the Bank of England. At present, the Governor and
Deputy-Governor almost always change at the end of two years; the case of any longer occupation
of the chair is so very rare, that it need not be taken account of. And the Governor and Deputy-
Governor of the Bank cannot well be shadows. They are expected to be constantly present; to see
all applicants for advances out of the ordinary routine; to carry on the almost continuous
correspondence between the Bank and its largest customerthe Government; to bring all necessary
matters before the board of directors or the Committee of Treasury,in a word, to do very much of
what falls to the lot of the manager in most companies. Under this shifting chief executive, there are
indeed very valuable heads of departments. The head of the Discount Department is especially
required to be a man of ability and experience. But these officers are essentially subordinate; no
one of them is like the general manager of an ordinary bankthe head of all action. The perpetually
present executivethe Governor and Deputy-Governormake it impossible that any subordinate should
have that position. A really able and active-minded Governor, being required to sit all day in the
bank, in fact does, and can hardly help doing, its principal business.
In theory, nothing can be worse than this government for a bank a shifting executive; a board of
directors chosen too young for it to be known whether they are able; a committee of management, in
which seniority is the necessary qualification, and old age the common result; and no trained
bankers anywhere.
Even if the Bank of England were an ordinary bank, such a constitution would be insufficient; but its
inadequacy is greater, and the consequences of that inadequacy far worse, because of its greater
functions. The Bank of England has to keep the sole banking reserve of the country; has to keep it
through all changes of the money market, and all turns of the Exchanges; has to decide on the
instant in a panic what sort of advances should be made, to what amounts, and for what dates;and
yet it has a constitution plainly defective. So far the government of the Bank of England being better
than that of any other bankas it ought to be, considering that its functions are much harder and
graverany one would be laughed at who proposed it as a model for the government of a new bank;
and that government, if it were so proposed, would on all hands be called old-fashioned, and
curious.
As was natural, the effectsgood and evilof its constitution are to be seen in every part of the Bank's
history. On one vital point the Bank's management has been excellent. It has done perhaps less
`bad business,' certainly less very bad business, than any bank of the same size and the same age.
In all its history I do not know that its name has ever been connected with a single large and
discreditable bad debt. There has never been a suspicion that it was `worked' for the benefit of any
one man, or any combination of men. The great respectability of the directors, and the steady
attention many of them have always given the business of the Bank, have kept it entirely free from
anything dishonorable and discreditable. Steady merchants collected in council are an admirable
judge of bills and securities. They always know the questionable standing of dangerous persons;
they are quick to note the smallest signs of corrupt transactions; and no sophistry will persuade the
best of them out of their good instincts. You could not have made the directors of the Bank of
England do the sort of business which `Overends' at last did, except by a moral miracleexcept by
changing their nature. And the fatal career of the Bank of the United States would, under their
management, have been equally impossible. Of the ultimate solvency of the Bank of England, or of
the eventual safety of its vast capital, even at the worst periods of its history, there has not been the
least doubt.
But nevertheless, as we have seen, the policy of the Bank has frequently been deplorable, and at
such times the defects of its government have aggravated if not caused its calamities.
In truth the executive of the Bank of England is now much such as the executive of a public
department of the Foreign Office or the Home Office would be in which there was no responsible
permanent head. In these departments of Government, the actual chief changes nearly, though not
quite, as often as the Governor of the Bank of England. The Parliamentary Under-Secretarythe
Deputy-Governor, so to speak, of that officechanges nearly as often. And if the administration solely,
or in its details, depended on these two, it would stop. New men could not carry it on with vigour and
efficiency; indeed they could not carry it on at all. But, in fact, they are assisted by a permanent
Under-Secretary, who manages all the routine business, who is the depository of the secrets of the
office, who embodies its traditions, who is the hyphen between changing administrations. In
consequence of this assistance, the continuous business of the department is, for the most part,
managed sufficiently well, notwithstanding frequent changes in the heads of administration. And it is
only by such assistance that such business could be so managed. The present administration of the
Bank is an attempt to manage a great, a growing, and a permanently continuous business without
an adequate permanent element, and a competent connecting link.
In answer, it may be said that the duties which press on the Governor and Deputy-Governor of the
Bank are not so great or so urgent as those which press upon the heads of official departments.
And perhaps, in point of mere labour, the Governor of the Bank has the advantage. Banking never
ought to be an exceedingly laborious trade. There must be a great want of system and a great
deficiency in skilled assistance if extreme labour is thrown upon the chief. But in importance, the
functions of the head of the Bank rank as high as those of any department. The cash reserve of the
country is as precious a deposit as any set of men can have the care of. And the difficulty of dealing
with a panic (as the administration of the Bank is forced to deal with it) is perhaps a more formidable
instant difficulty than presses upon any single minister. At any rate, it comes more suddenly, and
must be dealt with more immediately, than most comparable difficulties; and the judgment, the
nerve, and the vigour needful to deal with it are plainly rare and great.
The natural remedy would be to appoint a permanent Governor of the Bank. Nor, as I have said, can
there be much doubt that such was the intention of its founders. All the old companies which have
their beginning in the seventeenth century had the same constitution, and those of them which have
lingered down to our time retain it. The Hudson's Bay Company, the South Sea Company, the East
India Company, were all founded with a sort of sovereign executive, intended to be permanent, and
intended to be efficient. This is, indeed, the most natural mode of forming a company in the minds of
those to whom companies are new. Such persons will have always seen business transacted a
good deal despotically; they will have learnt the value of prompt decision and of consistent policy;
they will have often seen that business is best managed when those who are conducting it could
scarcely justify the course they are pursuing by distinct argument which others could understand. All
`city' people make their money by investments, for which there are often good argumentative
reasons; but they would hardly ever be able, if required before a Parliamentary committee, to state
those reasons. They have become used to act on them without distinctly analysing them, and, in a
monarchical way, with continued success only as a test of their goodness. Naturally such persons,
when proceeding to form a company, make it upon the model of that which they have been used to
see successful. They provide for the executive first and above all things. How much this was in the
minds of the founders of the Bank of England may be judged of by the name which they gave it. Its
corporate name is the `Governor and Company of the Bank of England.' So important did the
founders think the executive that they mentioned it distinctly, and mentioned it first.
And not only is this constitution of a company the most natural in the early days when companies
were new, it is also that which experience has shown to be the most efficient now that companies
have long been tried. Great railway companies are managed upon no other. Scarcely any instance
of great success in a railway can be mentioned in which the chairman has not been an active and
judicious man of business, constantly attending to the affairs of the company. A thousand instances
of railway disaster can be easily found in which the chairman was only a nominal heada nobleman,
or something of that sort-chosen for show. `Railway chairmanship' has become a profession, so
much is efficiency valued in it, and so indispensable has ability been found to be. The plan of
appointing a permanent `chairman' at the Bank of England is strongly supported by much modern
experience.
Nevertheless, I hesitate as to its expediency; at any rate, there are other plans which, for several
reasons, should, I think, first be tried in preference.
First. This plan would be exceedingly unpopular. A permanent Governor of the Bank of England
would be one of the greatest men in England. He would be a little `monarch' in the City; he would be
far greater than the `Lord Mayor.' He would be the personal embodiment of the Bank of England; he
would be constantly clothed with an almost indefinite prestige. Everybody in business would bow
down before him and try to stand well with him, for he might in a panic be able to save almost
anyone he liked, and to ruin almost anyone he liked. A day might come when his favour might mean
prosperity, and his distrust might mean ruin. A position with so much real power and so much
apparent dignity would be intensely coveted. Practical men would be apt to say that it was better
than the Prime Ministership, for it would last much longer, and would have a greater jurisdiction over
that which practical men would most value,over money. At all events, such a Governor, if he
understood his business, might make the fortunes of fifty men where the Prime Minister can make
that of one. Scarcely anything could be more unpopular in the City than the appointment of a little
king to reign over them.
Secondly. I do not believe that we should always get the best man for the post; often I fear that we
should not even get a tolerable man. There are many cases in which the offer of too high a pay
would prevent our obtaining the man we wish for, and this is one of them. A very high pay of
prestige is almost always very dangerous. It causes the post to be desired by vain men, by lazy
men, by men of rank; and when that post is one of real and technical business, and when, therefore,
it requires much previous training, much continuous labour, and much patient and quick judgment,
all such men are dangerous. But they are sure to covet all posts of splendid dignity, and can only be
kept out of them with the greatest difficulty. Probably, in every Cabinet there are still some members
(in the days of the old close boroughs there were many) whose posts have come to them not from
personal ability or inherent merit, but from their rank, their wealth, or even their imposing exterior.
The highest political offices are, indeed, kept clear of such people, for in them serious and important
duties must constantly be performed in the face of the world. A Prime Minister, or a Chancellor of
the Exchequer, or a Secretary of State must explain his policy and defend his actions in Parliament,
and the discriminating tact of a critical assemblyabounding in experience, and guided by traditionwill
soon discover what he is. But the Governor of the Bank would only perform quiet functions, which
look like routine, though they are not, m which there is no immediate risk of success or failure; which
years hence may indeed issue in a crop of bad debts, but which any grave persons may make at the
time to look fair and plausible. A large Bank is exactly the place where a vain and shallow person in
authority, if he be a man of gravity and method, as such men often are, may do infinite evil in no
long time, and before he is detected. If he is lucky enough to begin at a time of expansion in trade,
he is nearly sure not to be found out till the time of contraction has arrived, and then very large
figures will be required to reckon the evil he has done.
And thirdly,I fear that the possession of such patronage would ruin any set of persons in whose gift it
was. The election of the Chairman must be placed either in the court of proprietors or that of the
directors. If the proprietors choose, there will be something like the evils of an American presidential
election. Bank stock will be bought in order to confer the qualification of voting at the election of the
`chief of the City.' The Chairman, when elected, may well find that his most active supporters are
large borrowers of the Bank, and he may well be puzzled to decide between his duty to the Bank
and his gratitude to those who chose him. Probably, if he be a cautious man of average ability, he
will combine both evils; he will not lend so much money as he is asked for, and so will offend his
own supporters; but will lend some which will be lost, and so the profits of the Bank will be reduced.
A large body of Bank proprietors would make but a bad elective body for an office of great prestige;
they would not commonly choose a good person, and the person they did choose would be bound
by promises that would make him less good.
The court of directors would choose better; a small body of men of business would not easily be
persuaded to choose an extremely unfit man. But they would not often choose an extremely good
man. The really best man would probably not be so rich as the majority of the directors, nor of so
much standing, and not unnaturally they would much dislike to elevate to the headship of the City,
one who was much less in the estimation of the City than themselves. And they would be canvassed
in every way and on every side to appoint a man of mercantile dignity or mercantile influence. Many
people of the greatest prestige and rank in the City would covet so great a dignity; if not for
themselves, at least for some friend, or some relative, and so the directors would be set upon from
every side.
An election so liable to be disturbed by powerful vitiating causes would rarely end in a good choice.
The best candidate would almost never be chosen; often, I fear, one would be chosen altogether
unfit for a post so important. And the excitement of so keen an election would altogether disturb the
quiet of the Bank. The good and efficient working of a board of Bank directors depends on its
internal harmony, and that harmony would be broken for ever by the excitement, the sayings, and
the acts of a great election. The board of directors would almost certainly be demoralised by having
to choose a sovereign, and there is no certainty, nor any great likelihood, indeed, that they would
choose a good one. In France the difficulty of finding a good body to choose the Governor of the
Bank has been met characteristically. The Bank of France keeps the money of the State, and the
State appoints its governor. The French have generally a logical reason to give for all they do,
though perhaps the results of their actions are not always so good as the reasons for them. The
Governor of the Bank of France has not always, I am told, been a very competent person; the Sub-
Governor, whom the State also appoints, is, as we might expect, usually better. But for our English
purposes it would be useless to inquire minutely into this. No English statesman would consent to
be responsible for the choice of the Governor of the Bank of England. After every panic, the
Opposition would say in Parliament that the calamity had been `grievously aggravated,' if not wholly
caused, by the `gross misconduct' of the Governor appointed by the ministry. Or, possibly, offices
may have changed occupants and the ministry in power at the panic would be the opponents of the
ministry which at a former time appointed the Governor. In that case they would be apt to feel, and
to intimate, a `grave regret' at the course which the nominee of their adversaries had `thought it
desirable to pursue.' They would not much mind hurting his feelings, and if he resigned they would
have themselves a valuable piece of patronage to confer on one of their own friends. No result
could be worse than that the conduct of the Bank and the management should be made a matter of
party politics, and men of all parties would agree in this, even if they agreed in almost nothing else.
I am therefore afraid that we must abandon the plan of improving the government of the Bank of
England by the appointment of a permanent Governor, because we should not be sure of choosing
a good governor, and should indeed run a great risk, for the most part, of choosing a bad one.
I think, however, that much of the advantage, with little of the risk, might be secured by a humbler
scheme. In English political offices, as was observed before, the evil of a changing head is made
possible by the permanence of a dignified subordinate. Though the Parliamentary Secretary of State
and the Parliamentary Under-Secretary go in and out with each administration, another Under-
Secretary remains through all such changes, and is on that account called `permanent.' Now this
system seems to me in its principle perfectly applicable to the administration of the Bank of
England. For the reasons which have just been given, a permanent ruler of the Bank of England
cannot be appointed; for other reasons, which were just before given, some most influential
permanent functionary is essential in the proper conduct of the business of the Bank; and, mutatis
mutandis, these are the very difficulties, and the very advantages which have led us to frame our
principal offices of state in the present fashion.
Such a Deputy-Governor would not be at all a `king' in the City. There would be no mischievous
prestige about the office; there would be no attraction in it for a vain man; and there would be
nothing to make it an object of a violent canvass or of unscrupulous electioneering. The office would
be essentially subordinate in its character, just like the permanent secretary in a political office. The
pay should be high, for good ability is wantedbut no pay would attract the most dangerous class of
people. The very influential, but not very wise, City dignitary who would be so very dangerous is
usually very opulent; he would hardly have such influence he were not opulent: what he wants is not
money, but `position.' A Governorship of the Bank of England he would take almost without salary;
perhaps he would even pay to get it: but a minor office of essential subordination would not attract
him at all. We may augment the pay enough to get a good man, without fearing that by such pay we
may temptas by social privilege we should temptexactly the sort of man we do not want.
Undoubtedly such a permanent official should be a trained banker. There is a cardinal difference
between banking and other kinds of commerce; you can afford to run much less risk in banking than
in commerce, and you must take much greater precautions. In common business, the trader can
add to the cost price of the goods he sells a large mercantile profit, say 10 to 15 per cent; but the
banker has to be content with the interest of money, which in England is not so much as per cent
upon the average. The business of a banker therefore cannot bear so many bad debts as that of a
merchant, and he must be much more cautious to whom he gives credit. Real money is a
commodity much more coveted than common goods: for one deceit which is attempted on a
manufacturer or a merchant, twenty or more are attempted on a banker. And besides, a banker,
dealing with the money of others, and money payable on demand, must be always, as it were,
looking behind him and seeing that he has reserve enough in store if payment should be asked for,
which a merchant dealing mostly with his own capital need not think of. Adventure is the life of
commerce, but caution, I had almost said timidity, is the life of banking; and I cannot imagine that
the long series of great errors made by the Bank of England in the management of its reserve till
after 1857, would have been possible if the merchants in the Bank court had not erroneously taken
the same view of the Bank's business that they must properly take of their own mercantile business.
The Bank directors have almost always been too cheerful as to the Bank's business, and too little
disposed to take alarm. What we want to introduce into the Bank court is a wise apprehensiveness,
and this every trained banker is taught by the habits of his trade, and the atmosphere of his life.
The permanent Governor ought to give his whole time to the business of the Bank. He ought to be
forbidden to engage in any other concern. All the present directors, including the Governor and
Deputy-Governor, are engaged in their own business, and it is very possible, indeed it must
perpetually have happened, that their own business as merchants most occupied the minds of most
of them just when it was most important that the business of the Bank should occupy them. It is at a
panic and just before a panic that the business of the Bank is most exacting and most engrossing.
But just at that time the business of most merchants must be unusually occupying and may be
exceedingly critical. By the present constitution of the Bank, the attention of its sole rulers is most
apt to be diverted from the Bank's affairs just when those affairs require that attention the most. And
the only remedy is the appointment of a permanent and influential man, who will have no business
save that of the Bank, and who therefore presumably will attend most to it at the critical instant when
attention is most required. His mind, at any rate, will in a panic be free from pecuniary anxiety,
whereas many, if not all, of the present directors must be incessantly thinking of their own affairs
and unable to banish them from their minds.
The permanent Deputy-Governor must be a director and a man of fair position. He must not have to
say `Sir' to the Governor. There is no fair argument between an inferior who has to exhibit respect
and a superior who has to receive respect. The superior can always, and does mostly, refute the
bad arguments of his inferior; but the inferior rarely ventures to try to refute the bad arguments of his
superior. And he still more rarely states his case effectually; he pauses, hesitates, does not use the
best word or the most apt illustration, perhaps he uses a faulty illustration or a wrong word, and so
fails because the superior immediately exposes him. Important business can only be sufficiently
discussed by persons who can say very much what they like very much as they like to one another.
The thought of the speaker should come out as it was in his mind, and not be hidden in respectful
expressions or enfeebled by affected doubt. What is wanted at the Bank is not a new clerk to the
directorsthey have excellent clerks of great experience nowbut a permanent equal to the directors,
who shall be able to discuss on equal terms with them the business of the Bank, and have this
advantage over them in discussion, that he has no other business than that of the Bank to think of.
The formal duties of such a permanent officer could only be defined by some one conversant with
the business of the Bank, and could scarcely be intelligibly discussed before the public. Nor are the
precise duties of the least importance. Such an officer, if sound, able, and industrious, would soon
rule the affairs of the Bank. He would be acquainted better than anyone else, both with the traditions
of the past and with the facts of the present; he would have a great experience; he would have seen
many anxious times; he would always be on the watch for their recurrence. And he would have a
peculiar power of guidance at such moments from the nature of the men with whom he has most to
deal. Most Governors of the Bank of England are cautious merchants, not profoundly skilled in
banking, but most anxious that their period of office should be prosperous and that they should
themselves escape censure. If a `safe' course is pressed upon them they are likely to take that
course. Now it would almost always be `safe' to follow the advice of the great standing `authority'; it
would always be most `unsafe' not to follow it. If the changing Governor act on the advice of the
permanent Deputy-Governor, most of the blame in case of mischance would fall on the latter; it
would be said that a shifting officer like the Governor might very likely not know what should be
done, but that the permanent official was put there to know it and paid to know it. But if, on the other
hand, the changing Governor should disregard the advice of his permanent colleague, and the
consequence should be bad, he would be blamed exceedingly. It would be said that, `being without
experience, he had taken upon him to overrule men who had much experience; that when the
constitution of the Bank had provided them with skilled counsel, he had taken on himself to act of
his own head, and to disregard that counsel;' and so on ad infinitum. And there could be no sort of
conversation more injurious to a man in the City; the world there would say, rightly or wrongly, `We
must never be too severe on errors of judgment; we are all making them every day; if responsible
persons do their best we can expect no more. But this case is different: the Governor acted on a
wrong system; he took upon himself an unnecessary responsibility:' and so a Governor who
incurred disaster by disregarding his skilled counsellor would be thought a fool in the City for ever.
In consequence, the one skilled counsellor would in fact rule the Bank. I believe that the
appointment of the new permanent and skilled authority at the Bank is the greatest reform which
can be made there, and that which is most wanted. I believe that such a person would give to the
decision of the Bank that foresight, that quickness, and that consistency m which those decisions
are undeniably now deficient. As far as I can judge, this change in the constitution of the Bank is by
far the most necessary, and is perhaps more important even than all other changes. But,
nevertheless, we should reform the other points which we have seen to be defective.
First, the London bankers should not be altogether excluded from the court of directors. The old
idea, as I have explained, was that the London bankers were the competitors of the Bank of
England, and would hurt it if they could. But now the London bankers have another relation to the
Bank which did not then exist, and was not then imagined. Among private people they are the
principal depositors in the Bank; they are therefore particularly interested in its stability; they are
especially interested in the maintenance of a good banking reserve, for their own credit and the
safety of their large deposits depend on it. And they can bring to the court of directors an experience
of banking itself, got outside the Bank of England, which none of the present directors possess, for
they have learned all they know of banking at the Bank itself. There was also an old notion that the
secrets of the Bank would be divulged if they were imparted to bankers. But probably bankers are
better trained to silence and secrecy than most people. And there is only a thin partition now
between the bankers and the secrets of the Bank. Only lately a firm failed of which one partner was
a director of the London and Westminster Bank, and another a director of the Bank of England.
Who can define or class the confidential communications of such persons under such
circumstances?
As I observed before, the line drawn at present against bankers is very technical and exclusively
English. According to continental ideas, Messrs. Rothschild are bankers, if any one is a banker. But
the house of Rothschild is represented on the Bank direction. And it is most desirable that it should
be represented, for members of that firm can give if they choose confidential information of great
value to the Bank. But, nevertheless, the objection which is urged against English bankers is at least
equally applicable to these foreign bankers. They have, or may have, at certain periods an interest
opposite to the policy of the Bank. As the greatest Exchange dealers, they may wish to export gold
just when the Bank of England is raising its rate of interest to prevent anyone from exporting gold.
The vote of a great Exchange dealer might be objected to for plausible reasons of contrary interest,
if any such reasons were worth regarding. But in fact the particular interest of single directors is not
to be regarded; almost all directors who bring special information labour under a suspicion of
interest; they can only have acquired that information in present business, and such business may
very possibly be affected for good or evil by the policy of the Bank. But you must not on this account
seal up the Bank hermetically against living information; you must make a fair body of directors
upon the whole, and trust that the bias of some individual interests will disappear and be lost in the
whole. And if this is to be the guiding principle, it is not consistent to exclude English bankers from
the court.
Objection is often also taken to the constitution of the Committee of Treasury. That body is
composed of the Governor and Deputy-Governor and all the directors who have held those offices;
but as those offices in the main pass in rotation, this mode of election very much comes to an
election by seniority, and there are obvious objections to giving, not only a preponderance to age,
but a monopoly to age. In some cases, indeed, this monopoly I believe has already been infringed.
When directors have on account of the magnitude of their transactions, and the consequent
engrossing nature of their business, declined to fill the chair, in some cases they have been asked
to be members of the Committee of Treasury notwithstanding. And it would certainly upon principle
seem wiser to choose a committee which for some purposes approximates to a committee of
management by competence rather than by seniority.
An objection is also taken to the large number of Bank directors. There are twenty-four directors, a
Governor and a Deputy-Governor, making a total court of twenty-six persons, which is obviously too
large for the real discussion of any difficult business. And the case is worse because the court only
meets once a week, and only sits a very short time. It has been said, with exaggeration, but not
without a basis of truth, that if the Bank directors were to sit for four hours, there would be `a panic
solely from that.' `The court,' says Mr. Tooke, `meets at half-past eleven or twelve; and, if the sitting
be prolonged beyond half-past one, the Stock Exchange and the money market become excited,
under the idea that a change of importance is under discussion; and persons congregate about the
doors of the Bank parlour to obtain the earliest intimation of the decision.' And he proceeds to
conjecture that the knowledge of the impatience without must cause haste, if not impatience, within.
That the decisions of such a court should be of incalculable importance is plainly very strange.
There should be no delicacy as to altering the constitution of the Bank of England. The existing
constitution was framed in times that have passed away, and was intended to be used for purposes
very different from the present. The founders may have considered that it would lend money to the
Government, that it would keep the money of the Government, that it would issue notes payable to
bearer, but that it would keep the `Banking reserve' of a great nation no one in the seventeenth
century imagined. And when the use to which we are putting an old thing is a new use, in common
sense we should think whether the old thing is quite fit for the use to which we are setting it. `Putting
new wine into old bottles' is safe only when you watch the condition of the bottle, and adapt its
structure most carefully.
CHAPTER IX - The Joint Stock Banks
The Joint Stock Banks of this country are a most remarkable success. Generally speaking the
career of Joint Stock Companies in this country has been chequered. Adam Smith, many years
since, threw out many pregnant hints on the difficulty of such undertakingshints which even after so
many years will well repay perusal. But joint stock banking has been an exception to this rule. Four
years ago I threw together the facts on the subject and the reasons for them; and I venture to quote
the article, because subsequent experience suggests, I think, little to be added to it.
`The main classes of joint stock companies which have answered are three:1st. Those in which the
capital is used not to work the business but to guarantee the business. Thus a banker's business his
proper businessdoes not begin while he is using his own money: it commences when he begins to
use the capital of others. An insurance office in the long run needs no capital; the premiums which
are received ought to exceed the claims which accrue. In both cases, the capital is wanted to assure
the public and to induce it to trust the concern. 2ndly. Those companies have answered which have
an exclusive privilege which they have used with judgment, or which possibly was so very profitable
as to enable them to thrive with little judgment. 3rdly. Those which have undertaken a business both
large and simple employing more money than most individuals or private firms have at command,
and yet such that, in Adam Smith's words, "the operations are capable of being reduced to a routine
or such an uniformity of method as admits of no variation.
`As a rule, the most profitable of these companies are banks. Indeed, all the favouring conditions
just mentioned concur in many banks. An old-established bank has a "prestige," which amounts to a
"privileged opportunity"; though no exclusive right is given to it by law, a peculiar power is given to it
by opinion. The business of banking ought to be simple; if it is hard it is wrong. The only securities
which a banker, using money that he may be asked at short notice to repay, ought to touch, are
those which are easily saleable and easily intelligible. If there is a difficulty or a doubt, the security
should be declined. No business can of course be quite reduced to fixed rules. There must be
occasional cases which no pre-conceived theory can define. But banking comes as near to fixed
rules certainly as any existing business, perhaps as any possible business. The business of an old-
established bank has the full advantage of being a simple business, and in part the advantage of
being a monopoly business. Competition with it is only open in the sense in which competition with
"the London Tavern" is open; anyone that has to do with either will pay dear for it.
`But the main source of the profitableness of established banking is the smallness of the requisite
capital. Being only wanted as a "moral influence," it need not be more than is necessary to secure
that influence. Although, therefore, a banker deals only with the most sure securities, and with those
which yield the least interest, he can nevertheless gain and divide a very large profit upon his own
capital, because the money in his hands is so much larger than that capital.
`Experience, as shown by plain figures, confirms these conclusions. We print at the end of this
article the respective profits of I 10 banks in England, and Scotland, and Ireland, being all in those
countries of which we have sufficient informationthe Bank of England excepted. There are no doubt
others, but they are not quoted even on local Stock Exchange lists, and in most cases publish no
reports. The result of these banks, as regards the dividends they pay, is
No. of Companies Capital
£
Above 20 per cent 15 5,302,767
Between 15 and 20 per cent 20 5,439,439
10 and 15 per cent 36 14,056,950
5 and 10 per cent 36 14,182,379
Under 5 per cent 3 1,350,000
110 40,331,535
that is to say, above 25 per cent of the capital employed in these banks pays over 15 per cent, and
62 ½ per cent of the capital pays more than 10 per cent. So striking a result is not to be shown in
any other joint stock trade.
`The period to which these accounts refer was certainly not a particularly profitable oneon the
contrary, it has been specially unprofitable. The rate of interest has been very low, and the amount
of good security in the market small. Many banksto some extent most banksprobably had in their
books painful reminiscences of 1866. The fever of excitement which passed over the nation was
strongest in the classes to whom banks lent most, and consequently the losses of even the most
careful banks (save of those in rural and sheltered situations) were probably greater than usual. But
even tried by this very unfavourable test banking is a trade profitable far beyond the average of
trades.
`There is no attempt in these banks on the whole and as a rule to divide too muchon the contrary,
they have accumulated about 13,000,000 l., or nearly 1/3 rd of their capital, principally out of
undivided profits. The directors of some of them have been anxious to put away as much as
possible and to divide as little as possible.
`The reason is plain; out of the banks which pay more than 20 per cent, all but one were old-
established banks, and all those paying between 15 and 20 per cent were old banks too. The
"privileged opportunity" of which we spoke is singularly conspicuous in such figures; it enables
banks to pay much, which without it would not have paid much. The amount of the profit is clearly
proportional to the value of the "privileged opportunity." All the banks which pay above 20 per cent,
save one, are banks more than 25 years old; all those which pay between 15 and 20 are so too. A
new bank could not make these profits, or even by its competition much reduce these profits; in
attempting to do so, it would simply ruin itself. Not possessing the accumulated credit of years, it
would have to wind up before it attained that credit.
`The value of the opportunity too is proportioned to what has to be paid for it. Some old banks have
to pay interest for all their money; some have much for which they pay nothing. Those who give
much to their customers have of course less left for their shareholders. Thus Scotland, where there
is always a daily interest, has no bank in the lists paying over 15 per cent. The profits of Scotch
banks run thus:
Capital Dividend
£
Bank of Scotland 1,500,000 12
British Linen Company 1,000,000 3
Caledonian 125,000 10
Clydesdale 900,000 10
Commercial Bank of Scotland 1,000,000 13
National Bank of Scotland 1,000,000 112
North of Scotland 280,000 10
Union Bank of Scotland 1,000,000 10
City of Glasgow 870,000 8
Royal Bank 2.000.000 8
9,675,000
Good profits enough, but not at all like the profits of the London and Westminster, or the other most
lucrative banks of the South.
`The Bank of England, it is true, does not seem to pay so much as other English banks in this way
of reckoning. It makes an immense profit, but then its capital is immense too. In fact, the Bank of
England suffers under two difficulties. Being much older than the other joint stock banks, it belongs
to a less profitable era. When it was founded, banks looked rather to the profit on their own capital,
and to the gains of note issue than to the use of deposits. The first relations with the State were
more like those of a finance company than of a bank, as we now think of banking. If the Bank had
not made loans to the Government, which we should now think dubious, the Bank would not have
existed, for the Government would never have permitted it. Not only is the capital of the Bank of
England relatively greater, but the means of making profit in the Bank of England are relatively less
also. By custom and understanding the Bank of England keep a much greater reserve in
unprofitable cash than other banks; if they do not keep it, either our whole system must be changed
or we should break up in utter bankruptcy. The earning faculty of the Bank of England is in
proportion less than that of other banks, and also the sum on which it has to pay dividend is
altogether greater than theirs.
`It is interesting to compare the facts of joint stock banking with the fears of it which were felt. In
1832, Lord Overstone observed:"I think that joint stock banks are deficient in everything requisite for
the conduct of the banking business except extended responsibility; the banking business requires
peculiarly persons attentive to all its details, constantly, daily, and hourly watchful of every
transaction, much more than mercantile or trading business. It also requires immediate prompt
decisions upon circumstances when they arise, in many cases a decision that does not admit of
delay for consultation; it also requires a discretion to be exercised with reference to the special
circumstances of each case. Joint stock banks being of course obliged to act through agents and
not by a principal, and therefore under the restraint of general rules, cannot be guided by so nice a
reference to degrees of difference in the character of responsibility of parties; nor can they
undertake to regulate the assistance to be granted to concerns under temporary embarrassment by
so accurate a reference to the circumstances, favourable or unfavourable, of each case."
`But in this very respect, joint stock banks have probably improved the business of banking. The old
private banks in former times used to lend much to private individuals; the banker, as Lord
Overstone on another occasion explained, could have no security, but he formed his judgment of
the discretion, the sense, and the solvency of those to whom he lent. And when London was by
comparison a small city, and when by comparison everyone stuck to his proper business, this
practice might have been safe. But now that London is enormous and that no one can watch
anyone, such a trade would be disastrous; at present, it would hardly be safe in a country town. The
joint stock banks were quite unfit for the business Lord Overstone meant, but then that business is
quite unfit for the present time.
This success of Joint Stock Banking is very contrary to the general expectation at its origin. Not only
private bankers, such as Lord Overstone then was, but a great number of thinking persons feared
that the joint stock banks would fast ruin themselves, and then cause a collapse and panic in the
country. The whole of English commercial literature between 1830 and 1840 is filled with that idea.
Nor did it cease in 1840. So late as 1845, Sir R. Peel thought the foundation of joint stock banks so
dangerous that he subjected it to grave and exceptional difficulty. Under the Act of 1845, which he
proposed, no such companies could be founded except with shares of 100 l. with 50 l.; paid up on
each; which effectually checked the progress of such banks, for few new ones were established for
many years, or till that act had been repealed. But in this, as in many other cases, perhaps Sir R.
Peel will be found to have been clear-sighted rather than far-sighted. He was afraid of certain joint
stock banks which he saw rising around him; but the effect of his legislation was to give to these
very banks, if not a monopoly, at any rate an exemption from new rivals. No one now founds or can
found a new private bank, and Sir R. Peel by law prevented new joint stock banks from being
established. Though he was exceedingly distrustful of the joint stock banks founded between 1826
and 1845, yet in fact he was their especial patron, and he more than any other man encouraged and
protected them.
But in this wonderful success there are two dubious points, two considerations of different kinds,
which forbid us to say that in other countries, even in countries with the capacity of co-operation,
joint stock banks would succeed as well as we have seen that they succeed in England. 1st. These
great Banks have not had to keep so large a reserve against their liabilities as it was natural that
they should, being of first-rate magnitude, keep. They were at first, of course, very small in
comparison with what they are now. They found a number of private bankers grouped round the
Bank of England, and they added themselves to the group. Not only did they keep their reserve from
the beginning at the Bank of England, but they did not keep so much reserve as they would have
kept if there had been no Bank of England. For a long time this was hardly noticed. For many years
questions of the `currency,' particularly questions as to the Act of 1844, engrossed the attention of
all who were occupied with these subjects. Even those who were most anxious to speak evil of joint
stock banks, did not mention this particular evil. The first time, as far as I know, that it was
commented on in any important document, was in an official letter written in 1857 by Mr. Weguelin,
who was then Governor of the Bank, to Sir George Lewis, who was then Chancellor of the
Exchequer. The Governor and the Directors of the Bank of England had been asked by Sir George
Lewis severally to give their opinions on the Act of 1 844, and all their replies were published. In his,
Mr. Weguelin says:
`If the amount of the reserve kept by the Bank of England be contrasted with the reserve kept by the
joint stock banks, a new and hitherto little considered source of danger to the credit of the country
will present itself. The joint stock banks of London, judging by their published accounts, have
deposits to the amount of 30,000,000 l. Their capital is not more than 3,000,000 l., and they have on
an average 31,000,000 l., invested in one way or another, leaving only 2,000,000 l. as a reserve
against all this mass of liabilities.'
But these remarkable words were little observed in the discussions of that time. The air was
obscured by other matters. But in this work I have said so much on the subject that I need say little
now. The joint stock banks now keep a main part of their reserve on deposit with the bill-brokers, or
in good and convertible interest-bearing securities. From these they obtain a large income, and that
income swells their profits. If they had to keep a much larger part than now of that reserve in barren
cash, their dividends would be reduced, and their present success would become less conspicuous.
The second misgiving, which many calm observers more and more feel as to our largest joint stock
banks, fastens itself on their government. Is that government sufficient to lend well and keep safe so
many millions? They are governed, as every one knows, by a board of directors, assisted by a
general manager, and there are in London unrivalled materials for composing good boards of
directors. There are very many men of good means, of great sagacity and great experi- ence in
business, who are obliged to be in the City every day, and to remain there during the day, but who
have very much time on their hands. A merchant employing solely or principally his own capital has
often a great deal of leisure. He is obliged to be on the market, and to hear what is doing. Every day
he has some business to transact, but his transactions can be but few. His capital can bear only a
limited number of purchases; if he bought as much as would fill his time from day to day he would
soon be ruined, for he could not pay for it. Accordingly, many excellent men of business are quite
ready to become members of boards of directors, and to attend to the business of companies, a
good deal for the employment's sake. To have an interesting occupation which brings dignity and
power with it pleases them very much. As the aggregation of commerce in great cities grows, the
number of such men augments. A council of grave, careful, and experienced men can, without
difficulty, be collected for a great bank in London, such as never could have been collected before,
and such as cannot now be collected elsewhere.
There are facilities, too, for engaging a good banker to be a manager such as there never were
before in the world. The number of such persons is much on the increase. Any careful person who
is experienced in figures, and has real sound sense, may easily make himself a good banker. The
modes in which money can be safely lent by a banker are not many, and a clear-headed, quiet,
industrious person may soon learn all that is necessary about them. Our intricate law of real
property is an impediment in country banking, for it requires some special study even to
comprehend the elements of a law which is full of technical words, and which can only be explained
by narrating its history. But the banking of great cities is little concerned with loans on landed
property. And all the rest of the knowledge requisite for a banker can easily be obtained by anyone
who has the sort of mind which takes to it. No doubt there is a vast routine of work to be learned,
and the manager of a large bank must have a great facility in transacting business rapidly. But a
great number of persons are now bred from their earliest manhood in the very midst of that routine;
they learn it as they would learn a language, and come to be no more able to unlearn it than they
could unlearn a language. And the able ones among them acquire an almost magical rapidity in
effecting the business connected with that routine. A very good manager and very good board of
directors can, without unreasonable difficulty, be provided for a bank at present in London.
It will be asked, what more can be required? I reply, a great deal. All which the best board of
directors can really accomplish, is to form a good decision on the points which the manager
presents to them, and perhaps on a few others which one or two zealous members of their body
may select for discussion. A meeting of fifteen or eighteen persons is wholly unequal to the
transaction of more business than this; it will be fortunate, and it must be well guided, if it should be
found to be equal to so much. The discussion even of simple practical points by such a number of
persons is a somewhat tedious affair. Many of them will wish to speak on every decision of moment,
and some of themsome of the best of them perhapswill only speak with difficulty and slowly. Very
generally, several points will be started at once, unless the discussion is strictly watched by a rigid
chairman; and even on a single point the arguments will often raise grave questions which cannot
be answered, and suggest many more issues than can be advantageously decided by the meeting.
The time required by many persons for discussing many questions, would alone prevent an
assembly of many persons from overlooking a large and complicated business.
Nor is this the only difficulty. Not only would a real supervision of a large business by a board of
directors require much more time than the board would consent to occupy in meeting, it would also
require much more time and much more thought than the individual directors would consent to give.
These directors are only employing on the business of the Bank the vacant moments of their time,
and the spare energies of their minds. They cannot give the Bank more; the rest is required for the
safe conduct of their own affairs, and if they diverted it from these affairs they would be ruined. A
few of them may have little other business, or they may have other partners in the business, on
whose industry they can rely, and whose judgment they can trust; one or two may have retired from
business. But for the most part, directors of a company cannot attend principally and anxiously to
the affairs of a company without so far neglecting their own business as to run great risk of ruin; and
if they are ruined, their trustworthiness ceases, and they are no longer permitted by custom to be
directors.
Nor, even if it were possible really to supervise a business by the effectual and constant inspection
of fifteen or sixteen rich and capable persons, would even the largest business easily bear the
expense of such a supervision. I say rich, because the members of a board governing a large bank
must be men of standing and note besides, or they would discredit the bank; they need not be rich
in the sense of being worth millions, but they must be known to possess a fair amount of capital and
be seen to be transacting a fair quantity of business. But the labour of such persons, I do not say
their spare powers, but their principal energies, fetches a high price. Business is really a profession
often requiring for its practice quite as much knowledge, and quite as much skill, as law and
medicine; and requiring also the possession of money. A thorough man of business, employing a
fair capital in a trade, which he thoroughly comprehends, not only earns a profit on that capital, but
really makes of his professional skill a large income. He has a revenue from talent as well as from
money; and to induce sixteen or eighteen persons to abandon such a position and such an income
in order to devote their entire attention to the affairs of a joint stock company, a salary must be given
too large for the bank to pay or for anyone to wish to propose.
And an effectual supervision by the whole board being impossible, there is a great risk that the
whole business may fall to the general manager. Many unhappy cases have proved this to be very
dangerous. Even when the business of joint stock banks was far less, and when the deposits
entrusted to them were very much smaller, a manager sometimes committed frauds which were
dangerous, and still oftener made mistakes that were ruinous. Actual crime will always be rare; but,
as an uninspected manager of a great bank has the control of untold millions, sometimes we must
expect to see it: the magnitude of the temptation will occasionally prevail over the feebleness of
human nature. But error is far more formidable than fraud: the mistakes of a sanguine manager are,
far more to be dreaded than the theft of a dishonest manager. Easy misconception is far more
common than long-sighted deceit. And the losses to which an adventurous and plausible manager,
in complete good faith, would readily commit a bank, are beyond comparison greater than any
which a fraudulent manager would be able to conceal, even with the utmost ingenuity. If the losses
by mistake in banking and the losses by fraud were put side by side, those by mistake would be
incomparably the greater. There is no more unsafe government for a bank than that of an eager and
active manager, subject only to the supervision of a numerous board of directors, even though that
board be excellent, for the manager may easily glide into dangerous and insecure transactions, nor
can the board effectually check him.
The remedy is this: a certain number of the directors, either those who have more spare time than
others, or those who are more ready to sell a large part of their time to the bank, must be formed
into a real working committee, which must meet constantly, must investigate every large transaction,
must be acquainted with the means and standing of every large borrower, and must be in such
incessant communication with the manager that it will be impossible for him to engage in hazardous
enterprises of dangerous magnitude without their knowing it and having an opportunity of forbidding
it. In almost all cases they would forbid it; all committees are cautious, and a committee of careful
men of business, picked from a large city, will usually err on the side of caution if it err at all. The
daily attention of a small but competent minor council, to whom most of the powers of the directors
are delegated, and who, like a cabinet, guide the deliberations of the board at its meetings, is the
only adequate security of a large bank from the rash engagements of a despotic and active general
manager. Fraud, in the face of such a committee, would probably never be attempted, and even
now it is a rare and minor evil.
Some such committees are vaguely known to exist in most, if not all, our large joint stock banks. But
their real constitution is not known. No customer and no shareholder knows the names of the
managing committee, perhaps, in any of these large banks. And this is a grave error. A large
depositor ought to be able to ascertain who really are the persons that dispose of his money; and
still more a large shareholder ought not to rest till he knows who it is that makes engagements on
his behalf, and who it is that may ruin him if they choose. The committee ought to be composed of
quiet men of business, who can be ascertained by inquiry to be of high character and well-judging
mind. And if the public and the shareholder knew that there was such a committee, they would have
sufficient reasons for the confidence which now is given without such reasons.
A certain number of directors attending daily by rotation is, it should be said, no substitute for a
permanent committee. It has no sufficient responsibility. A changing body cannot have any
responsibility. The transactions which were agreed to by one set of directors present on the Monday
might be exactly those which would be much disapproved by directors present on the Wednesday. It
is essential to the decisions of most business, and not least of the banking business, that they
should be made constantly by the same persons; the chain of transactions must pass through the
same minds. A large business may be managed tolerably by a quiet group of second-rate men if
those men be always the same; but it cannot be managed at all by a fluctuating body, even of the
very cleverest men. You might as well attempt to guide the affairs of the nation by means of a
cabinet similarly changing.
Our great joint stock bands are imprudent in so carefully concealing the details of their government,
and in secluding those details from the risk of discussion. The answer, no doubt will be, `Let well
alone; as you have admitted, there hardly ever before was so great a success as these banks of
ours: what more do you or can you want?' I can only say that I want further to confirm this great
success and to make it secure for the future. At present there is at least the possibility of a great
reaction. Supposing that, owing to defects in its government, one even of the greater London joint
stock banks failed, there would be an instant suspicion of the whole system. One terra incognita
being seen to be faulty, every other terra incognita would be suspected. If the real government of
these banks had for years been known, and if the subsisting banks had been known not to be ruled
by the bad mode of government which had ruined the bank that had fallen, then the ruin of that bank
would not be hurtful. The other banks would be seen to be exempt from the cause which had
destroyed it. But at present the ruin of one of these great banks would greatly impair the credit of all.
Scarcely any one knows the precise government of any one; in no case has that government been
described on authority; and the fall of one by grave misgovernment would be taken to show that the
others might as easily be misgoverned also. And a tardy disclosure even of an admirable
constitution would not much help the surviving banks: as it was extracted by necessity, it would be
received with suspicion. A sceptical world would say `of course they say they are all perfect now; it
would not do for them to say anything else.'
And not only the depositors and the shareholders of these large banks have a grave interest in their
good government, but the public also. We have seen that our banking reserve is, as compared with
our liabilities, singularly small; we have seen that the rise of these great banks has lessened the
proportion of that reserve to those liabilities; we have seen that the greatest strain on the banking
reserve is a `panic.' Now, no cause is more capable of producing a panic, perhaps none is so
capable, as the failure of a first-rate joint stock bank in London. Such an event would have
something like the effect of the failure of Overend, Gurney and Co.; scarcely any other event would
have an equal effect. And therefore, under the existing constitution of our banking system the
government of these great banks is of primary importance to us all.
CHAPTER X - The Private Banks
Perhaps some readers of the last part of the last chapter have been inclined to say that I must be a
latent enemy to Joint Stock Banking. At any rate, I have pointed out what I think grave defects in it.
But I fear that a reader of this chapter may, on like grounds, suppose that I am an enemy to Private
Banking. And I can only hope that the two impressions may counteract one another, and may show
that I do not intend to be unfair.
I can imagine nothing better in theory or more successful in practice than private banks as they were
in the beginning. A man of known wealth, known integrity, and known ability is largely entrusted with
the money of his neighbours. The confidence is strictly personal. His neighbours know him, and
trust him because they know him. They see daily his manner of life, and judge from it that their
confidence is deserved. In rural districts, and in former times, it was difficult for a man to ruin himself
except at the place in which he lived; for the most part he spent his money there, and speculated
there if he speculated at all. Those who lived there also would soon see if he was acting in a
manner to shake their confidence. Even in large cities, as cities then were, it was possible for most
persons to ascertain with fair certainty the real position of conspicuous persons, and to learn all
which was material in fixing their credit. Accordingly the bankers who for a long series of years
passed successfully this strict and continual investigation, became very wealthy and very powerful.
The name `London Banker' had especially a charmed value. He was supposed to represent, and
often did represent, a certain union of pecuniary sagacity and educated refinement which was
scarcely to be found in any other part of society. In a time when the trading classes were much ruder
than they now are, many private bankers possessed variety of knowledge and a delicacy of
attainment which would even now be very rare. Such a position is indeed singularly favourable. The
calling is hereditary; the credit of the bank descends from father to son: this inherited wealth soon
begins inherited refinement. Banking is a watchful, but not a laborious trade. A banker, even in large
business, can feel pretty sure that all his transactions are sound, and yet have much spare mind. A
certain part of his time, and a considerable part of his thoughts, he can readily devote to other pur
suits. And a London banker can also have the most intellectual society in the world if he chooses it.
There has probably very rarely ever been so happy a position as that of a London private banker;
and never perhaps a happier.
It is painful to have to doubt of the continuance of such a class, and yet, I fear, we must doubt of it.
The evidence of figures is against it. In 1810 there were 40 private banks in Lombard Street
admitted to the clearing-house: there now are only 3. Though the business of banking has increased
so much since 1810, this species of banks is fewer in number than it was then. Nor is this the worst.
The race is not renewed. There are not many recognised impossibilities in business, but everybody
admits `that you cannot found a new private bank.' No such has been founded in London, or, as far
as I know, in the country, for many years. The old ones merge or die, and so the number is
lessened; but no new ones begin so as to increase that number again.
The truth is that the circumstances which originally favoured the establishment of private banks
have now almost passed away. The world has become so large and complicated that it is not easy
to ascertain who is rich and who is poor. No doubt there are some enormously wealthy men in
England whose means everybody has heard of, and has no doubt of. But these are not the men to
incur the vast liabilities of private banking. If they were bred in it they might stay in it; but they would
never begin it for themselves. And if they did, I expect people would begin to doubt even of their
wealth. It would be said, `What does A B go into banking for? he cannot be as rich as we thought.' A
millionaire commonly shrinks from liability, and the essence of great banking is great liability. No
doubt there are many `second-rate' rich men, as we now count riches, who would be quite ready to
add to their income the profit of a private bank if only they could manage it. But unluckily they cannot
manage it. Their wealth is not sufficiently familiar to the world; they cannot obtain the necessary
confidence. No new private bank is founded in England because men of first-rate wealth will not
found one, and men not of absolutely first-rate wealth cannot.
In the present day, also, private banking is exposed to a competition against which in its origin it had
not to struggle. Owing to the changes of which I have before spoken, joint stock banking has begun
to compete with it. In old times this was impossible; the Bank of England had a monopoly in banking
of the principle of association. But now large joint stock banks of deposit are among the most
conspicuous banks in Lombard Street. They have a large paid-up capital and intelligible published
accounts; they use these as an incessant advertisement, in a manner in which no individual can use
his own wealth. By their increasing progress they effectually prevent the foundation of any new
private bank.
The amount of the present business of private banks is perfectly unknown. Their balance sheets are
effective secretsrigidly guarded. But none of them, except a few of the largest, are believed at all to
gain business. The common repute of Lombard Street might be wrong in a particular case, but upon
the general doctrine it is almost sure to be right. There are a few well-known exceptions, but
according to universal belief the deposits of most private bankers in London tend rather to diminish
than to increase.
As to the smaller banks, this naturally would be so. A large bank always tends to become larger,
and a small one tends to become smaller. People naturally choose for their banker the banker who
has most present credit, and the one who has most money in hand is the one who possesses such
credit. This is what is meant by saying that a long established and rich bank has a `privileged
opportunity'; it is in a better position to do its business than any one else is; it has a great advantage
over old competitors and an overwhelming superiority over new comers. New people coming into
Lombard Street judge by results; they give to those who have: they take their money to the biggest
bank because it is the biggest. I confess I cannot, looking far forward into the future, expect that the
smaller private banks will maintain their ground. Their old connections will not leave them; there will
be no fatal ruin, no sudden mortality. But the tide will gently ebb, and the course of business will be
carried elsewhere.
Sooner or later, appearances indicate, and principle suggests, that the business of Lombard Street
will be divided between the joint stock banks and a few large private banks. And then we have to
ask ourserves the question, can those large private banks be permanent? I am sure I should be very
sorry to say that they certainly cannot, but at the same time I cannot be blind to the grave difficulties
which they must surmount.
In the first place, an hereditary business of great magnitude is dangerous. The management of such
a business needs more than common industry and more than common ability. But there is no
security at all that these will be regularly continued in each generation. The case of Overend,
Gurney and Co., the model instance of all evil in business, is a most alarming example of this evil.
No cleverer men of business probably (cleverer I mean for the purposes of their particular calling)
could well be found than the founders and first managers of that house. But in a very few years the
rule in it passed to a generation whose folly surpassed the usual limit of imaginable incapacity. In a
short time they substituted ruin for prosperity and changed opulence into insolvency. Such great
folly is happily rare; and the business of a bank is not nearly as difficult as the business of a
discount company. Still much folly is common, and the business of a great bank requires a great
deal of ability, and an even rarer degree of trained and sober judgment. That which happened so
marvelously in the green tree may happen also in the dry. A great private bank might easily become
very rotten by a change from discretion to foolishness in those who conduct it.
We have had as yet in London, happily, no example of this; indeed, we have hardly as yet had the
opportunity. Till now private banks have been small; small as we now reckon banks. For their
exigencies a moderate degree of ability and an anxious caution will suffice. But if the size of the
banks is augmented and greater ability is required, the constant difficulty of an hereditary
government will begin to be felt. `The father had great brains and created the business: but the son
had less brains and lost or lessened it.' This is the history of all great monarchies, and it may be the
history of great private banks. The peculiarity in the case of Overend, Gurney and Co.at least, one
peculiarityis that the evil was soon discovered. The richest partners had least concern in the
management; and when they found that incredible losses were ruining them, they stopped the
concern and turned it into a company. But they had done nothing; if at least they had only prevented
farther losses, the firm might have been in existence and in the highest credit now. It was the
publicity of their losses which ruined them. But if they had continued to be a private partnership they
need not have disclosed those losses: they might have written them off quietly out of the immense
profits they could have accumulated. They had some ten millions of other people's money in their
hands which no one thought of disturbing. The perturbation through the country which their failure
caused in the end, shows how diffused and how unimpaired their popular reputation was. No one in
the rural districts (as I know by experience) would ever believe a word against them, say what you
might. The catastrophe came because at the change the partners in the old private firmthe Gurney
family especiallyhad guaranteed the new company against the previous losses: those losses turned
out to be much greater than was expected. To pay what was necessary the `Gurneys' had to sell
their estates, and their visible ruin destroyed the credit of the concern. But if there had been no such
guarantee, and no sale of estates,if the great losses had slept a quiet sleep in a hidden ledger,no
one would have been alarmed, and the credit and the business of `Overends' might have existed till
now, and their name still continued to be one of our first names. The difficulty of propagating a good
management by inheritance for generations is greatest in private banks and discount firms because
of their essential secrecy.
The danger may indeed be surmounted by the continual infusion of new and able partners. The
deterioration of the old blood may be compensated by the excellent quality of the fresh blood. But to
this again there is an objection, of little value perhaps in seeming, but of much real influence in
practice. The infusion of new partners requires from the old partners a considerable sacrifice of
income; the old must give up that which the new receive, and the old will not like this. The effectual
remedy is so painful that I fear it often may be postponed too long.
I cannot, therefore, expect with certainty the continuance of our system of private banking. I am sure
that the days of small banks will before many years come to an end, and that the difficulties of large
private banks are very important. In the mean time it is very important that large private banks
should be well managed. And the present state of banking makes this peculiarly difficult. The detail
of the business is augmenting with an overwhelming rapidity. More cheques are drawn year by year;
not only more absolutely, but more by each person, and more in proportion to his income. The
payments in, and payments out of a common account are very much more numerous than they
formerly were. And this causes an enormous growth of detail. And besides, bankers have of late
begun almost a new business. They now not only keep people's money, but also collect their
incomes for them. Many persons live entirely on the income of shares, or debentures, or foreign
bonds, which is paid in coupons, and these are handed in for the bank to collect. Often enough the
debenture, or the certificate, or the bond is in the custody of the banker, and he is expected to see
when the coupon is due, and to cut it off and transmit it for payment. And the detail of all this is
incredible, and it needs a special machinery to cope with it.
A large joint stock bank, if well-worked, has that machinery. It has at the head of the executive a
general manager who was tried in the detail of banking, who is devoted to it, and who is content to
live almost wholly in it. He thinks of little else, and ought to think of little else. One of his first duties
is to form a hierarchy of inferior officers, whose respective duties are defined, and to see that they
can perform and do perform those duties. But a private bank of the type usual in London has no
such officer. It is managed by the partners; now these are generally rich men, are seldom able to
grapple with great business of detail, and are not disposed to spend their whole lives and devote
their entire minds to it if they were able. A person with the accumulated wealth, the education and
the social place of a great London banker would be a `fool so to devote himself. He would sacrifice
a suitable and a pleasant life for an unpleasant and an unsuitable life. But still the detail must be
well done; and some one must be specially chosen to watch it and to preside over it, or it will not be
well done. Until now, or until lately, this difficulty has not been fully felt. The detail of the business of
a small private bank was moderate enough to be superintended effectually by the partners. But, as
has been said, the detail of bankingthe proportion of detail to the size of the bankis everywhere
increasing. The size of the private banks will have to augment if private banks are not to cease; and
therefore the necessity of a good organisation for detail is urgent. If the bank grows, and
simultaneously the detail grows in proportion to the bank, a frightful confusion is near unless care be
taken.
The only organisation which I can imagine to be effectual is that which exists in the antagonistic
establishments. The great private banks will have, I believe, to appoint in some form or other, and
under some name or other, some species of general manager who will watch, contrive, and arrange
the detail for them. The precise shape of the organisation is immaterial; each bank may have its
own shape, but the man must be there. The true business of the private partners in such a bank is
much that of the directors in a joint stock bank. They should form a permanent committee to consult
with their general manager, to watch him, and to attend to large loans and points of principle. They
should not themselves be responsible for detail; if they do there will be two evils at once: the detail
will be done badly, and the minds of those who ought to decide principal things will be distracted
from those principal things. There will be a continual worry in the bank, and in a worry bad loans are
apt to be made and money is apt to be lost.
A subsidiary advantage of this organisation is that it would render the transition from private banking
to joint stock banking easier, if that transition should be necessary. The one might merge in the
other as convenience suggested and as events required. There is nothing intrusive in discussing
this subject. The organisation of the private is just like that of the joint stock banks; all the public are
interested that it should be good. The want of a good organisation may cause the failure of one or
more of these banks; and such failure of such banks may intensify a panic, even if it should not
cause one.
CHAPTER XI - The Bill-Brokers
Under every system of banking, whether that in which the reserve is kept in many banks, or one in
which it is kept in a single bank only, there will always be a class of persons who examine more
carefully than busy bankers can the nature of different securities; and who, by attending only to one
class, come to be particularly well acquainted with that class. And as these specially qualified
dealers can for the most part lend much more than their own capital, they will always be ready to
borrow largely from bankers and others, and to deposit the securities which they know to be good as
a pledge for the loan. They act thus as intermediaries between the borrowing public and the less
qualified capitalist; knowing better than the ordinary capitalist which loans are better and which are
worse, they borrow from him, and gain a profit by charging to the public more than they pay to him.
Many stock brokers transact such business upon a great scale. They lend large sums on foreign
bonds or railway shares or other such securities, and borrow those sums from bankers, depositing
the securities with the bankers, and generally, though not always, giving their guarantee. But by far
the greatest of these intermediate dealers are the bill-brokers. Mercantile bills are an exceedingly
difficult kind of security to understand. The relative credit of different merchants is a great `tradition';
it is a large mass of most valuable knowledge which has never been described in books and is
probably incapable of being so described. The subject matter of it, too, is shifting and changing
daily; an accurate representation of the trustworthiness of houses at the beginning of a year might
easily be a most fatal representation at the end of it. In all years there are great changes; some
houses rise a good deal and some fall. And in some particular years the changes are immense; in
years like 1871 many active men make so much money that at the end of the year they are worthy
of altogether greater credit than anyone would have dreamed of giving to them at the beginning. On
the other hand, in years like i866 a contagious ruin destroys the trustworthiness of very many firms
and persons, and often, especially, of many who stood highest immediately before. Such years alter
altogether an important part of the mercantile world: the final question of bill-brokers, `which bills will
be paid and which will not? which bills are second-rate and which first-rate?' would be answered
very differently at the beginning of the year and at the end. No one can be a good bill-broker who
has not learnt the great mercantile tradition of what is called `the standing of parties" and who does
not watch personally and incessantly the inevitable changes which from hour to hour impair the truth
of that tradition. The credit' of a personthat is, the reliance which may be placed on his pecuniary
fidelityis a different thing from his property. No doubt, other things being equal, a rich man is more
likely to pay than a poor man. But on the other hand, there are many men not of much wealth who
are trusted in the market, `as a matter of business,' for sums much exceeding the wealth of those
who are many times richer. A firm or a person who have been long known to `meet their
engagements,' inspire a degree of confidence not dependent on the quantity of his or their property.
Persons who buy to sell again soon are often liable for amounts altogether much greater than their
own capital; and the power of obtaining those sums depends upon their `respectability,' their
`standing,' and their `credit,' as the technical terms express it, and more simply upon the opinion
which those who deal with them have formed of them. The principal mode in which money is raised
by traders is by `bills of exchange;' the estimated certainty of their paying those bills on the day they
fall due is the measure of their credit; and those who estimate that liability best, the only persons
indeed who can estimate it exceedingly well, are the bill-brokers. And these dealers, taking
advantage of their peculiar knowledge, borrow immense sums from bankers and others; they
generally deposit the bills as a security; and they generally give their own guarantee of the
goodness of the bill: but neither of such practices indeed is essential, though both are the ordinary
rule. When Overends failed, as I have said before, they had borrowed in this way very largely. There
are others now in the trade who have borrowed quite as much.
As is usually the case, this kind of business has grown up only gradually. In the year 1810 there was
no such business precisely answering to what we now call bill-broking in London. Mr. Richardson,
the principal `bill-broker' of the time, as the term was then understood, thus described his business
to the `Bullion Committee:'
`What is the nature of the agency for country banks'It is twofold: in the first place to procure money
for country bankers on bills when they have occasion to borrow on discount, which is not often the
case; and in the next place, to lend the money for the country bankers on bills on discount. The
sums of money which I lend for country bankers on discount are fifty times more than the sums
borrowed for country bankers.
`Do you send London bills into the country for discount?Yes.
`Do you receive bills from the country upon London in return, at a date, to he discounted?Yes, to a
very considerable amount, from particular parts of the country.
`Are not both sets of bills by this means under discount?No, the bills received from one part of the
country are sent down to another part for discount.
`And they are not discounted in London?No. In some parts of the country there is but little circulation
of bills drawn upon London, as in Norfolk, Suffolk, Essex, Sussex, &c.; but there is there a
considerable circulation in country bank-notes, principally optional notes. In Lancashire there is little
or no circulation of country bank-notes; but there is a great circulation of bills drawn upon London at
two or three months' date. I receive bills to a considerable amount from Lancashire in particular, and
remit them to Norfolk, Suffolk, &c., where the bankers have large lodgments, and much surplus
money to advance on bills for discount.'
Mr. Richardson was only a broker who found money for bills and bills for money. He is further
asked:
`Do you guarantee the bills you discount, and what is your charge per cent?No, we do not guarantee
them; our charge is one-eighth per cent brokerage upon the bill discountedbut we make no charge
to the lender of the money.
`Do you consider that brokerage as a compensation for the skill which you exercise in selecting the
bills which you thus get discounted?Yes, for selecting of the bills, writing letters, and other trouble.
`Does the party who furnishes the money give you any kind of compensation?None at all.
`Does he not consider you as his agent, and in some degree responsible for the safety of the bills
which you give him?Not at all.
`Does he not prefer you on the score of his judging that you will give him good intelligence upon that
subject?~Yes, he relies upon us.
`Do you then exercise a discretion as to the probable safety of the bills?~Yes; if a bill comes to us
which we conceive not to be safe, we return it.
`Do you not then conceive yourselves to depend in a great measure for the quantity of business
which you can perform on the favour of the party lending the money?Yes, very much so. If we
manage our business well, we retain our friends; if we do not, we lose them.'
It was natural enough that the owners of the money should not pay, though the owner of the bill did,
for in almost all ages the borrower has been a seeker more or less anxious; he has always been
ready to pay for those who will find him the money he is in search of. But the possessor of money
has rarely been willing to pay anything; he has usually and rightly believed that the borrower would
discover him soon.
Notwithstanding other changes, the distribution of the customers of the bill-brokers in different parts
of the country still remains much as Mr. Richardson described it sixty years ago. For the most part,
agricultural counties do not employ as much money as they save; manufacturing counties, on the
other hand, can employ much more than they save; and therefore the money of Norfolk or of
Somersetshire is deposited with the London bill-brokers, who use it to discount the bills of
Lancashire and Yorkshire.
The old practice of bill-broking, which Mr. Richardson describes, also still exists. There are many
brokers to be seen about Lombard Street with bills which they wish to discount but which they do
not guarantee. They have sometimes discounted these bills with their own capital, and if they can
re-discount them at a slightly lower rate they gain a difference which at first seems but trifling, but
with which they are quite content, because this system of lending first and borrowing again
immediately enables them to turn their capital very frequently, and on a few thousand pounds of
capital to discount hundreds of thousands of bills; as the transactions are so many, they can be
content with a smaller profit on each. In other cases, these nonguaranteeing brokers are only agents
who are seeking money for bills which they have undertaken to get discounted. But in either case,
as far as the banker or other ultimate capitalist is concerned, the transaction is essentially that which
Mr. Richardson describes. The loan by such banker is a rediscount of the bill; that banker cannot
obtain repayment of that loan, except by the payment of the bill at maturity. He has no claim upon
the agent who brought him the bill. Billbroking, in this which we may call its archaic form, is simply
one of the modes in which bankers obtain bills which are acceptable to them and which they
rediscount. No reference is made in it to the credit of the bill-broker; the bills being discounted
`without recourse' to him are as good if taken from a pauper as if taken from a millionaire. The
lender exercises his own judgment on the goodness of the bill.
But in modern bill-broking the credit of the bill-broker is a vital element. The lender considers that
the bill-brokerno matter whether an individual, a company, or a firmhas considerable wealth, and he
takes the `bills,' relying that the broker would not venture that wealth by guaranteeing them unless
he thought them good. The lender thinks, too, that the bill-broker being daily conversant with bills
and bills only, knows probably all about bills: he lends partly in reliance on the wealth of the broker
and partly in reliance on his skill. He does not exercise much judgment of his own on the bills
deposited with him: he often does not watch them very closely. Probably not one-thousandth part of
the creditors on security of Overend, Gurney and Co., had ever expected to have to rely on that
security, or had ever given much real attention to it. Sometimes, indeed, the confidence in the bill-
brokers goes farther. A considerable number of persons lend to them, not only without much looking
at the security but even without taking any security. This is the exact reverse of the practice which
Mr. Richardson described in 1810; then the lender relied wholly on the goodness of the bill, now, in
these particular cases, he relies solely on the bill-broker, and does not take a bill in any shape.
Nothing can be more natural or more inevitable than this change. It was certain that the bill-broker,
being supposed to understand bills well, would be asked by the lenders to evince his reliance on the
bills he offered by giving a guarantee for them. It was also most natural that the bill-brokers, having
by the constant practice of this lucrative trade obtained high standing and acquired great wealth,
should become, more or less, bankers too, and should receive money on deposit without giving any
security for it.
But the effects of the change have been very remarkable. In the practice as Mr. Richardson
described it, there is no peculiarity very likely to affect the money market. The bill-broker brought
bills to the banker, just as others brought them; nothing at all could be said as to it except that the
Bank must not discount bad bills, must not discount too many bills, and must keep a good reserve.
But the modern practice introduces more complex considerations. In the trade of bill-broking, as it
now exists, there is one great difficulty; the bill-broker has to pay interest for all the money which he
receives. How this arose we have just seen. The present lender to the bill-broker at first always used
to discount a bill, which is as much as saying that he was always a lender at interest. When he
came to take the guarantee of the broker, and only to look at the bills as a collateral security,
naturally he did not forego his interest: still less did he forego it when he ceased to take security at
all. The bill-broker has, in one shape or other, to pay interest on every sixpence left with him, and
that constant habit of giving interest has this grave consequence: the bill-broker cannot afford to
keep much money unemployed. He has become a banker owing large sums which he may be
called on to repay, but he cannot hold as much as an ordinary banker, or nearly as much, of such
sums in cash, because the loss of interest would ruin him. Competition reduces the rate which the
bill-broker can charge, and raises the rate which the bill-broker must give, so that he has to live on a
difference exceedingly narrow. And if he constantly kept a large hoard of barren money he would
soon be found in the `Gazette.'
The difficulty is aggravated by the terms upon which a great part of the money at the bill-brokers is
deposited with them. Very much of it is repayable at demand, or at very short notice. The demands
on a broker in periods of alarm may consequently be very great, and in practice they often, are so.
In times of panic there is always a very heavy call, if not a run upon them; and in consequence of
the essential nature of their business, they cannot constantly keep a large unemployed reserve of
their own in actual cash, they are obliged to ask help of some one who possesses that cash. By the
conditions of his trade, the bill-broker is forced to belong to a class of `dependent money-dealers,'
as we may term them, that is, of dealers who do not keep their own reserve, and must, therefore, at
every crisis of great difficulty revert to others.
In a natural state of banking, that in which all the principal banks kept their own reserve, this
demand of the bill-brokers and other dependent dealers would be one of the principal calls on that
reserve. At every period of incipient panic the holders of it would perceive that it was of great
importance to themselves to support these dependent dealers. If the panic destroyed those dealers
it would grow by what it fed upon (as is its nature), and might probably destroy also the bankers, the
holders of the reserve. The public terror at such times is indiscriminate. When one house of good
credit has perished, other houses of equal credit though of different nature are m danger of
perishing. The many holders of the banking reserve would under the natural system of banking be
obliged to advance out of that reserve to uphold bill-brokers and similar dealers. It would be
essential to their own preservation not to let such dealers fail, and the protection of such dealers
would therefore be reckoned among the necessary purposes for which they retained that reserve.
Nor probably would the demands on the bill-brokers in such a system of banking be exceedingly
formidable. Considerable sums would no doubt be drawn from them, but there would be no special
reason why money should be demanded from them more than from any other money dealers. They
would share the panic with the bankers who kept the reserve, but they would not feel it more than
the bankers. In each crisis the set of the storm would be determined by the cause which had excited
it, but there would not be anything in the nature of bill-broking to attract the advance of the alarm
peculiarly to them. They would not be more likely to suffer than other persons; the only difference
would be that when they did suffer, having no adequate reserve of their own, they would be obliged
to ask the aid of others.
But under a one-reserve system of banking, the position of the bill-brokers is much more singular
and much more precarious. In fact, in Lombard Street, the principal depositors of the bill-brokers are
the bankers, whether of London, or of provincial England, or of Scotland, or Ireland. Such deposits
are, in fact, a portion of the reserve of these bankers; they make an essential part of the sums which
they have provided and laid by against a panic. Accordingly, in every panic these sums are sure to
be called in from the bill-brokers; they were wanted to be used by their owners in time of panic, and
in time of panic they ask for them. `Perhaps it may be interesting,' said Alderman Salomons,
speaking on behalf of the London and Westminster Bank, after the panic of 1857, to the committee,
`to know that, on November 11, we held discounted bills for brokers to the amount of 5,623,0001.
Out of these bills 2,800,000!. matured between November 1 and December 4; 2,000,000 l. more
between December 1 and December 31; consequently we were prepared merely by the maturing of
our bills of exchange for any demand that might come upon us.' This is not indeed a direct
withdrawal of money on deposit, but its principal effect is identical. At the beginning of the time the
London and Westminster Bank had lent 5,000,000 l. more to the bill-brokers than they had at the
end of it; and that 5,000,000 l. the bank had added to its reserve against a time of difficulty.
The intensity of the demand on the bill-broker is aggravated therefore by our peculiar system of
banking. Just at the moment when, by the nature of their business, they have to resort to the
reserves of bankers for necessary support, the bankers remove from them large sums in order to
strengthen those reserves. A great additional strain is thrown upon them just at the moment when
they are least able to bear it; and it is thrown by those who under a natural system of banking would
not aggravate the pressure on the bill-brokers, but relieve it.
And the profits of bill-broking are proportionably raised. The reserves of the bankers so deposited
with the bill-broker form a most profitable part of his business; they are on the whole of very large
amount, and at all times, except those of panic, may well be depended upon. The bankers are pretty
sure to keep them there, just because they must keep a reserve, and they consider it one of the best
places in which to keep it. Under a more natural system, no part of the banking reserve would ever
be lodged at the brokers. Bankers would deposit with the brokers only their extra money, the money
which they considered they could safely lend, and which they would not require during a panic. In
the eye of the banker, money at the brokers would then be one of the investments of cash, it would
not be a part of such cash. The deposits of bill-brokers and the profits of bill-broking are increased
by our present system, just in proportion as the dangers of bill-brokers during a panic are increased
by it.
The strain, too, on our banking reserve which is caused by the demands of the bill-brokers, is also
more dangerous than it would be under a natural system, because that reserve is in itself less. The
system of keeping the entire ultimate reserve at a single bank, undoubtedly diminishes the amount
of reserve which is kept. And exactly on that very account the danger of any particular demand on
that reserve is augmented, because the magnitude of the fund upon which that demand falls is
diminished. So that our one-reserve system of banking combines two evils: first, it makes the
demand of the brokers upon the final reserve greater, because under it so many bankers remove so
much money from the brokers; and under it also the final reserve is reduced to its minimum point,
and the entire system of credit is made more delicate, and more sensitive.
The peculiarity, indeed, of the effects of the one reserve is indeed even greater in this respect.
Under the natural system, the billbrokers would be in no respect the rivals of the bankers which kept
the ultimate reserve. They would be rather the agents for these bankers in lending upon certain
securities which they did not themselves like, or on which they did not feel competent to lend safely.
The bankers who in time of panic had to help them would in ordinary times derive much advantage
from them. But under our present system all this is reversed. The Bank of England never deposits
any money with the bill-brokers; in ordinary times it never derives any advantage from them. On the
other hand, as the Bank carries on itself a large discount business, as it considers that it is itself
competent to lend on all kinds of bills, the bill-brokers are its most formidable rivals. As they
constantly give high rates for money it is necessary that they should undersell the Bank, and in
ordinary times they do undersell it. But as the Bank of England alone keeps the final banking
reserve, the bill-brokers of necessity have to resort to that final reserve; so that at every panic, and
by the essential constitution of the money market, the Bank of England has to help, has to maintain
in existence, the dealers, who never in return help the Bank at any time, but who are in ordinary
times its closest competitors and its keenest rivals.
It might be expected that such a state of things would cause much discontent at the Bank of
England, and in matter of fact there has been much discussion about it, and much objection taken to
it. After the panic of 1857, this was so especially. During that panic, the Bank of England advanced
to the bill-brokers more than 9,000,000 l., though their advances to bankers, whether London or
country, were only 8,000,000 l.; and, not unnaturally, the Bank thought it unreasonable that so large
an inroad upon their resources should be made by their rivals. In consequence, in 1858 they made a
rule that they would only advance to the bill-brokers at certain seasons of the year, when the public
money is particularly large at the bank, and that at other times any application for an advance
should be considered excep tonal, and dealt with accordingly. And the object of that regulation was
officially stated to be `to make them keep their own reserve, and not to be dependent on the Bank of
England.' As might be supposed, this rule was exceedingly unpopular with the brokers, and the
greatest of them, Overend, Gurney and Co., resolved on a strange policy in the hope of abolishing
it. They thought they could frighten the Bank of England, and could show that if they were
dependent on it, it was also dependent on them. They accordingly accumulated a large deposit at
the Bank to the amount of 3,000,000!., and then withdrew it all at once. But this policy had no effect,
except that of exciting a distrust of `Overends': the credit of the Bank of England was not
diminished; Overends had to return the money in a few days, and had the dissatisfaction of feeling
that they had in vain attempted to assail the solid basis of everyone's credit, and that everyone
disliked them for doing so. But though this rn-conceived attempt failed as it deserved, the rule itself
could not be maintained. The Bank does, in fact, at every period of pressure, advance to the bin-
brokers; the case may be considered `exceptional,' but the advance is always made if the security
offered is really good. However much the Bank may dislike to aid their rivals, yet they must aid
them; at a crisis they feel that they would only be aggravating incipient demand, and be augmenting
the probable pressure on themselves if they refused to do so.
I shall be asked if this anomaly is inevitable, and I am afraid that for practical purposes we must
consider it to be so. It may be lessened; the bill-brokers may, and should, discourage as much as
they can the deposit of money with them on demand, and encourage the deposit of it at distant fixed
dates or long notice. This will diminish the anomaly, but it will not cure it. Practically, bin-brokers
cannot refuse to receive money at call. In every market a dealer must conduct his business
according to the custom of the market, or he will not be able to conduct it at all. All the bin-brokers
can do is to offer better rates for more permanent money, and this (though possibly not so much as
might be wished) they do at present. In its essence, this anomaly is, I believe, an inevitable part of
the system of banking which history has given us, and which we have only to make the best of,
since we cannot alter it.
CHAPTER XII - The Principles Which Should Regulate the Amount of the Banking Reserve to
Be Kept by the Bank of England
There is a very common notion that the amount of the reserve which the Bank of England ought to
keep can be determined at once from the face of their weekly balance sheet. It is imagined that you
have only to take the liabilities of the Banking department, and that a third or some other fixed
proportion will in all cases be the amount of reserve which the Bank should keep against those
liabilities. But to this there are several objections, some arising from the general nature of the
banking trade, and others from the special position of the Bank of England.
That the amount of the liabilities of a bank is a principal element in determining the proper amount
of its reserve is plainly true; but that it is the only element by which that amount is determined is
plainly false. The intrinsic nature of these liabilities must be considered, as well as their numerical
quantity. For example, no one would say that the same amount of reserve ought to be kept against
acceptances which cannot be paid except at a certain day, and against deposits at call, which may
be demanded at any moment. If a bank groups these liabilities together in the balance-sheet, you
cannot tell the amount of reserve it ought to keep. The necessary information is not given you.
Nor can you certainly determine the amount of reserve necessary to be kept against deposits unless
you know something as to the nature of these deposits. If out of 3,000,000 l. of money, one
depositor has 1 ,ooo,oool. to his credit, and may draw it out when he pleases, a much larger reserve
will be necessary against that liability of 1, ,ooo,oool. than against the remaining 2,000,000!. The
intensity of the liability, so to say, is much greater; and therefore the provision in store must be much
greater also. On the other hand, supposing that this single depositor is one of calculable
habitssuppose that it is a public body, the time of whose demands is known, and the time of whose
receipts is known alsothis single liability requires a less reserve than that of an equal amount of
ordinary liabilities. The danger that it win be called for is much less; and therefore the security taken
against it may be much less too. Unless the quality of the liabilities is considered as well as their
quantity, the due provision for their payment cannot be determined.
These are general truths as to all banks, and they have a very particular application to the Bank of
England. The first application is favourable to the Bank; for it shows the danger of one of the
principal liabilities to be much smaller than it seems. The largest account at the Bank of England is
that of the English Government; and probably there has never been any account of which it was so
easy in time of peace to calculate the course. All the material facts relative to the English revenue,
and the English expenditure, are exceedingly well known; and the amount of the coming payments
to and from this account are always, except in war times, to be calculated with wonderful accuracy.
In war, no doubt, this is all reversed; the account of a government at war is probably the most
uncertain of all accounts, especially of a government of a scattered empire, like the English, whose
places of outlay in time of war are so many and so distant, and the amount of whose payments is
therefore so incalculable. Ordinarily, however, there is no account of which the course can be so
easily predicted; and therefore no account which needs in ordinary times so little reserve. The
principal payments, when they are made, are also of the most satisfactory kind to a banker; they
are, to a great extent, made to another account at his bank. These largest ordinary payments of the
Government are the dividends on the debt, and these are mostly made to bankers who act as
agents for the creditors of the nation. The payment of the dividends for the Government is,
therefore, in great part a transfer from the account of the Government to the accounts of the various
bankers. A certain amount no doubt goes almost at once to the non-banking classes; to those who
keep coin and notes in house, and have no account at any bank. But even this amount is calculable,
for it is always nearly the same. And the entire operation is, to those who can watch it, singularly
invariable time after time.
But it is important to observe, that the published accounts of the Bank give no such information to
the public as win enable them to make their own calculations. The account of which we have been
speaking is the yearly account of the English Governmentwhat we may call the Budget account, that
of revenue and expenditure. And the laws of this are, as we have shown, already known. But under
the head `Public Deposits' in the accounts of the Bank, are contained also other accounts, and
particularly that of the Secretary for India in Council, the laws of which must be different and are
quite unknown. The Secretary for India is a large lender on its account. If any one proposed to give
such power to the Chancellor of the Exchequer, there would be great fear and outcry. But so much
depends on habit and tradition, that the India Office on one side of Downing Street can do without
remark, and with universal assent, what it would be thought `unsound' and extravagant to propose
that the other side should do. The present India Office inherits this independence from the old Board
of the Company, which, being mercantile and business-like, used to lend its own money on the
Stock Exchange as it pleased; the Council of India, its successor, retains the power. Nothing can be
better than that it should be allowed to do as it likes; but the mixing up the account of a body which
has such a power, and which draws money from India, with that of the Home government clearly
prevents the general public from being able to draw inferences as to the course of the combined
account from its knowledge of home finance only. The account of `public deposits' in the Bank
return includes other accounts too, as the Savings' Bank balance, the Chancery Funds account, and
others; and in consequence, till lately the public had but little knowledge of the real changes of the
account of our Government, properly so called. But Mr. Lowe has lately given us a weekly account,
and from this, and not from the Bank account, we are able to form a judgment. This account and the
return of the Bank of England, it is true, unhappily appear on different days; but except for that
accident our knowledge would be perfect; and as it is, for almost all purposes what we know is
reasonably sufficient. We can now calculate the course of the Government account nearly as well
as it is possible to calculate it.
So far, as we have said, an analysis of the return of the Bank of England is very favourable to the
Bank. So great a reserve need not usually be kept against the Government account as if it were a
common account. We know the laws of its changes peculiarly well: we can tell when its principal
changes will happen with great accuracy; and we know that at such changes most of what is paid
away by the Government is only paid to other depositors at the Bank, and that it win really stay at
the Bank, though under another name. If we look to the private deposits of the Bank of England, at
first sight we may think that the result is the same. By far the most important of these are the
`Bankers' deposits'; and, for the most part, these deposits as a whole are likely to vary very little.
Each banker, we will suppose, keeps as little as he can, but in all domestic transactions payment
from one is really payment to the other. All the most important transactions in the country are settled
by cheques; these cheques are paid in to the `clearing-house,' and the balances resulting from them
are settled by transfers from the account of one banker to another at the Bank of England.
Payments out of the bankers' balances, therefore, correspond with payments in. As a whole, the
deposit of the bankers' balances at the Bank of England would at first sight seem to be a deposit
singularly stable.
Indeed, they would seem, so to say, to be better than stable. They augment when everything else
tends to diminish. At a panic, when all other deposits are likely to be taken away, the bankers'
deposits, augment; in fact they did so in 1866, though we do not know the particulars; and it is
natural that they should so increase. At such moments all bankers are extremely anxious, and they
try to strengthen themselves by every means in their power; they try to have as much money as it is
possible at command; they augment their reserve as much as they can, and they place that reserve
at the Bank of England. A deposit which is not likely to vary in ordinary times, and which is likely to
augment in times of danger, seems, in some sort, the model of a deposit. It might seem not only that
a large proportion of it might be lent, but that the whole of it might be so. But a further analysis will,
as I believe, show that this conclusion is entirely false; that the bankers' deposits are a singularly
treacherous form of liability; that the utmost caution ought to be used in dealing with them; that, as a
rule, a less proportion of them ought to be lent than of ordinary deposits.
The easiest mode of explaining anything is, usually, to exemplify it by a single actual case. And in
this subject, fortunately, there is a most conspicuous case near at hand. The German Government
has lately taken large sums in bullion from this country, in part from the Bank of England, and in part
not, according as it chose. It was in the main well advised, and considerate in its action; and did not
take nearly as much from the Bank as it might, or as would have been dangerous. Still it took large
sums from the Bank; and it might easily have taken more. How then did the German Government
obtain this vast power over the Bank? The answer is, that it obtained it by means of the bankers'
balances, and that it did so in two ways.
First, the German Government had a large balance of its own lying at a particular Joint Stock Bank.
That bank lent this balance at its own discretion, to bill-brokers or others, and it formed a single item
in the general funds of the London market. There was nothing special about it, except that it
belonged to a foreign government, and that its owner was always likely to call it in, and sometimes
did so. As long as it stayed unlent in the London Joint Stock Bank, it increased the balances of that
bank at the Bank of England; but so soon as it was lent, say, to a bill-broker, it increased the bill-
broker's balance; and as soon as it was employed by the bill-broker in the discount of bills, the
owners of those bills paid it to their credit at their separate banks, and it augmented the balances of
those bankers at the Bank of England. Of course if it were employed in the discount of bills
belonging to foreigners, the money might be taken abroad, and by similar operations it might also be
transferred to the English provinces or to Scotland. But, as a rule, such money when deposited in
London, for a considerable time remains in London; and so long as it does so, it swells the
aggregate balances of the body of bankers at the Bank of England. It is now in the balance of one
bank, now of another, but it is always dispersed about those balances somewhere. The evident
consequence is that this part of the bankers' balances is at the mercy of the German Government
when it chooses to apply for it. Supposing, then, the sum to be three or four millions and I believe
that on more than one occasion in the last year or two it has been quite as much, if not morethat
sum might at once be withdrawn from the Bank of England. In this case the Bank of England is in
the position of a banker who is liable for a large amount to a single customer, but with this addition,
that it is liable for an unknown amount. The German Government, as is well known, keeps its
account (and a very valuable one it must be) at the London Joint Stock Bank; but the Bank of
England has no access to the account of the German Government at that bank; they cannot tell how
much German money is lying to the credit there. Nor can the Bank of England infer much from the
balance of the London Joint Stock Bank in their Bank, for the German money was probably paid in
various sums to that bank, and lent out again in other various sums. It might to some extent
augment that bank's balance at the Bank of England, or it might not, but it certainly would not be so
much added to that balance; and inspection of that bank's balance would not enable the Bank of
England to determine even in the vaguest manner what the entire sum was for which it might be
asked at any moment. Nor would the inspection of the bankers' balances as a whole lead to any
certain and sure conclusions. Something might be inferred from them, but not anything certain.
Those balances are no doubt in a state of constant fluctuation; and very possibly during the time
that the German money was coming in some other might be going out. Any sudden increase in the
bankers' balances would be a probable indication of new foreign money, but new foreign money
might come in without causing an increase, since some other and contemporaneous cause might
effect a counteracting decrease.
This is the first, and the plainest way in which the German Government could take, and did take,
money from this country; and in which it might have broken the Bank of England if it had liked. The
German Government had money here and took it away, which is very easy to understand. But the
Government also possessed a far greater power, of a somewhat more complex kind. It was the
owner of many debts from England. A large part of the `indemnity' was paid by France to Germany
in bills on England, and the German Government, as those bills became due, acquired an
unprecedented command over the market. As each bill arrived at maturity, the German Government
could, if it chose, take the proceeds abroad; and it could do so in bullion, as for coinage purposes it
wanted bullion. This would at first naturally cause a reduction in the bankers' balances; at least that
would be its tendency. Supposing the German Government to hold bill A, a good bill, the banker at
whose bank bill A was payable would have to pay it; and that would reduce his balance; and as the
sum so paid would go to Germany, it would not appear to the credit of any other banker: the
aggregate of the bankers' balances would thus be reduced. But this reduction would not be
permanent. A banker who has to pay 100,000 l. cannot afford to reduce his balance at the Bank of
England 100,000 l.; suppose that his liabilities are 2,000,000 l., and that as a rule he finds it
necessary to keep at the Bank one-tenth of these liabilities, or 200,000 l., the payment of 100,000 l.
would reduce his reserve to 100,000 l.; but his liabilities would be still 1,900,000 l, and therefore to
keep up his tenth he would have 90,000 l. to find. His process for finding it is this: he calls in, say, a
loan to the bill-brokers; and if no equal additional money is contemporaneously carried to these
brokers (which in the case of a large withdrawal of foreign money is not probable), they must reduce
their business and discount less. But the effect of this is to throw additional business on the Bank of
England. They hold the ultimate reserve of the country, and they must discount out of it if no one
else will: if they declined to do so there would be panic and collapse. As soon, therefore, as the
withdrawal of the German money reduces the bankers' balances, there is a new demand on the
Bank for fresh discounts to make up those balances. The drain on the Bank is twofold: first, the
banking reserve is reduced by exportation of the German money, which reduces the means of the
Bank of England; and then out of those reduced means the Bank of England has to make greater
advances.
The same result may be arrived at more easily. Supposing any foreign Government or person to
have any sort of securities which he can pledge in the market, that operation gives it, or him, a credit
on some banker, and enables it, or him, to take money from the banking reserve at the Bank of
England, and from the bankers' balances; and to replace the bankers' balances at their inevitable
minimum, the Bank of England must lend. Every sudden demand on the country causes, in
proportion to its magnitude, this peculiar effect. And this is the reason why the Bank of England
ought, I think, to deal most cautiously and delicately with their banking deposits. They are the
symbol of an indefinite liability: by means of them, as we see, an amount of money so great that it is
impossible to assign a limit to it might be abstracted from the Bank of England. As the Bank of
England lends money to keep up the bankers' balances, at their usual amount, and as by means of
that usual amount whatever sum foreigners can get credit for may be taken from us, it is not
possible to assign a superior limit (to use the scientific word) to the demands which by means of the
bankers' balances may be made upon the Bank of England.
The result comes round to the simple point, on which this book is a commentary: the Bank of
England, by the effect of a long history, holds the ultimate cash reserve of the country; whatever
cash the country has to pay comes out of that reserve, and therefore the Bank of England has to
pay it. And it is as the Bankers' Bank that the Bank of England has to pay it, for it is by being so that
it becomes the keeper of the final cash reserve.
Some persons have been so much impressed with such considerations as these, that they have
contended that the Bank of England ought never to lend the `bankers' balances' at all, that they
ought to keep them intact, and as an unused deposit. I am not sure, indeed, that I have seen that
extreme form of the opinion in print, but I have often heard it in Lombard Street, from persons very
influential and very qualified to judge; even in print I have seen close approximations to it. But I am
satisfied that the laying down such a `hard and fast' rule would be very dangerous; in very important
and very changeable business rigid rules are apt to be often dangerous. In a panic, as has been
said, the bankers' balances greatly augment. It is true the Bank of England has to lend the money
by which they are filled. The banker calls in his money from the bill-broker, ceases to re-discount for
that broker, or borrows on securities, or sells securities; and in one or other of these ways he causes
a new demand for money which can only at such times be met from the Bank of England. Every one
else is in want too. But without inquiring into the origin of the increase at panics, the amount of the
bankers' deposits in fact increases very rapidly; an immense amount of unused money is at such
moments often poured by them into the Bank of England. And nothing can more surely aggravate
the panic than to forbid the Bank of England to lend that money. Just when money is most scarce
you happen to have an unusually large fund of this particular species of money, and you should lend
it as fast as you can at such moments, for it is ready lending which cures panics, and non-lending or
niggardly lending which aggravates them.
At other times, particularly at the quarterly payment of the dividends, an absolute rule which laid
down that the bankers' balances were never to be lent, would be productive of great inconvenience.
A large sum is just then paid from the Government balance to the bankers' balances, and if you
permitted the Bank to lend it while it was still in the hands of the Government, but forbad them to
lend it when it came into the hands of the bankers, a great tilt upwards in the value of money would
be the consequence, for a most important amount of it would suddenly have become ineffective.
But the idea that the bankers' balances ought never to be lent is only a natural aggravation of the
truth that these balances ought to be used with extreme caution; that as they entail a liability
peculiarly great and singularly difficult to foresee, they ought never to be used like a common
deposit.
It follows from what has been said that there are always possible and very heavy demands on the
Bank of England which are not shown in the account of the Banking department at all: these
demands may be greatest when the liabilities shown by that account are smallest, and lowest when
those liabilities are largest. If, for example, the German Government brings bills or other good
securities to this market, obtains money with them, and removes that money from the market in
bullion, that money may, if the German Government choose, be taken wholly from the Bank of
England. If the wants of the German Government be urgent, and if the amount of gold `arrivals,' that
is, the gold coming here from the mining countries, be but small, that gold will be taken from the
Bank of England, for there is no other large store in the country. The German Government is only a
conspicuous example of a foreign power which happens lately to have had an unusual command of
good securities, and an unusually continuous wish to use them in England. Any foreign state
hereafter which wants cash will be likely to come here for it; so long as the Bank of France should
continue not to pay in specie, a foreign state which wants it must of necessity come to London for it.
And no indication of the likelihood or unlikelihood of that want can be found in the books of the Bank
of England.
What is almost a revolution in the policy of the Bank of England necessarily follows: no certain or
fixed proportion of its liabilities can in the present times be laid down as that which the Bank ought
to keep in reserve. The old notion that one-third, or any other such fraction, is in all cases enough,
must be abandoned. The probable demands upon the Bank are so various in amount, and so little
disclosed by the figures of the account, that no simple and easy calculation is a sufficient guide. A
definite proportion of the liabilities might often be too small for the reserve, and sometimes too great.
The forces of the enemy being variable, those of the defence cannot always be the same.
I admit that this conclusion is very inconvenient. In past times it has been a great aid to the Bank
and to the public to be able to decide on the proper policy of the Bank from a mere inspection of its
account. In that way the Bank knew easily what to do and the public knew easily what to foresee.
But, unhappily, the rule which is most simple is not always the rule which is most to be relied upon.
The practical difficulties of life often cannot be met by very simple rules; those dangers being
complex and many, the rules for encountering them cannot well be single or simple. A uniform
remedy for many diseases often ends by killing the patient.
Another simple rule often laid down for the management of the Bank of England must now be
abandoned also. It has been said that the Bank of England should look to the market rate, and
make its own rate conform to that. This rule was, indeed, always erroneous. The first duty of the
Bank of England was to protect the ultimate cash of the country, and to raise the rate of interest so
as to protect it. But this rule was never so erroneous as now, because the number of sudden
demands upon that reserve was never formerly so great. The market rate of Lombard Street is not
influenced by those demands. That rate is determined by the amount of deposits in the hands of bill-
brokers and bankers, and the amount of good bills and acceptable securities offered at the moment.
The probable efflux of bullion from the Bank scarcely affects it at all; even the real efflux affects it
but little; if the open market did not believe that the Bank rate would be altered in consequence of
such effluxes the market rate would not rise. If the Bank choose to let its bullion go unheeded, and
is seen to be going so to choose, the value of money in Lombard Street will remain unaltered. The
more numerous the demands on the Bank for bullion, and the more variable their magnitude, the
more dangerous is the rule that the Bank rate of discount should conform to the market rate. In
former quiet times the influence, or the partial influence, of that rule has often produced grave
disasters. In the present difficult times an adherence to it is a recipe for making a large number of
panics.
A more distinct view of abstract principle must be taken before we can fix on the amount of the
reserve which the Bank of England ought to keep. Why should a bank keep any reserve? Because it
may be called on to pay certain liabilities at once and in a moment. Why does any bank publish an
account? In order to satisfy the public that it possesses cashor available securitiesenough to meet
its liabilities. The object of publishing the account of the banking department of the Bank of England
is to let the nation see how the national reserve of cash stands, to assure the public that there is
enough and more than enough to meet not only all probable calls, but all calls of which there can be
a chance of reasonable apprehension. And there is no doubt that the publication of the Bank
account gives more stability to the money market than any other kind of precaution would give.
Some persons, indeed, feared that the opposite result would happen; they feared that the constant
publication of the incessant changes in the reserve would terrify and harass the public mind. An old
banker once told me: `Sir, I was on Lord Althorp's committee which decided on the publication of the
Bank account, and I voted against it. I thought it would frighten people. But I am bound to own that
the committee was right and I was wrong, for that publication has given the money market a greater
sense of security than anything else which has happened in my time.' The diffusion of confidence
through Lombard Street and the world is the object of the publication of the Bank accounts and of
the Bank reserve.
But that object is not attained if the amount of that reserve when so published is not enough to
tranquillise people. A panic is sure to be caused if that reserve is, from whatever cause, exceedingly
low. At every moment there is a certain minimum which I will call the apprehension minimum,' below
which the reserve cannot fall without great risk of diffused fear; and by this I do not mean absolute
panic, but only a vague fright and timorousness which spreads itself instantly, and as if by magic,
over the public mind. Such seasons of incipient alarm are exceedingly dangerous, because they
beget the calamities they dread. What is most feared at such moments of susceptibility is the
destruction of credit; and if any grave failure or bad event happens at such moments, the public
fancy seizes on it, there is a general run, and credit is suspended. The Bank reserve then never
ought to be diminished below the `apprehension point.' And this is as much as to say, that it never
ought very closely to approach that point; since, if it gets very near, some accident may easily bring
it down to that point and cause the evil that is feared.
There is no `royal road' to the amount of the `apprehension minimum': no abstract argument, and no
mathematical computation will teach it to us. And we cannot expect that they should. Credit is an
opinion generated by circumstances and varying with those circumstances. The state of credit at
any particular time is a matter of fact only to be ascertained like other matters of fact; it can only be
known by trial and inquiry. And in the same way, nothing but experience can tell us what amount of
`reserve' will create a diffused confidence; on such a subject there is no way of arriving at a just
conclusion except by incessantly watching the public mind, and seeing at each juncture how it is
affected.
Of course in such a matter the cardinal rule to be observed is, that errors of excess are innocuous
but errors of defect are destructive. Too much reserve only means a small loss of profit, but too
small a reserve may mean `ruin.' Credit may be at once shaken, and if some terrifying accident
happen to supervene, there may be a run on the Banking department that may be too much for it, as
in 1857 and 1866, and may make it unable to pay its way without assistanceas it was m those
years.
And the observance of this maxim is the more necessary because the `apprehension minimum' is
not always the same. On the contrary, in times when the public has recently seen the Bank of
England exposed to remarkable demands, it is likely to expect that such demands may come again.
Conspicuous and recent events educate it, so to speak; it expects that much will be demanded
when much has of late often been demanded, and that little will be so, when in general but little has
been so. A bank like the Bank of England must always, therefore, be on the watch for a rise, if I may
so express it, in the apprehension minimum; it must provide an adequate fund not only to allay the
misgivings of to-day, but also to allay what may be the still greater misgivings of to-morrow. And the
only practical mode of obtaining this object isto keep the actual reserve always in advance of the
minimum `apprehension' reserve.
And this involves something much more. As the actual reserve is never to be less, and is always, if
possible, to exceed by a reasonable amount the `minimum' apprehension reserve, it must when the
Bank is quiet and taking no precautions very considerably exceed that minimum. All the precautions
of the Bank take time to operate. The principal precaution is a rise in the rate of discount, and such
a rise certainly does attract money from the Continent and from all the world much faster than could
have been anticipated. But it does not act instantaneously; even the right rate, the ultimately
attractive rate, requires an interval for its action, and before the money can come here. And the right
rate is often not discovered for some time. It requires several `moves,' as the phrase goes, several
augmentations of the rate of discount by the Bank, before the really effectual rate is reached, and in
the mean time bullion is ebbing away and the `reserve' is diminishing. Unless, therefore, in times
without precaution the actual reserve exceed the `apprehension minimum' by at least the amount
which may be taken away in the inevitable interval, and before the available precautions begin to
operate, the rule prescribed will be infringed, and the actual reserve will be less than the
`apprehension' minimum. In time the precautions taken may attract gold and raise the reserve to the
needful amount, but in the interim the evils may happen against which the rule was devised,
diffused apprehension may arise, and then any unlucky accident may cause many calamities.
I may be asked, `What does all this reasoning in practice come to? At the present moment how
much reserve do you say the Bank of England should keep? state your recommendation clearly (I
know it will be said) if you wish to have it attended to.' And I will answer the question plainly, though
in so doing there is a great risk that the principles I advocate may be in some degree injured through
some mistake I may make in applying them.
I should say that at the present time the mind of the monetary world would become feverish and
fearful if the reserve in the Banking department of the Bank of England went below 10,000,000 l.
Estimated by the idea of old times, by the idea even of ten years ago, that sum, I know, sounds
extremely large. My own nerves were educated to smaller figures, because I was trained in times
when the demands on us were less, when neither was so much reserve wanted nor did the public
expect so much. But I judge from such observations as I can make of the present state of men's
minds, that in fact, and whether justifiably or not, the important and intelligent part of the public
which watches the Bank reserve becomes anxious and dissatisfied if that reserve falls below
10,000,000 l. That sum, therefore, I call the `apprehension minimum' for the present times.
Circumstances may change and may make it less or more, but according to the most careful
estimate I can make, that is what I should call it now.
It will be said that this estimate is arbitrary and these figures are conjectures. I reply that I only
submit them for the judgment of others. The main question is one of factDoes not the public mind
begin to be anxious and timorous just where I have placed the apprehension point? and the
deductions from that are comparatively simple questions of mixed fact and reasoning. The final
appeal in such cases necessarily is to those who are conversant with and who closely watch the
facts.
I shall perhaps be told also that a body like the Court of the Directors of the Bank of England cannot
act on estimates like these: that such a body must have a plain rule and keep to it. I say in reply, that
if the correct framing of such estimates is necessary for the good guidance of the Bank, we must
make a governing body which can correctly frame such estimates. We must not suffer from a
dangerous policy because we have inherited an imperfect form of administration. I have before
explained in what manner the government of the Bank of England should, I consider, be
strengthened, and that government so strengthened would, I believe, be altogether competent to a
wise policy.
Then I should say, putting the foregoing reasoning into figures, that the Bank ought never to keep
less than 11,000,000 l.. or 11,500,000 l. since experience shows that a million, or a million and a
half, may be taken from us at any time. I should regard this as the practical minimum at which,
roughly of course, the Bank should aim, and which it should try never to be below. And, in order not
to be below 11,500,000 l., the Bank must begin to take precautions when the reserve is between
14,000,000 l. and 15,000,000 l.; for experience shows that between 2,000,000 l. and 3,000,000 l.
may, probably enough, be withdrawn from the Bank store before the right rate of interest is found
which will attract money from abroad, and before that rate has had time to attract it. When the
reserve is between 14,000,000 l. and 15,000,000 l., and when it begins to be diminished by foreign
demand, the Bank of England should, I think, begin to act, and to raise the rate of interest.
CHAPTER XIII - Conclusion
I know it will be said that in this work I have pointed out a deep malady, and only suggested a
superficial remedy. I have tediously insisted that the natural system of banking is that of many banks
keeping their own cash reserve, with the penalty of failure before them if they neglect it. I have
shown that our system is that of a single bank keeping the whole reserve under no effectual penalty
of failure. And yet I propose to retain that system, and only attempt to mend and palliate it.
I can only reply that I propose to retain this system because I am quite sure that it is of no manner of
use proposing to alter it. A system of credit which has slowly grown up as years went on, which has
suited itself to the course of business, which has forced itself on the habits of men, will not be
altered because theorists disapprove of it, or because books are written against it. You might as
well, or better, try to alter the English monarchy and substitute a republic, as to alter the present
constitution of the English money market, founded on the Bank of England, and substitute for it a
system in which each bank shall keep its own reserve. There is no force to be found adequate to so
vast a reconstruction, and so vast a destructions and therefore it is useless proposing them.
No one who has not long considered the subject can have a notion how much this dependence on
the Bank of England is fixed in our national habits. I have given so many illustrations in this book
that I fear I must have exhausted my reader's patience, but I will risk giving another. I suppose
almost everyone thinks that our system of savings' banks is sound and good. Almost everyone
would be surprised to hear that there is any possible objection to it. Yet see what it amounts to. By
the last return the savings' banksthe old and the Post Office togethercontain about 60,000,000 l. of
deposits, and against this they hold in the funds securities of the best kind. But they hold no cash
whatever. They have of course the petty cash about the various branches necessary for daily work.
But of cash in ultimate reserve cash in reserve against a panicthe savings' banks have not a
sixpence. These banks depend on being able in a panic to realise their securities. But it has been
shown over and over again, that in a panic such securities can only be realised by the help of the
Bank of Englandthat it is only the Bank with the ultimate cash reserve which has at such moments
any new money, or any power to lend and act. If in a general panic there were a run on the savings'
banks, those banks could not sell 100,000 l. of Consols without the help of the Bank of England; not
holding themselves a cash reserve for times of panic, they are entirely dependent on the one Bank
which does hold that reserve.
This is only a single additional instance beyond the innumerable ones given, which shows how
deeply our system of banking is fixed in our ways of thinking. The Government keeps the money of
the poor upon it, and the nation fully approves of their doing so. No one hears a syllable of objection.
And every practical manevery man who knows the scene of actionwill agree that our system of
banking, based on a single reserve in the Bank of England, cannot be altered, or a system of many
banks, each keeping its own reserve, be substituted for it. Nothing but a revolution would effect it,
and there is nothing to cause a revolution.
This being so, there is nothing for it but to make the best of our banking system, and to work it in the
best way that it is capable of. We can only use palliatives, and the point is to get the best palliative
we can. I have endeavoured to show why it seems to me that the palliatives which I have suggested
are the best that are at our disposal.
I have explained why the French plan will not suit our English world. The direct appointment of the
Governor and Deputy-Governor of the Bank of England by the executive Government would not
lessen our evils or help our difficulties. I fear it would rather make both worse. But possibly it may be
suggested that I ought to explain why the American system, or some modification, would not or
might not be suitable to us. The American law says that each national bank shall have a fixed
proportion of cash to its liabilities (there are two classes of banks, and two different proportions; but
that is not to the present purpose), and it ascertains by inspectors, who inspect at their own times,
whether the required amount of cash is in the bank or not. It may be asked, could nothing like this
be attempted in England? could not it, or some modification, help us out of our difficulties? As far as
the American banking system is one of many reserves, I have said why I think it is of no use
considering whether we should adopt it or not. We cannot adopt it if we would. The one-reserve
system is fixed upon us. The only practical imitation of the American system would be to enact that
the Banking department of the Bank of England should always keep a fixed proportionsay one-third
of its liabilitiesin reserve. But, as we have seen before, a fixed proportion of the liabilities, even when
that proportion is voluntarily chosen by the directors, and not imposed by law, is not the proper
standard for a bank reserve. Liabilities may be imminent or distant, and a fixed rule which imposes
the same reserve for both will sometimes err by excess, and sometimes by defect. It will waste
profits by over-provision against ordinary danger, and yet it may not always save the bank; for this
provision is often likely enough to be insufficient against rare and unusual dangers. But bad as is
this system when voluntarily chosen, it becomes far worse when legally and compulsorily imposed.
In a sensitive state of the English money market the near approach to the legal limit of reserve
would be a sure incentive to panic; if one-third were fixed by law, the moment the banks were close
to one-third, alarm would begin, and would run like magic. And the fear would be worse because it
would not be unfoundedat least, not wholly. If you say that the Bank shall always hold one-third of its
liabilities as a reserve, you say in fact that this one-third shall always be useless, for out of it the
Bank cannot make advances, cannot give extra help, cannot do what we have seen the holders of
the ultimate reserve ought to do and must do. There is no help for us in the American system; its
very essence and principle are faulty.
We must therefore, I think, have recourse to feeble and humble palliatives such as I have
suggested. With good sense, good judgment, and good care, I have no doubt that they may be
enough. But I have written in vain if I require to say now that the problem is delicate, that the solution
is varying and difficult, and that the result is inestimable to us all.
APPENDIX.
Note A.
Liabilities and Cash Reserve of the Chief Banking Systems.
The following is a comparison of the liabilities to the public, and of the cash reserve, of the banking
systems of the United Kingdom, France, Germany, and the United States. For the United Kingdom
the figures are the most defective, as they only include the deposits of the Bank of England, and of
the London joint stock banks, and the banking reserve of the Bank of England, which is the only
cash available against these liabilities is also the only cash reserve against the similar liabilities of
the London private banks, the provincial English banks, and the Scotch and Irish banks. In the case
of England, therefore, the method of comparison exhibits a larger proportion of cash to liabilities
than what really exists.
(1) ENGLISH BANKING.
Liabilities.
Deposits of Bank of England, less estimated Joint Stock Bank balances, at
December 31, 1872
£ 29,000,000
Deposits of London Joint Stock Banks at December 31 1872 (see `Economist,'
February 8, 1873)
£ 91,000,000
Total liabilities £ 120,000,000
Reserve of Cash
Banking Reserve in Bank of England. £ 13,500,000
Making proportion of cash reserve to liabilities to the public about per cent.
(2) BANK of FRANCE (FEBRUARY, 1873).
Liabilities
Circulation £ 110,000,000
Deposits £ 15,000,000
Total liabilities £ 125,000,000
Reserve of Cash.
Coin and bullion in hand £ 32,000,000
Making proportion of cash reserve to liabilities to the public about 25 per cent.
(3) BANKS OF GERMANY (JANUARY, 1873).
Liabilities
Circulation £ 63,000,000
Deposits £ 8,000,000
Acceptances and Indorsements £ 17,000,000
Total liabilities £ 88,000,000
Reserves of Cash
Cash in Hand £ 41,000,000
Making proportion of cash reserve to liabilities to the public about per cent.
(4) NATIONAL BANKS OF UNITED STATES (OCTOBER 3, 1872).
Liabilities
Circulation £ 67,000,000
Deposits £ 145,000,000
Total liabilities £ 212,000,000
Reserve of Cash
Coin and legal tenders in hand £ 26,000,000
Making proportion of cash reserve to liabilities to the public about 12.3 per cent.
SUMMARY
Liabilities to the
public
Cash held Proportion of cash to
liabilities per cent
Bank of England and London
Joint Stock Banks
120,000,000 13,500,000 11.2
Bank of France 125,000,000 32,000,000 25.0
Banks of Germany 88,000,000 41,000,000 47.0
National Banks of United States . 212,000,000 26,000,000 12.3
Note B.
Extract from Evidence Given by Mr. Alderman Salomons before House of Commons Select
Committee in 1858
1146. Chairman.] The effect upon yourselves of the pressure in No-. vember was, I presume, to
induce you to increase your reserve in your own hands, and also to increase your deposits with the
Bank of England'Yes, that was so; but I wish to tell the Committee that that was done almost entirely
by allowing the bills of exchange which we held to mature, and not by raising any money, or
curtailing our accommodation to our customers. Perhaps it may be interesting to the Committee to
know that on the 1 1th of November we held discounted bills for brokers to the amount of 5,623,000
l. Out of those bills, 2,800,000 l. matured between the 1 1th of November and the 4th of December,
and 2,000,0001. more between the 4th of December and the 3 1st. So that about 5,000,000 l. of bills
matured between the 1 1th of November and the 31st of December; consequently we were
prepared, merely by the maturing of our bills of exchange, for any demands that might possibly
come upon us.
1147. I understand you to say that you did not withdraw your usual accommodation from your own
customers, but that you ceased to have in deposit with the bill-brokers so large a sum of money as
you had before? Not exactly that; the bills which we had discounted were allowed to mature, and we
discounted less; we kept a large reserve of cash.
1148. That is to say, you withdrew from the commercial world a part of that accommodation which
you had previously given, and at the same time you increased your deposits with the Bank of
England?Yes, our deposits with the Bank of England were increased. We did not otherwise
withdraw accommodation.
1149. Mr. Weguelin.] Had you any money at call with the billbrokers?A small amount; perhaps about
500,000 l. or less, which we did not call in.
1150. Chairman.] What I understand you to say is, that the effect of the commercial pressure upon
you was to induce you upon the whole to withdraw from commerce an amount of accommodation
which in other times you had given, and at the same time to increase your deposits with the Bank of
England?So far only as ceasing to discount with strangers, persons not having current accounts
with us.
1151. Or to give the same amount to the bill-broker?For a while, instead of discounting for brokers
and strangers, we allowed our bills to mature, and remained quiescent with a view to enable us to
meet any demand that might be made on ourselves.
1152. Except what you felt bound to your own customers to continue to give, you ceased to make
advances?Quite so; perhaps I might say at the same time, that besides a large balance which we
kept at the Bank of England, which of course was as available as in our own tills, we increased our
notes in our tills at the head office and at all the branches.
1153. I suppose at that time large sales of public securities were made by the London joint stock
banks, which securities were purchased by the public?It is understood that some joint stock and
other banks sold, but I believe it is quite certain that the public purchased largely, because they
always purchase when the funds fall.
1154. Are you prepared to give the Committee any opinion of your own as to the effect, one way or
the other, which the system of the joint stock banks may have produced with regard to aggravating
or diminishing the commercial pressure in the autumn of last year?I should state, generally, that the
joint stock banks, as well as all other banks, in London, by collecting money from those who had it
to spare, must of necessity have assisted, and could not do otherwise than assist commerce, both
then and at all other times.
1155. You say that your discounts, either at your own counter or through the bill-brokers, are
ordinarily very large, but that at the time of severest pressure you contracted them so far as you
thought was just to your own immediate customers?Yes; but the capital was still there, because it
was at the Bank of England, and it was capable of being used for short periods; if we did not want it,
others might have used it.
1156. Mr. Weguelin.] In fact, it was used by the Bank of England? Undoubtedly; I should suppose
so; there is no question about it.
1157. You, of course, felt quite certain that your deposits in the Bank of England might be had upon
demand?We had no doubt about it.
1158 You did not take into consideration the effect of the law of 1844, which might have placed the
Banking Department of the Bank of England in such a position as not to be able to meet the
demands of its depositors? I must say that that never gave us the smallest concern.
1159. You therefore considered that, if the time should arrive, the Government would interfere with
some measure as they had previously done to enable the Bank to meet the demands upon it?We
should always have thought that if the Bank of England had stopped payment, all the machinery of
Government would have stopped with it, and we never could have believed that so formidable a
calamity would have arisen if the Government could have prevented it.
1160. Chairman.] The notion of the convertibility of the note being in danger never crossed your
mind?Never for a moment; nothing of the kind.
1161. Mr. Weguelin.] I refer not to the convertibility of the note, but to the state of the Banking
Department of the Bank of England?If we had thought that there was any doubt whatever about it,
we should have taken our bank-notes and put them in our own strong chest. We could never for a
moment believe an event of that kind as likely to happen.
1162. Therefore you think that the measure taken by the Government, of issuing a letter authorising
the Bank of England to increase their issues of notes upon securities, was what was generally
expected by the commercial world, and what in future the commercial world would look to in such a
conjunction of circumstances?We looked for some measure of that nature. That, no doubt, was the
most obvious one. We had great doubts whether it would come when it did, until the very last
moment.
1163. Have you ever contemplated the possibility of the Bank refusing to advance, under
circumstances similar to those which existed in November, 1857, upon good banking securities?Of
course I have, and it is a very difficult question to answer as to what its effect might be; but the
notion appears to me to be so thoroughly ingrained in the minds of the commercial world, that
whenever you have good security it ought to be convertible at the Bank in some shape or way, that I
have very great doubt indeed whether the Bank can ever take a position to refuse to assist persons
who have good commercial securities to offer.
1164. Mr. Cayley.] When you say that you have come to some fresh arrangement with regard to
your allowance of interest upon deposits, do you speak of yourselves as the London and
Westminster Bank, or of some of the other banks in combination with yourselves?I think all the
banks have come to an understanding that it is not desirable, either for their proprietors or for the
public, to follow closely at all times the alterations of the Bank. I believe it is understood amongst
them all that they do not intend following that course in future.
x 165. Is that from a feeling that it is rather dangerous under particular circumstances?I cannot
admit as to its being dangerous, but there can be no doubt of this, that there is a notion in the public
mind which we ought not to contend against, that when you offer a high rate of interest for money,
you rather do it because you want the person's money, than because you are obeying the market
rate; and I think it is desirable that we should show that if persons wish to employ their money, and
want an excessive rate, they may take it away and employ it themselves.
1166. You think that there is now a general understanding amongst the banks which you have
mentioned, to act upon a different principle from that on which they acted during last October and
November?I think I may say that I know that to be the case.
1167. Was not it the fact that this system of giving so high a rate of interest upon money at call
commenced very much with the establishment of some banks during the last year or two, which,
instead of demanding 10 days' or a month's notice, were willing to allow interest upon only three
days' notice; did not that system begin about two years ago?I do not think it began with the new
banks; I think it began with one of the older banks; I know that as regards my own bank, that we
were forced into it; I forgot to say, that with regard to ourselves in taking money on deposit, the
parties must leave the money a month, or they lose interest. We do not take money from any
depositor at interest unless upon the understand ing and condition that it remains a month with us;
he may withdraw it within the month, but then he forfeits interest; it will not carry interest unless it is
with us a month, and then it is removable on demand without notice.
1168. Is it or is it not a fact that some of the banks pay interest upon their current accounts?Yes, I
think most of the new banks do so; and the Unlon Bank of London does it.
1169. At a smaller rate than upon their deposits, I presume?I think at a smaller rate, but I believe it
is a fixed rate on the minimum balance for some period, either six months or one month, I do not
exactly know the period. I think I ought to add (and I believe it is the case with all the banks) that the
London and Westminster Bank, from the day of its first institution until the present day, has never re-
discounted a bill. No bill has ever left our bank unless it has been for payment.
1170. Is not that generally the case with the London joint stock banks? I believe it is the case.
1171. Mr. Weguelin.] But you sometimes lend money upon bills deposited with you by bill-
brokers?Yes.
1172. And you occasionally call in that money and re-deliver those securities?Yes; but that we do to
a very small extent.
1173. Is not that equivalent to a re-discount of bills?No; the discount of a bill and the lending money
on bills are very different things. When we discount a bill, that bill becomes our property; it is in our
control, and we keep it and lock it up until it falls due; but when brokers come to us and want to
borrow, say 50,000 l. on a deposit of bills, and we let them have the money and afterwards return
those bills to them and we get back our money, surely that is not a re-discount.
1174. When you want to employ your money for a short period, do you not frequently take bills of
long date, and advance upon them?But that is not a re-discount on our part. Very often brokers in
borrowing money send in bills of long date, and afterwards we call in that loan; but that is no more a
re-discount than lending money upon consols and calling in that money again. It is not an advance
of ours; we do not seek it; they come to us and borrow our money, and give us a security; when we
want our money we call for that money, and return their security. Surely that is not a re-discount.
1175. Mr. Hankey.] Is there not this clear distinction between returning a bill on which you have
made an advance and discounting a bill, that if you have discounted a bill your liability continues
upon the bill until that bill has come to maturity?Yes.
1176. In the other case you have no further liability whatever?Certamly.
1177. Should you not consider that a very important distinction?I think it is an important distinction.
Take this case: suppose a party comes to us and borrows 50,000 l., and we lend it him, and when
the loan becomes due we take our money back again. Surely that is not a discount on our part.
1178. Is there not this distinction, that if you re-discount you may go on pledging the liability of your
bank to an almost unlimited amount, whereas in the other case you only get back that money which
you have lent?Undoubtedly.
1179. Mr. Cayley.] The late Chancellor of the Exchequer stated before the adjournment, in a speech
in the House of Commons, that during the Monday, Tuesday, Wednesday, and Thursday of the
panic, the Bank was almost, if not entirely, the only body that discounted commercial bills; how can
you reconcile that with what you have said, that you gave as much accommodation as usual to your
customers?I am not responsible for what the Chancellor of the Exchequer said; I am responsible for
what I am now stating as to the course of our bank, that our advances to our customers on the 31st
of December were nearly 500,0001. higher than they were on the 1st of October. With regard to our
not discounting for other parties, it was in consequence of the discredit which prevailed, that it was
necessary we should hold a portion of our deposits in order that they should be available in case
persons called for them; a certain number of persons did so; in the month of November we had a
reduction of our deposits, and if we had gone on discounting for brokers we should have had to go
into the market ourselves to raise money on our Government securities, but we avoided that by not
discounting, and leaving our money at the Bank of England.
i8o. Then you did not discount as much as usual for your customers during that period?Yes. we did,
and more.
1181. But not to strangers?Not to strangers; I make a distinction between our transactions with our
customers, who of course expect us to give accommodation, and discounts for brokers, which is
entirely voluntary, depending upon our having money to employ.
1182. How would it have been if the letter had not issued at the last moment? That is a question
which I can hardly answer.
1183. What do you mean by that general expression of yours?It is impossible to predicate what may
happen in time of panic and alarm. A great alarm prevailed certainly amongst the commercial world,
and it could never have been alleviated, except by some extraordinary means of relief. We might
probably have been in the state in which Hamburg was, where they have no bank-notes in
circulation.
1184. Mr. Spooner.] What did you mean by the expression, `the last moment'? You said that the
letter came out at the last moment; the last moment of what?It was late in the day; it was a day of
great distress. For two days there was a great deal of anxiety, and everybody expected that there
would be some relief; and it was when expectation, I suppose, was highly excited that the letter
came, and it gave relief.
1185. Cannot you tell us what your opinion would have been, if that last moment had happened to
have elapsed, and the letter had not come? It is very difficult to say; it is too much to say that it could
not have been got over. There can be no doubt whatever that what created the difficulty existed out
of London, and not in it; and therefore it is much more difficult for me to give an opinion. I believe
that the banking interest, both private and joint stock, was in a perfectly sound condition, and able to
bear any strain which might have been brought upon it in London.
1186. Mr. Han key.] Can you give the Committee any idea as to what proportion of deposits you
consider generally desirable to keep in reserve? You must be very much guided by circumstances.
In times of alarm, when there are failures, of course all bankers strengthen their reserves; our
reserve then is larger. In times of ordinary business we find, both as regards our deposits at interest
as well as those which are not at interest, that there is a constant circulation; that the receipts of
money very nearly meet the payments.
1187. You probably keep at all times a certain amount of your deposits totally unemployed; in
reserve?Yes.
1188. In a normal state of commercial affairs, is there any fixed proportion, or can you give the
Committee any idea of what you would consider about a fair and desirable proportion which should
be so kept unemployed?I think the best idea which I can give upon that subject is to give our annual
statement, or balance sheet, for the 31st of December.
1189. Does that show what amount of unemployed money you had on that day?Yes. I will put in a
statement, which perhaps will be the best means of meeting the question, showing the cash in hand
on the 30th of June and the 31st of December in every year, as shown by our published accounts,
together with our money at call and our Government securities; that will be perhaps the best and
most convenient way of giving the information you desire to have. (See Table below.)
1190. Do you consider that when your deposits are materially on the increase it is necessary to
keep a larger amount of money in reserve than you would keep at other times?I may say that, as a
general rule, our reserve would always bear some proportion to our deposits.
Total Lodgments with London and Westminster Bank; also Amount of Cash in Hand, Moneys with
Bill-Brokers at Call, and Government Securities held by the Bank.
DATE Deposits Cash in
Hand
Money at Call Government
Securities
TOTAL
31 December
1845
3,590,014 563,072 628,500 1,039,745 2,231,317
31 December
1846
3,280,864 634,575 423,060 938,717 1,996,352
31 December
1847
2,733,753 7,231,325 350,108 791,899 1,863,332
30 June 1848 3,170,118 588,871 159,724 1,295,047 2,043,642
31 December
1848
3,089,659 645,468 176,824 1,189,213 2,011,505
30 June 1849 3,392,857 552,642 246,494 964,800 1,763,936
31 December
1849
3,680,623 686,761 264,577 973,691 1,224,029
30 June 1850 3,821,022 654,649 258,177 972,055 1,884,881
31 December
1850
3,969,648 566,039 334,982 1,089,794 1,990,815
30 June 1851 4,414,179 691,719 424,195 1,054,018 2,169,932
31 December
1851
4,677,298 653,946 378,337 1,054,018 2,080,301
30 June 1852 5,245,135 861,778 136,687 1,054,018 2,122,483
31 December
1852
5,581,706 855,057 397,087 1,119,477 2,371,621
30 June 1853 6,219,817 904,252 499,467 1,218,852 2,622,571
31 December
1853
6,259,540 791,699 677,392 1,468,902 2,937,993
30 June 1854 6,892,470 827,397 917,557 1,457,415 3,202,369
31 December
1854
7,177,244 694,309 486,400 1,451,074 2,631,783
30 June 1855 8,166,553 722,243 483,890 1,754,074 2,960,207
31 December
1855
8,744,095 847,856 451,575 1,949,074 3,248,505
30 June 1856 11,170,010 906,876 601,800 1,980,489 3,489,165
31 December
1856
11,438,461 1,119,591 432,000 2,922,625 4,474,216
30 June 1857 13,913,058 967,078 687,730 3,353,179 5,007,987
31 December
1857
113,889,021 2,226,441 1,115,883 3,582,797 6,923,121
1191. Do you employ your money in the discounting of bills for other persons than your own
customers?Discount brokers.
1192. Only to discount brokers? Yes.
1193. Not to strangers who are in the habit of bringing you in bills; commercial houses?I should say
generally not. We have one or two houses for whom we discount who have not accounts with us as
bankers, but generally we do not discount except for our customers or for billbrokers.
1194. Do you consider that any advantage can arise to the public by the Bank of England advancing
to a greater extent than can be considered strictly prudent on the soundest principle of banking,
under the idea of their affording aid to the commercial world?As I said before, as long as there are
good bills in circulation, that is, bills about which there would be no doubt of their being paid at
maturity, there should be some means by which those bills could be discounted.
1195. And do you think that it is part of the functions of the Bank of England to discount a bill for
anybody, merely because the party holding the bill wishes to convert it into cash?As I said before,
the Bank of England will have great difficulty in getting rid of that inconvenient idea which there is in
the mind of the public, that the Bank of England is something more than an ordinary joint stock
bank. I think it must depend very much upon circumstances whether you can or cannot refuse the
discount of good bills which are offered to you.
Note C.
Statement of Circulation and Deposits of the Bank of Dundee at Intervals of Ten Years between
1764 and 1864.
Year Circulation Deposits
1764 30,395 --
1774 27,670 --
1784 56,342 --
1794 50,354 --
1804 54,096 157,821
1814 46,627 445,066
1824 29,675 343,948
1834 26,467 563,202
1844 27,504 535,253
1854 40,774 705,222
1864 41,118 684,898
The Bank did not begin to receive deposits until 1792, in which year they amounted to 35,9441.
Note D.
Meeting of the Proprietors of the Bank of England. September 13, 1866. (From `Economist,'
September 22, 1866.)
A General Court of the Bank of England was held at the Bank at twelve o'clock on the 3th instant,
for the purpose of declaring a dividend for the past half-year.
Mr. Launcelot Holland, the Governor of the Bank, who presided upon the occasion, addressed the
proprietors as follows: This is one of the quarterly general courts appointed by our charter, and it is
also one of our half-yearly general courts, held under our bye-laws, for the purpose of declaring a
dividend. From a statement which I hold in my hand it appears that the net profits of the Bank for the
half-year ending on the 31st of August last amounted to 970,014). 17s. 10d.; making the amount of
the rest on that day, 3,981,7831. 18s. 11d.; and after providing for a dividend at the rate of 6 l. 10s.
per cent, the rest will stand at 3,035,838 l.. 18s. 11d. The court of directors, therefore, propose that a
half-yearly dividend of interest and profits, to the amount of 61. 10s. per cent, without deduction on
account of income tax, shall be made on the 10th of October next. That is the proposal I have now
to lay before the general court; but as important events have occurred since we last met, I think it
right I should briefly advert to them upon this occasion. A great strain has within the last few months
been put upon the resources of this house, and of the whole banking community of London; and I
think I am entitled to say that not only this house but the entire banking body acquitted themselves
most honourably and creditably throughout that very trying period. Banking is a very peculiar
business, and it depends so much upon credit that the least blast of suspicion is sufficient to sweep
away, as it were, the harvest of a whole year. But the manner in which the banking establishments
generally of London met the demands made upon them during the greater portion of the past half-
year affords a most satisfactory proof of the soundness of the principles on which their business is
conducted. This house exerted itself to the utmostand exerted itself most successfullyto meet the
crisis. We did not flinch from our post. When the storm came upon us, on the morning on which it
became known that the house of Overend and Co. had failed, we were in as sound and healthy a
position as any banking establishment could hold; and on that day and throughout the succeeding
week, we made advances which would hardly be credited. I do not believe that any one would have
thought of predicting, even at the shortest period beforehand, the greatness of those advances. It
was not unnatural that in this state of things a certain degree of alarm should have taken possession
of the public mind, and that those who required accommodation from the Bank should have gone to
the Chancellor of the Exchequer and requested the Government to empower us to issue notes
beyond the statutory amount, if we should think that such a measure was desirable. But we had to
act before we could receive any such power, and before the Chancellor of the Exchequer was
perhaps out of his bed we had advanced one-half of our reserves, which were certainly thus
reduced to an amount which we could not witness without regret. But we could not flinch from the
duty which we conceived was imposed upon us of supporting the banking community, and I am not
aware that any legitimate application for assistance made to this house was refused. Every
gentleman who came here with adequate security was liberally dealt with, and if accommodation
could not be afforded to the full extent which was demanded, no one who offered proper security
failed to obtain relief from this house. I have perhaps gone a little more into details than is
customary upon these occasions, but the times have been unusually interesting, and I thought it
desirable to say this much in justification of the course adopted by this house of running its balances
down to a point which some gentlemen may consider dangerous. Looking back, however, upon
recent events, I cannot take any blame to this court for not having been prepared for such a tornado
as that which burst upon us on the ith of May; and I hope the court of proprietors will feel that their
directors acted properly upon that occasion, and that they did their best to meet a very extraordinary
state of circumstances. I have now only to move that a dividend be declared at the rate of 6 l. 10s.
per cent for the past half-year.
Mr. Hyam said that before the question was put he wished to offer a few observations to the court.
He believed that the statement of accounts which had just been laid before them was perfectly
satisfactory. He also thought that the directors had done their best to assist the commercial classes
throughout the late monetary crisis; but it appeared to him at the same time that they were in fault in
not having applied at an earlier period to the Chancellor of the Exchequer for a suspension of the
Bank Act. It was well known that the demand on the Bank was materially lessened in the earlier part
of the day, in consequence of a rumour which had been extensively circulated that permission to
overstep the limits laid down in the Act had been granted. That concession, however, had only been
made after the most urgent representations had been addressed to the Chancellor of the Exchequer
at a late hour in the night, and if it had then been refused he felt persuaded that the state of affairs
would have been much worse on the Saturday than it had been on the Friday. The fact was that the
Act of 1844 was totally unsuited to the present requirements of the country, which since that period
had tripled or quadrupled its commerce; and he was sorry to know that the measure seemed to
meet with the approval of many of their directors. Any one who read the speeches made in the
course of the discussion on Mr. Watkins' motion must see that the subject called for further inquiry;
and he trusted that the demand for that inquiry would yet be conceded.
Mr. Jones said he entirely dissented from the views with respect to the Bank Act entertained by the
hon. proprietor who had just addressed the court. In his opinion the main cause of the recent
monetary crisis was that, while we had bought 275,000,000 l. worth of foreign produce in the year
1865, the value of our exports had only been 165,000,000 l., so that we had a balance against us to
the amount of 110,000,000 l. He believed that the Bank acted wisely in resisting every attempt to
increase the paper currency, and he felt convinced that the working classes would be the people
least likely to benefit by the rise in prices which would take place under such a change.
Mr. Moxon said he should be glad to know what was the amount of bad debts made by the Bank
during the past half-year. It was stated very confidently out of doors that during that period the
directors had between 3,000,0001. and 4,000,000 l. of bills returned to them.
The Governor of the Bank.May I ask what is your authority for that statement? We are rather
amused at hearing it, and we have never been able to trace any rumour of the kind to an authentic
source.
Mr. Moxon continuedWhether the bad debts were large or small, he thought it was desirable that
they should all know what was their actual amount. They had been told at their last meeting that the
Bank held a great many railway debentures; and he should like to know whether any of those
debentures came from railway companies that had since been unable to meet their obligations. He
understood that a portion of their property was locked up in advances made on account of the
Thames Embankment, and in other ways which did not leave the money available for general
banking and commercial purposes; and if that were so, he should express his disapproval of such a
policy. There was another important point to which he wished to advert. He was anxious to know
what was the aggregate balance of the joint stock banks in the Bank of England. He feared that
some time or other the joint stock banks would be in a position to command perhaps the stoppage
of the Bank of England. If that were not so, the sooner the public were full& informed upon the point
the better. But if ten or twelve joint stock banks had large balances in the Bank of England, and if
the Bank balances were to run very low, people would naturally begin to suspect that the joint stock
banks had more power over the Bank of England than they ought to have. He wished further to ask
whether the directors had of late taken into consideration the expediency of paying interest on
deposits. He believed that under their present mode of carrying on their business they were
foregoing large profits which they might receive with advantage to themselves and to the public; and
he would recommend that they should undertake the custody of securities after the system adopted
by the Bank of France. In conclusion, he proposed to move three resolutions, for the purpose of
providing, first, that a list of all the proprietors of Bank stock should be printed, with a separate entry
of the names of all those persons not entitled to vote from the smallness of their stock, or from the
shortness of time during which they held it; secondly, that a copy of the charter of the Bank, with the
rules, orders, and bye-laws passed for the good government of their corporation, should be printed
for the use of the shareholders; and thirdly, that auditors should be appointed to make detailed
audits of their accounts.
Mr. Gerstenberg recommended that the directors should take some step for the purpose of
preventing the spread of such erroneous notions as that which lately prevailed on the Continent, that
the Bank was about to suspend specie payments.
Mr. W. Botly said he wished to see the directors taking into their consideration the expediency of
allowing interest on deposits.
Mr. Alderman Salomons said he wished to take that opportunity of stating that he believed nothing
could be more satisfactory to the managers and shareholders of joint stock banks than the
testimony which the Governor of the Bank of England had that day borne to the sound and
honourable manner in which their business was conducted. It was mainfestly desirable that the joint
stock banks and the banking interest generally should work in harmony with the Bank of England;
and he sincerely thanked the Governor of the Bank for the kindly manner in which he had alluded to
the mode in which the joint stock banks had met the late monetary crisis.
The Governor of the Bank saidBefore putting the question for the declaration of a dividend, I wish to
refer to one or two points that have been raised by the gentlemen who have addressed the court on
this occasion. The most prominent topic brought under our notice is the expediency of allowing
interest on deposits; and upon that point I must say that I believe a more dangerous innovation
could not be made in the practice of the Bank of England. The downfall of Overend and Gurney, and
of many other houses, must be traced to the policy which they adopted of paying interest on
deposits at call, while they were themselves tempted to invest the money so received in
speculations in Ireland or in America, or at the bottom of the sea, where it was not available when a
moment of pressure arrived.
Mr. Botly said he did not mean deposits on call.
The Governor of the Bank of England continuedThat is only a matter of detail; the main question is
whether we ought to pay interest on deposits, and of such policy I must express my entire
disapproval. Mr. Moxon has referred to the amount of our debts, but, as I stated when I took the
liberty of interrupting him, we could never trace the origin of any rumour which prevailed upon that
subject. As far as it can be said to have ever existed it had its origin most probably in the vast
amount advanced by the Bank. It must, however, be remembered that we did not make our
advances without ample security, and the best proof of that is the marvelously small amount of bad
debts which we contracted. It has never been a feature of the Bank to state what was the precise
amount of those debts; but I believe that if I were to mention it upon the present occasion, it would
be found to be so inconsiderable that I should hardly obtain credence for the announcement I
should have to make. I am convmced that our present dividend has been as honestly and as hardly
earned as any that we have ever realised; but it has been obtained by means of great vigilance and
great anxiety on the part of each and all of your directors; and I will add that I believe you would only
diminish their sense of responsibility, and introduce confusion into the management of your
business, if you were to transfer to auditors the making up of your ac counts. If your directors
deserve your confidence they are surely capable of performing that duty, and if they do not deserve
it you ought not to continue them in their present office. With regard to the supposed lock-up of our
capital, I must observe that, with 14,000,000 l. on our hands, we must necessarily invest it in a
variety of securities; but there is no ground for imagining that our money is locked up and is not
available for the purpose of making commercial advances. We advanced in the space of three
months the sum of 45,000,000 l.; and what more than that do you want? It has been recommended
that we should take charge of securities; but we have found it necessary to refuse all securities
except those of our customers; and I believe the custody of securities is becoming a growing evil.
With regard to railway debentures, I do not believe we have one of a doubtful character. We have
no debentures except those of first-class railway companies and companies which we know are
acting within their Parliamentary limits. Having alluded to those subjects, I will now put the motion
for the declaration of the dividend.
The motion was accordingly put and unanimously adopted.
The chairman then announced that that resolution should be confirmed by ballot on Tuesday next,
inasmuch as the Bank could not, under the provisions of its Act of Parliament, declare otherwise
than in that form a dividend higher than that which it had distributed during the preceding half-year.
The three resolutions proposed by Mr. Moxon were then read; but they were not put to the meeting,
inasmuch as they found no seconders.
Mr. Alderman Salomons said that their Governor had observed that he thought the payment of
interests on deposits was objectionable; and everyone must see that such a practice ought not to be
adopted by the Bank of England. But he took it for granted that the Governor did not mean that his
statement should apply to joint stock banks which he had himself told them had conducted their
business so creditably and so successfully.
The Governor of the Bank said that what he stated was that such a system would be dangerous for
the Bank of England, and dangerous if carried into effect in the way contemplated by Mr. Moxon.
Mr. P. N. Laurie said he understood the Governor of the Bank to say that it would be dangerous to
take deposits on call, and in that opinion he concurred.
Mr. Alderman Salomons said that he, too, was of the same opinion.
On the motion of Mr. Alderman Salomons, seconded by Mr. Botly, a vote of thanks was passed to
the Governor and the directors for their able and successful management of the Bank during the
past half-year, and the proceedings then terminated.
Notes:
1. See Note A at the end of the volume.
2. See Note B. at the end of the volume.
3. Smith's `Wealth of Nations,' Book IV. chap. iii. `Digression concerning Banks of Deposit,' &c.
4. See Note C in Appendix.
5. These are the amounts at December 31, 1865. See `Grundzüge der National-Oekonomie. Von
Max Wirth.' Drirter Band, p. 491.
6. See Note D in the Appendix.
7. Vide Economist of September 22, 1866.
Livros Grátis
( http://www.livrosgratis.com.br )
Milhares de Livros para Download:
Baixar livros de Administração
Baixar livros de Agronomia
Baixar livros de Arquitetura
Baixar livros de Artes
Baixar livros de Astronomia
Baixar livros de Biologia Geral
Baixar livros de Ciência da Computação
Baixar livros de Ciência da Informação
Baixar livros de Ciência Política
Baixar livros de Ciências da Saúde
Baixar livros de Comunicação
Baixar livros do Conselho Nacional de Educação - CNE
Baixar livros de Defesa civil
Baixar livros de Direito
Baixar livros de Direitos humanos
Baixar livros de Economia
Baixar livros de Economia Doméstica
Baixar livros de Educação
Baixar livros de Educação - Trânsito
Baixar livros de Educação Física
Baixar livros de Engenharia Aeroespacial
Baixar livros de Farmácia
Baixar livros de Filosofia
Baixar livros de Física
Baixar livros de Geociências
Baixar livros de Geografia
Baixar livros de História
Baixar livros de Línguas
Baixar livros de Literatura
Baixar livros de Literatura de Cordel
Baixar livros de Literatura Infantil
Baixar livros de Matemática
Baixar livros de Medicina
Baixar livros de Medicina Veterinária
Baixar livros de Meio Ambiente
Baixar livros de Meteorologia
Baixar Monografias e TCC
Baixar livros Multidisciplinar
Baixar livros de Música
Baixar livros de Psicologia
Baixar livros de Química
Baixar livros de Saúde Coletiva
Baixar livros de Serviço Social
Baixar livros de Sociologia
Baixar livros de Teologia
Baixar livros de Trabalho
Baixar livros de Turismo