Download PDF
ads:
Renato Alencar Adelino da Costa
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special
GARCH models
Tese de Doutorado
Thesis presented to the Postgraduate Program in Engenharia
El´etrica of the Departamento de Engenharia El´etrica, PUC–Rio
as partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doutor
em Engenharia El´etrica
Advisor : Prof.
´
Alvaro de Lima Veiga Filho
Co–Advisor: Prof. Tak Kuen Siu
Rio de Janeiro
August 2010
ads:
Livros Grátis
http://www.livrosgratis.com.br
Milhares de livros grátis para download.
Renato Alencar Adelino da Costa
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special
GARCH models
Thesis presented to the Postgraduate Program in Engenharia
El´etrica of the Departamento de Engenharia El´etrica, PUC–Rio
as partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doutor
em Engenharia El´etrica. Approved by the following commission:
Prof.
´
Alvaro de Lima Veiga Filho
Advisor
Departamento de Engenharia El´etrica –PUC-Rio
Prof. Tak Kuen Siu
Co–Advisor
Department of Actuarial Studies, Faculty of Business and
Economics, Macquarie University
Prof. Caio Ibsen de Almeida
EPGE–FGV
Prof. Adrian Heringer Pizzinga
Departamento de Estat´ıstica UFF
Prof. Paulo Henrique Soto Costa
Faculdade de Ciˆencias Econˆomicas, Departamento de An´alise
Quantitativa UERJ
Prof. Marcelo Cunha Medeiros
Departamento de Economia PUC-Rio
Prof. Joel Maur´ıcio Corrˆea da Rosa
Departamento de Estat´ıstica UFF
Prof. Carlos Kubrusly
Departamento de Engenharia El´etrica PUC-Rio
Prof. Jos´e Eugenio Leal
Coordinator of the Centro ecnico Cient´ıfico PUC–Rio
Rio de Janeiro August 17, 2010
ads:
All rights reserved.
Renato Alencar Adelino da Costa
Renato Costa is a Master in Mathematics, graduated from
the Pontifical Catholic University of Rio de Janeiro (Rio
de Janeiro, Brazil). There he studied Applied mathematics
with the intent of using it in Finance. He recently spent 9
months at the Department of Mathematics and Statistics of
Curtin University of Technology where he did research for his
PhD thesis as a exchange/sandwich student sponsored by the
National Council for Scientific and technological Development
(CNPq)
Bibliographic data
Costa, Renato Alencar Adelino da
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH
models / Renato Alencar Adelino da Costa ; advisor:
´
Alvaro
de Lima Veiga Filho; co–advisor: Tak Kuen Siu. 2010.
103 f. : il. ; 30 cm
Tese (Doutorado em Engenharia El´etrica)-Pontif´ıcia Uni-
versidade Cat´olica do Rio de Janeiro, Rio de Janeiro, 2010.
Inclui bibliografia
1. Engenharia El´etrica Teses. 2. Apre¸camento de op¸oes.
3. Mudan¸ca de medida. 4. GARCH. 5. FC-GARCH. 6. Mistura
de GARCHs. 7. Transformada de Esscher condicional. I. Veiga,
´
Alvaro de Lima . II. Siu, Tak Kuen. III. Pontif´ıcia Universidade
Cat´olica do Rio de Janeiro. Departamento de Engenharia
El´etrica. IV. T´ıtulo.
CDD: 510
Acknowledgments
Firstly, I’d like to thank my advisors
´
Alvaro de Lima Veiga Filho and
Tak Kuen Siu for the patience and help provided.
I also would like to thank Professor Carlos Kubrusly for the knowledge
and advice given during some of my doctoral courses, Professors Cristiano
Fernandes, Marcos da Silveira and Tara Baydia for the initial guidances in my
first year as a PhD student and Thomas Lewiner for helping me fixing my
thesis tex file.
My life relies strongly in the support given by my family, not only
financially but also emotionally, so I must thank a lot my wife Cristiane Gomes
Silva da Costa, for her forbearance and understanding when I couldn’t be
with her to study, my father Jos´e Adelino da Costa and my mother Regina
Maria Alencar da Costa for everything they’ve done for me, my sister Roberta
Alencar Adelino da Costa Lopes Correia, my nephew J´ulio esar, my aunt
Alcina da Concei¸ao Coutinho, my un cle Ricardo Borges Alencar and my
grandparents Neemias Alencar and Maria Aparecida Borges Alencar and also
my grandmother Celeste Costa Adelino that unfourtunately is not among us
anymore.
I also would like to thank my personal friends for their friendship, in
particular to Anderson Mazzoli Lisboa, D´ecio Marques de Paiva, Rafael Brasil,
Rafael Ferr˜ao, S´ergio Adriano and Viviane Martins for the support given as
true friends.
I thank PUC-Rio as well as the secretaries for the support provided and
the National Council of Research (CNPq) for providing me the scholarship not
only in Brazil but also during my research at Curtin University of Technology
as a sandwich/exchange student where I learned a lot and made many personal
and professional important contacts.
My thanks to my friends and colleagues at Curtin and PUC-Rio: Adrian
Pizzinga, Andr´e Cunha, Aldo Ferreira, Alexandre Santos, Alexandre Street,
Bernardo Pagnoncelli, Caio Azevedo, Camila Epprecht, Cristina Vidigal, Davi
Michel, Deepak Candeep, Ling Wang, Luiz Oz´orio, arcio Candeias, Mariana
Paix˜ao, Marlene Marchena, Masnita Misirian, Nattakorn Phewchean (Mick),
Regina Fukuda, Reinaldo Marques, Rodrigo Atherino, Rodrigo Moreira Topin,
Rodrigo Sechin, Rodrigo Silva Mello, Waseem AlShanti and Wilson Freitas.
Abstract
Costa, Renato Alencar Adelino da; Veiga,
´
Alvaro de Lima ; Siu, Tak
Kuen. Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH
models. Rio de Janeiro, 2010. 103p. Tese de Doutorado Departamento
de Engenharia El´etrica, Pontif´ıcia Universidade Cat´olica do Rio de
Janeiro.
Option pricing is a very imp ortant issue nowadays. The use of probabilis-
tic methods is required for risk neutral pricing. Here we apply the method of
Siu et al. for two classes of GARCHs, viz., the FC-GARCH and the Mixture
of GARCHs.
In both models we derive the risk neutral version of the mo d el which is
essential for pricing contracts, in two different cases, when the noise is normal
as well as when it is shifted gamma.
We also performed simulations with both models and compared to the
benchmark Black Scholes model, checked for the smile effect and made some
sensibility analysis in the parameters.
Keywords
Option Pricing. Change of measure. GARCH. FC-GARCH. Mix-
ture of GARCHs. Conditional Esscher transform.
Resumo
Costa, Renato Alencar Adelino da; Veiga,
´
Alvaro de Lima ; Siu, Tak
Kuen. Apre¸camento neutro ao risco de opoes sob modelos
GARCH especiais. Rio de Janeiro, 2010. 103p. Tese de Doutorado
Departamento de Engenharia El´etrica, Pontif´ıcia Universidade Cat´olica
do Rio de Janeiro.
O apre¸camento de op¸oes ´e um assunto muito importante nos dias de
hoje. M´etodos probabilisticos ao necess´arios para fazer o apre¸camento neutro
ao risco. Usaremos o m´etodo de Siu et al. para duas classes de GARCHs, o
FC-GARCH e a mistura de GARCHs
Em amb os os modelos os encontramos a vers˜ao neutra ao risco do
modelo que ´e necess´aria para a precifica¸ao de contratos, em dois diferentes
casos, quando o ru´ıdo ´e normal e quando ´e shifted gamma.
Fizemos tamb´em simula¸oes para ilustrar e comparamos os resultados
com o valor de Black Scholes, verificamos a existˆencia de smile e fizemos uma
an´alise de sensibilidade nos parˆametros
Palavras–chave
Apre¸camento de op¸oes. Mudan¸ca de medida. GARCH. FC-
GARCH. Mistura de GARCHs. Transformada de Esscher condicional.
Contents
1 Introduction 8
2 Continuous Time Finance 12
2.1 Initial Definitions 12
2.2 Equivalences among Processes and other Definitions 13
2.3 Martingales 14
2.4 Stochastic Integrals 16
2.5 Itˆo Processes, Differentiation Rule and Solution of a SDE 17
2.6 Examples of Itˆo Formula 20
2.7 Change of Measure 24
3 GARCH Models 26
3.1 ARCH Models 26
3.2 Flexible Coefficient Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Het-
eroskedastic (FC-GARCH) 27
4 Option Pricing 29
4.1 Pricing Formula in the Risk-Neutral Measure 29
4.2 Black-Scholes-Merton Formula 31
4.3 Put-Call Parity 33
4.4 Incomplete Markets 34
4.5 Duan’s breakthrough 37
5 Option Pricing under a Nonlinear and Nonnormal GARCH 40
5.1 Flexible Coefficient Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Het-
eroskedastic (FC-GARCH) models for Asset Returns 40
5.2 The Conditional Esscher Transform 42
5.3 Some Parametric Cases 46
5.4 Simulation Studies 53
5.5 Sensitivity Analysis 64
5.6 Discussion of the results 65
5.7 Conclusions 65
6 Option Valuation under Mixture GARCH models 67
6.1 Asset Price Dynamics and Pricing Model 67
6.2 Parametric Cases 76
6.3 Empirical Results and Discussion 82
6.4 Sensitivity Analysis 94
6.5 Summary and discussion 95
7 Future works and finak remarks 96
Bibliography 97
A Appendix 101
1
Introduction
Option valuation is one of the most important topics in financial eco-
nomics. The path-breaking work by Black and Scholes (1973)(6) and Merton
(1973)(37) provides the cornerstone for an explosive growth in the literature
describing the theory and p ractice of option pricing models. The key economic
insights behind the Black-Scholes-Merton model are the concept of perfect
hedging of an option, by constructing a replicating portfolio via trading the
underlying assets continuously, and pricing by the no-arbitrage principle. Cox,
Ross and Rubinstein (1979) (12) were the first to establish the relationship be-
tween the risk-neutral valuation and the no-arbitrage principle. Harrison and
Kreps (1979)(33), and Harrison and Pliska (1981, 1983)(34) (35) established
a solid mathematical foundation for the relationship between the no-arbitrage
principle and the notion of risk-neutral valuation using the language of proba-
bility theory. They also provide a solid theoretical foundation to the concept of
market incompleteness. If the securities market is complete, there is a unique
equivalent martingale measure, i.e., a unique risk neutral measure and , hence,
the unique price of any contingent claim is given by its expected discounted
payoff at expiry under the martingale measure. However, in an incomplete mar-
ket, there are infinitely many equivalent martingale measures and, so, a range
of no-arbitrage prices for a contingent claim can be found, and this complicates
the pricing and hedging issues.
ollmer and Sondermann (1986)(29), ollmer and Schweizer (1991)(28)
and Schweizer (1996)(40) determined the equivalent martingale pricing mea-
sure by minimizing the quadratic utility of the losses due to imperfect hedg-
ing. Davis (1997)(14) adopted a traditional valuation approach in economics,
namely the marginal rate of substitut ion, to determine a pricing measure by
solving a utility maximization problem. The seminal work by Gerber and Shiu
(1994)(31) provided a pertinent solution to the option pricing problem in an
incomplete market by using the Esscher transform, a time-honored tool in
actuarial science introduced by Esscher (1932)(25). Their model provided a
convenient and flexible way to price options under different parametric as-
sumptions on the stock returns within the class of infinitely divisible distribu-
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 9
tions. They can justify the pricing result by considering a utility maximization
problem with respect to a power utility function. Their significant contribu-
tions highlighted the interplay between the financial and insurance pricing
in incomplete markets and its importantance is mentioned in B¨uh lmann et
al. (1996) (9) and Embrechts (2001) (24). uhlmann et al. (1996) (9) devel-
oped the conditional Esscher transform by generalizing the classical Esscher
transform to stochastic processes in order to incorporate the richer theory of
semi-martingales under the no-arbitrage condition in the Gerber-Shiu option-
pricing model. B¨uhlmann et al. (1998) (10) investigated the use of Esscher
transforms in discrete finance models and established a solid foundation for its
use based on economic arguments. Siu, Tong and Yang (2001) (42) introduced
the concept of a random Esscher transform with a random Esscher parameter
and adopted the random Esscher transform to incorporate the uncertainty of
the probability measures for r isk measurement. Elliott, Chan and Siu (2004)
(22) provided a modification of the random Esscher transform and developed
the regime switching random Esscher transform to identify a pricing measure
for option valuation und er a Markov-mod ulated Geometric Brownian Motion
(MMGBM). Yao (2002) (46) adopted the Esscher Transform to specify the
forward-risk-adjusted measure and provided a general and consistent frame-
work for pricing derivatives on stocks, interest rates and currency rates.
Autoregressive conditional heteroskedastic (ARCH) models were pro-
posed by the Nobel Laureate Robert Engle as a tool to describe time-varying
volatility dynamics and other stylised empirical facts of many financial time
series. Bollerslev (1986) (7) and Taylor (1986) (44) generalized the idea of the
ARCH models and developed the generalized ARCH (GARCH) models inde-
pendently by assuming that the current level of the conditional variance not
only depends on the past values of the innovations but also the past values
of the conditional variances. For an excellent overview of ARCH-type models,
see Bollerslev, Chou and Kroner (1992)(8).
There has been a considerable interest in option valuation under GARCH
models in the finance literature. The seminal work by Duan (1995) (17) was
the pioneer to provide a solid theoretical foundation for option valuation in
the context of GARCH models. He generalized the concept of risk-neutral val-
uation and introduced the notion of locally risk-neutral valuation relationship
(LRNVR) which provides a sou nd economic argument to choose a particu-
lar equivalent martingale measure in the GARCH mod el with a conditionally
normal stock innovation. Under the preference assumptions and distributional
assumptions, Duan (1995) provided a rigorous theoretical foundation and eco-
nomic justification of the validity of LRNVR. Duan, Popova and Ritcken (2002)
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 10
(19) developed a family of option pricing models where the underlying stock
price d ynamics are modelled by a regime switching process in which the prices
stay in one volatility regime for a random amount of time before switching
over into a new regime. Barone- Adesi, Engle and Mancini (2008)(3) proposed
a new approach to compute option prices under the GARCH models in an in-
complete market framework. Their model allows the actual volatility of asset
returns to be different from the volatility of asset returns under the pricing
probability measure. Siu, Tong and Yang (2004) (43) proposed an alternative
method to price options under the GARCH models with infinitely divisible in-
novations by using the conditional Esscher transform proposed by B¨uhlmann
et al. (1996). Elliott, Siu and Chan (2004) introduced the use of a modified
version of the conditional Esscher transform, namely the Markov switching
conditional Esscher transform (MS CET), to determine an equivalent martin-
gale pricing measure under a Markov switching GARCH model. They justified
their pricing results by considering the stochastic power utility function with
Markov switching risk-aversion parameters.
The thesis extends the literature in two main points. First, we deal with
more general processes to perform option pricing than in Duan(1995) (17)
and Siu et al.(2004) (43), viz. the Flexible Coefficient GARCH model (FC-
GARCH) which is a nonlinear model and nests several well-known GARCH
specifications in the literature and th e mixture of GARCHs. Second, we can
treat those two models in a variety of innovation distributions, not being
restricted to the normal case as in Duan(1995) (17). In particular in this
thesis we perform calculations and simulations for the Normal and Shifted-
Gamma cases. A minor contribution is that we include the possibility of a
negative innovation in the Shifted-Gamma case. This allow us to mimic the
small and negative skewness usually found in the empirical literature. This
contribution give the practitioners flexibility in choosing among the Normal,
the positive and negative Shifted-Gamma innovation cases according to the
sign and magnitude of the skewness.
Although the non-linearity of the FC-GARCH affects little the prediction
of the volatility, it considerably affects the option prices. We notice both in
the FC-GARCH and in the Mixture of GARCHs that the option prices vary
a lot in our experiments. We also noticed that th e choice of the innovation
distribution is important for better describing the skewness of the series. We
deal with negative shifted-Gamma innovations to treat negative skewness data.
When using a different innovation, a significant difference in the option price
is also detected.
The document is structured as follows. First we make a review on the
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 11
mathematical background knowledge, then in chapter three we talk about the
simplest ARCH models. In chapter 4, we briefly discuss the option pricing
methodologies. Chapters 5 and 6 contain the main results of the research. They
consist of two risk n eutral option pricing papers, one assuming the FC-GARCH
as the underlying log-return process and the other a mixture of GARCHs. In
chapter 5, we develop the methodology in Siu et al.(2004) (43) to the FC-
GARCH. In chapter 6, we perform a similar methodology to the Mixture
of GARCHs. The theoretical results we achieved are the Theorems 35, 36,
41 and 42. In both these chapters we discuss the model, the methodology,
the calculations and simulation experiments. We finish the thesis with the
conclusions, future intent of work and a small app endix.
2
Continuous Time Finance
This Chapter will cover the basics of Probability Theory used in Finance
and then the use of it in Finance. We deal, in particular, with the topics
concerning Continuous Time Finance.
The work here is done with discrete time models but as the continuous
case account for the discrete case also as its particular case we will do all
discussion in continuous time for mental exercising and generality.
Most of what is here was made initially as beamer slides presented to my
co-advisor as a weekly seminar based from the Elliot and Kopp book (21) but
I also did a mixing of contents from other books such as the Lecture Notes of
Evans version 1.2 (26), Billingsley (4), Oksendal (38), Shreve (41) and Bingham
and Kiesel (5). We refer to these for some proofs and additional details.
2.1
Initial Definitions
This subsection deals with continuous time stochastic processes, so we
are going to consider that t lies in T , where T is one of the following sets:
[0, T ], [0, ) or [0, ]. And we will be always considering a probability space
(Ω, F, P).
Definition 1 (Filtration) F = {F
t
}
t∈T
is called a filtration if it is a increasing
family of sub-σ-algebras, i.e., if it is a family of σ-algebras such that for s t:
F
t
F, F
s
F
t
We also suppose that the filtration is complete and is right continuous in
the folowing sense: (Information now comes continuously.)
F
t
=
s>t
F
s
, t T
Definition 2 (Stochastic Processes) A continuous-time stochastic process X
taking values in a measurable space (E, E) is a family of r.v’s {X
t
} defined in
(Ω, F, P), indexed by t taking values in (E, E). Notice that:
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 13
X
t
(·) is a random variable.
X
·
(ω) is a path of the process X.
2.2
Equivalences among Processes and other Definitions
We are going to define different ways of comparing sto chastic processes as
well as clarify the d ifferences among those concepts. Besides that, we are going
to give some common definitions concerning the measurability of stochastic
processes.
Definition 3 (Equivalent Processes) Let
φ
X
t
1
,t
2
,...,t
n
(A) = P({ω : (X
t
1
(ω), X
t
2
(ω), ..., X
t
n
(ω)) A})
be a measure in R
n
. X and Y are equivalent if t heir families of finite
distributions coincides and we denote by X Y .
Definition 4 (Modification of a process) Suppose (X
t
)
t0
and (Y )
t0
two
proce sses defined on the same probability space (Ω, F, P) and taking values
in (E, E). The process {Y
t
} is said to be a modification of {X
t
} if
X
t
= Y
t
a.s. t T ;
i.e.,
P(X
t
= Y
t
) = 1 t T .
Remark: Note that for each t, it is possible to have a null set associated to it.
Definition 5 (Indistinguishable) Suppose (X
t
)
t0
and (Y )
t0
two processes
defined on the same probability space (Ω, F, P) and taking values in (E, E).
The process {Y
t
} is said to be indistinguishable from {X
t
} if for almost every
ω ,
X
t
(ω) = Y
t
(ω) t T ;
i.e.,
P({ω : X
t
(ω) = Y
t
(ω), t T }) = 1.
Remark: Note that in this case, there is only one null set.
Now we are going to present a concept concerning sets but that is related
to indistinguishability:
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 14
Definition 6 (Evanescent) A [0, ] × is evanescent if
1
A
(t, ω) =
1, if (t, ω) A
0, if (t, ω) / A
(2-1)
is indistinguishable from the zero process, i.e.,
P({ω : 1
A
(t, ω) = 0, t T }) = 1. (2-2)
what is equivalent to
P({ω : t T with (t, ω) A}) = 0. (2-3)
which means that the probability of having an omega that allows the existence
of a t such that the pair (t, ω) is in A is null.
Definition 7 (Adapted Process) X is said to be adapted to (F
t
)
t0
if X
t
is
F
t
-measurable t T .
It means that information comes according to time. No future information is
known. Here we can for each t, check the measurability of X as a function only
of omega.
Definition 8 (Progressively Measurable) The process X defined in ([0, T ] ×
, B([0, T ] × F)) to a measurable space (E, E) is said to be “progressively
measurable” (or simply “progressive”) if, for every time t [0, T ], the map
X : [0, T ] × E
(t, ω) → X
t
(ω)
is B([0, T ]) F
t
-Measurable function. This implies that X is F
t
-adapted.
This property asks a jointly measurability condition that concerns not only
the space but also time.
2.3
Martingales
One of the most important concepts in Finance is the process property
of being a martingale. Here we are going to define, give examples and see the
main related results shortly.
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 15
2.3.1
Definition
Definition 9 (Martingale) A real valued adapted process (M
t
) is said to be a
martingale with respect to the filtration {F
t
}
t∈T
if E|M
t
| < t and s t:
E[M
t
|F
s
] = M
s
. a.s.
If the equality is replaced by then (M
t
) is said to be a supermartingale.
If the equality is replaced by then (M
t
) is said to be a submartingale.
The martingale condition can be regarded as E[X
t
|F
s
] being a version of
the process X
t
:
A
E[X
t
|F
s
]dP =
A
X
s
dP A F
s
(2-4)
but by the definition of conditional expectation we have:
A
E[X
t
|F
s
]dP =
A
X
t
dP A F
s
(2-5)
so that for s t:
A
X
s
dP =
A
X
t
dP A F
s
. (2-6)
The martingale can be seen as a model for “fair games” or a “pure random
process” because given the information available ab out the process until now,
the expected value is the present value.
Remark: A martingale is a pr ocess “constant in mean”, in the sense
that
E[M
t
] = E[M
0
] t 0
Indeed,
E[M
t
|F
s
] = M
s
a.s. s t
implies
E[E[M
t
|F
s
]] = E[M
s
]
so that by the iterated expectation property:
E[M
t
] = E[M
s
] s t.
Theorem 10 (Levy) Let (B
t
)
t0
be a standard Brownian Motion with respect
to the filtration (F
t
)
t0
. Then:
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 16
a) (B
t
)
t0
is an F
t
-martingale.
b) (B
2
t
t)
t0
is an F
t
-martingale.
c) (e
σB
t
σ
2
t
2
)
t0
is an F
t
-martingale.
Also, the converse holds true (stated as Characterization of a Brownian
Motion in section 3.6). Besides that, there is a curious property of the
Brownian Motion, viz., its paths although continuous a.s. are non-differentiable
almost everywhere.
For the proof of this curiosity and the Theorem see Evans (26) and Elliot (21)
respectivelly.
2.4
Stochastic Integrals
Here we build the definition of the stochastic integral starting from simple
functions and finishing with a wider range of functions.
Definition 11 (Simple processes)Consider (W
t
) a (F
t
)-Brownian motion de-
fined on (Ω, F, P) . A real-valued simple process on [0, T ] is a function H for
which
a) There is a partition 0 = t
0
< t
1
< ... < t
n
= T ; and
b) H
t
0
= H
0
(ω) and H
t
= H
i
(ω) for t (t
i
, t
i+1
], where H
i
(·) is F
t
i
-
measurable and square integrable. That is,
H
t
= H
0
(ω) +
n1
i=0
H
i
(ω)1
(t
i
,t
i+1
]
, t [0, T ].
Definition 12 (Stochastic Integral of a simple process) If H is a simple
proce ss, the stochastic integral of H with respect to the Brownian Motion (W
t
)
is the process defined for t (t
k
, t
k+1
], by
t
0
H
s
dW
s
=
k1
i=0
H
i
(W
t
i+1
W
t
i
) + H
k
(W
t
W
t
k
).
This can be written as a martingale transform:
t
0
H
s
dW
s
=
n
i=0
H
i
(W
t
i+1
t
W
t
i
t
).
Theorem 13 Suppose H is a simple process. Then:
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 17
a)
t
0
H
s
dW
s
is a continuous F
t
-martingale.
b) E
(
t
0
H
s
dW
s
)
2
= E
t
0
H
2
s
ds
(Itˆo Isometry).
c) E
sup
0tT
|
t
0
H
s
dW
s
|
2
4E
T
0
H
2
s
ds
.
Lemma 14 Let H be the space of processes adapted to (F
t
) that satisfy
E[
T
0
H
2
s
ds] < . Suppose H
s
H. Then there is a sequence {H
n
s
} of simple
proce sses such that
lim
n→∞
E
T
0
|H
s
H
n
s
|
2
ds
= 0.
i.e., we can now define the stochastic integral to a broader space taking
this special L
2
limit of simple processes. Simple processes are dense in H if we
consider this convergence.
There is a broader class of processes that the integral can be defined keeping
the properties in the Theorem above. Please refer to Elliott (21) for this
generalization.
2.5
Itˆo Processes, Differentiation Rule and Solution of a SDE
In this section we are going to present the Itˆo Processes, th e so called
Itˆo Lemma and see through some examples the usual uses of it in solving
Stochastic Differential Equations.
2.5.1
Initial Definitions
Definition 15 (Itˆo Processes) Suppose (Ω, F, P) is a probability space with a
filtration (F
t
)
t0
and (W
t
) is a standard (F
t
)-Brownian Motion. A real valued
Itˆo process (X
t
)
t0
is a process of the form:
X
t
= X
0
+
t
0
K
s
ds +
t
0
H
s
dW
s
,
where:
(a) X
0
is F
0
-measurable,
(b) K and H are adapted to F
t
(c)
T
0
|K
s
|ds < a.s. and
T
0
|H
s
|
2
ds < a.s.
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 18
Definition 16 (Quadratic Variation) Given a partition 0 = t
0
< t
1
< ... <
t
n
= t of the interval [0, t] and writing |π| = max
i
(t
i+1
t
i
), the quadrati c
variation of a continuous martingale (M
t
)
t0
, denoted by M
t
, is defined by:
M
t
= lim
|π|→0
n
i=0
(M
t
i+1
M
t
i
)
2
For the Brownian Motion, W
t
= t
2.5.2
Itˆo Formula and SDEs
Let’s start with the main result in Stochastic Calculus:
Theorem 17 (Itˆo Formula) Suppose {X
t
}
t0
is an Itˆo process of the form
X
t
= X
0
+
t
0
K
s
ds +
t
0
H
s
dW
s
Suppose f twice differentiable. Then,
f(X
t
) = f(X
0
) +
t
0
f
(X
s
)dX
s
+
1
2
t
0
f
′′
(X
s
)dX
s
Here, by definition, X
t
=
t
0
H
2
s
ds ; that is the (predictable) quadratic vari-
ation of X is the quadratic variation of the martingale component
t
0
H
s
dW
s
Also,
t
0
f
(X
s
)dX
s
=
t
0
f
(X
s
)K
s
ds +
t
0
f
(X
s
)H
s
dW
s
Definition 18 (Solution of a SDE)
A process X
t
, 0 t T is a solution of the stochastic differential
equation
dX
t
= f(X
t
, t)dt + σ(X
t
, t)dW
t
with initial condition X
0
= ξ if for all t the integrals
t
0
f(X
s
, s)ds and
t
0
σ(X
s
, s)dW
s
are well defined and
X
t
= ξ +
t
0
f(X
s
, s)ds +
t
0
σ(X
s
, s)dW
s
a.s.
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 19
Note that the symbols dt”, dW have no meaning alone they just
make sense when they are in a equation. Even then the meaning is that of a
notation for the integral equation of its solution. Now that we have introduced
the differential notation, for pencil and paper compuations, we prefer to write
the result in Itˆo Lemma as:
df(X
t
) = f
(X
t
)dX
t
+
1
2
f
′′
(X
t
)dX
t
,
together with the fact that X
t
=
t
0
H
2
s
ds we have ultimately:
df(X
t
) = f
(X
t
)dX
t
+
1
2
f
′′
(X
t
)H
2
s
ds (2-7)
= f
(X
t
)K
t
dt + f
(X
t
)H
t
dW
t
+
1
2
f
′′
(X
t
)H
2
t
dt (2-8)
=
f
(X
t
)K
t
+
1
2
f
′′
(X
t
)H
2
t
dt + f
(X
t
)H
t
dW
t
(2-9)
It is worth writing the more general result although later we are going to show
a sufficient general particular case.
Theorem 19 (Multidimensional Itˆo Lemma)
Suppose X
t
= (X
1
t
, ..., X
N
t
) is a n-dimensional Itˆo process with
dX
i
t
= K
i
t
dt +
m
j=1
H
ij
t
dW
j
t
, (2-10)
and suppose f : [0, T ] × R
n
R is C
1,2
. Then
df(t, X
1
t
, ..., X
n
t
) =
f
t
(t, X
1
0
, ..., X
n
0
)dt +
n
i=1
f
x
i
(t, X
1
0
, ..., X
n
0
)dX
i
t
+
1
2
n
i,j=1
f
2
x
i
x
j
(t, X
1
0
, ..., X
n
0
)
m
r=1
H
i,r
t
H
j,r
t
dt
Note that if m = 1 we have:
df(t, X
1
t
, ..., X
n
t
) =
f
t
(t, X
1
0
, ..., X
n
0
)dt +
n
i=1
f
x
i
(t, X
1
0
, ..., X
n
0
)dX
i
t
+
1
2
n
i,j
f
2
x
i
x
j
(t, X
1
0
, ..., X
n
0
)H
i
t
H
j
t
dt
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 20
2.5.3
Existence and Uniqueness
The result we are going to present assure us about the existence and
uniquiness of a solution in some Stochastic Differential Equations.
Theorem 20 (Existence and Uniq ueness of solutions) Suppose the usual as-
sumptions and that ξ,f and σ satisfy:
|f(x, t) f(x
, t)| + |σ(x, t) σ(x
, t)| K|x x
|, (2-11)
|f(x, t)|
2
+ |σ(x, t)|
2
K
2
0
(1 + |x|
2
), (2-12)
E[|ξ|
2
] < (2-13)
for all 0 t T, x, ˆx R
n
and some constant K. Then there is a unique
solution X (up to indistinguishability) given by
X
t
= ξ +
t
0
f(X
s
, s)ds +
t
0
σ(X
s
, s)dW
s
a.s.
such that
E
sup
0tT
|X
t
|
2
< C
1 + E[|ξ|
2
]
.
Proof :
Please refer to (21) and (26).
2.6
Examples of Itˆo Formula
Example 21 Lets Calculate the integral of W
t
w.r.t. W
t
, i.e.,
t
s
W
u
dW
u
For that, we consider dX
t
= dW
t
so that K
u
= 0 and H
u
= 1 and the
fuction y = x
m
.
By the Itˆo formula,
X
u
= W
u
=
u
0
1dv = u
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 21
and
d(W
m
t
) = mW
m1
u
dW
u
+
1
2
m(m 1)W
m2
du.
or equivalently
W
m
t
W
m
s
= m
t
s
W
m1
u
dW
u
+
1
2
t
s
m(m 1)W
m2
du.
Substituting m = 2, we have
W
2
t
W
2
s
= 2
t
s
W
u
dW
u
+
1
2
t
s
2du
so that
W
2
t
W
2
s
= 2
t
s
W
u
dW
u
+
t
s
du
Then
W
2
t
W
2
s
2
(t s)
2
=
t
s
W
u
dW
u
.
instead of the expected
t
s
W
u
dW
u
=
W
2
t
W
2
s
2
that we used to have in calculus.
Lemma 22 (Two-dimensional formula)
For,
dX
s
= K
x
s
dt + H
x
s
dW
s
dY
s
= K
y
s
dt + H
y
s
dW
s
We have
f(t, X
t
, Y
t
) = f(0, X
0
, Y
0
) +
t
0
f
s
(s, x, y)ds +
t
0
f
x
(s, x, y)dX +
+
t
0
f
y
(s, x, y)dY +
t
0
f
2
x∂y
(s, x, y)H
x
s
H
y
s
ds
+
1
2
t
0
f
2
x
2
(s, x, y)H
x
s
2
ds +
1
2
t
0
f
2
y
2
(s, x, y)H
y
s
2
ds
Example 23 (Itˆo Product Rule) Suppose
dX
s
= K
x
s
dt + H
x
s
dW
s
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 22
dY
s
= K
y
s
dt + H
y
s
dW
s
The Itˆo Formula applied to f(x, y) = x.y we have:
f(t, X, Y ) = f(0, X
0
, Y
0
) +
t
0
Y dX +
t
0
XdY
+
t
0
1H
x
s
H
y
s
ds
or
d(X
t
.Y
t
) = Y
t
dX
t
+ X
t
dY
t
+ H
x
t
H
y
t
dt
Example 24 (Solution of a Lognormal SDE)
Suppose
dS
t
S
t
= µdt + σdW
t
, S
0
= X
0
.
or equivalently
S
t
= X
0
+
t
0
S
s
µds +
t
0
S
s
σdW
s
.
This is a Itˆo Process if we think K
s
= S
s
µ and H
s
= S
s
σ satisfying the
usual conditions.
Then X
t
=
t
0
σ
2
S
2
s
ds.
If S
t
> 0, by the Itˆo Formula with f(x) = log(x) we have
logS
t
= logX
0
+
t
0
1
S
s
dS
s
+
1
2
t
0
1
S
2
s
σ
2
S
2
s
ds (2-14)
= logX
0
+
t
0
µ
σ
2
2
ds +
t
0
σdW
s
(2-15)
= logX
0
+
µ
σ
2
2
t + σW
t
(2-16)
so that
S
t
= X
0
.e
µ
σ
2
2
t+σW
t
.
Example 25 (Testing a Solution of a Lognormal SDE) Consider
F (t, x) = X
0
e
µ
σ
2
2
t+σx
.
Show that S
t
= F (t, W
t
) satisfies the lognormal SDE of the example using Itˆo
Formula.
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 23
By Itˆo Formula,
F (t, W
t
) = F (0, W
0
) +
t
0
F
s
(s, W
s
)ds
+
t
0
F
W
s
(s, W
s
)dW
s
+
t
0
2
F
W
2
s
(s, W
s
)d W
s
Equivalently
X
0
e
µ
σ
2
2
t+σW
t
= X
0
+
t
0
µ
σ
2
2
X
0
e
µ
σ
2
2
s+σW
s
ds
+
t
0
σX
0
e
µ
σ
2
2
s+σW
s
dW
s
+
1
2
t
0
σ
2
e
µ
σ
2
2
s+σW
s
X
0
ds
Then
X
0
e
µ
σ
2
2
t+σW
t
= X
0
+
t
0
µX
0
e
µ
σ
2
2
s+σW
s
ds
+
t
0
σX
0
e
µ
σ
2
2
s+σW
s
dW
s
.
Now, by the definition of S
t
S
t
= X
0
+
t
0
µS
s
ds +
t
0
σS
s
dW
s
.
Example 26 (Quotient Rule) Suppose B a Brownian Motion and
dX
t
= X
t
(µ
X
dt + σ
X
dB
t
)
dY
t
= Y
t
(µ
Y
dt + σ
Y
dB
t
)
Define Z by Z
t
= Y
t
/X
t
. Show that Z is lognormal with dyn amics
dZ
t
= Z
t
(µ
Z
dt + σ
Z
dB
t
)
and determine µ
Z
and σ
Z
in terms of the coefficients of X and Y .
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 24
The Itˆo Formula applied to f(x, y) = y/x gives us:
d
Y
t
X
t
=
Y
t
X
2
t
dX
t
+
1
X
t
dY
t
+
1
2
2Y
t
X
3
t
X
2
t
σ
2
X
dt
1
X
2
t
X
t
Y
t
σ
X
σ
Y
=
=
Y
t
X
2
t
X
t
µ
X
dt +
Y
t
X
2
t
X
t
σ
X
dB
t
+
1
X
t
Y
t
µ
Y
dt +
1
X
t
Y
t
σ
Y
dB
t
+
Y
t
X
t
σ
2
X
dt
Y
t
X
t
σ
X
σ
Y
dt
=
Y
t
X
t
(µ
Y
µ
X
+ σ
2
X
σ
X
σ
Y
)dt +
Y
t
X
t
(σ
Y
σ
X
)dB
t
so that
d
Y
t
X
t
=
Y
t
X
t
(µ
Y
µ
X
+ σ
2
X
σ
X
σ
Y
)dt +
Y
t
X
t
(σ
Y
σ
X
)dB
t
means by the definition of Z
t
that
dZ
t
= Z
t
(µ
Z
dt + σ
Z
dB
t
)
with
µ
Z
= (µ
Y
µ
X
+ σ
2
X
σ
X
σ
Y
)
σ
Z
= (σ
Y
σ
X
)
2.7
Change of Measure
Let Q be a second probability measure on (Ω, F) t hat is absolutely
continuous with respect to P (Q << P) such that
M
t
=
dQ
dP
F
t
, and Q(A) =
A
M
t
dP, for A F
t
Lemma : (X
t
M
t
) is a martingale under P iff X
t
is a martingale under
Q.
Proof : Suppose s t and A F
s
. Then
A
X
t
dQ =
A
X
t
M
t
dP =
A
X
s
M
s
dP =
A
X
s
dQ.
Theorem 27 (Characterization of a Brownian Motion) Suppose (W
t
)
t0
is
a continuous (scalar) martingale on the filtered space (Ω, F, P, F), such that
(W
2
t
t)
t0
is a martingale. Then (W
t
) is a Brownian Motion.
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 25
So this Theorem implies that a real process (B
t
)
t0
is a standard Brown-
ian Motion if:
a) t B
t
(ω) is continuous a.s.,
b) B
t
is a martingale
c) B
2
t
t is a martingale.
Definition 28 (History of the Brownian Motion Process) Write F
0
t
= σ(B
s
:
s t) for the σ-algebra on generated by the history of the Brownian Motion
up to time t. Then, (F
t
)
t0
will denote the right-continuous complete filtration
generated by the F
0
t
.
The idea of the Girsanov’s Theorem is to show how (B
t
) behaves under
a change of measure.
Theorem 29 (Girsanov’s Theorem) Suppose (θ
t
)
0tT
is an adapted, mea-
surable process such that
T
0
θ
2
s
ds < a.s. and also so that the process
Λ
t
= e
{
t
0
θ
s
dB
s
1
2
t
0
θ
2
s
ds
}
(2-17)
is an (F
t
, P) martingale. Define a new measure Q
θ
on F
T
by
dQ
θ
dP
F
T
= Λ
T
(2-18)
Then the process
W
t
= B
t
+
t
0
θ
s
ds
is a standard Brownian motion on (F
t
, Q
θ
).
Proof : By Itˆo differentiation rule and by the definition of Λ. For details please
refer to (21).
3
GARCH Models
We will here, define the basic econometric models that will be the basis for
our work. In chapters 5 and 6 we are going to adapt the methodoly developed
in Siu et al. (43) to the FC-GARCH model of
´
Alvaro and Medeiros (36) and
for the Mixture of GARCHs.
To start, we should first go to the basics and define the ARCH and
GARCH models.
3.1
ARCH Models
When we want to express the volatility in terms of past returns, we should
use an Autoregresive Conditional Heterokesdastic model (henceforth ARCH)
model, which is defined by a model with:
y
t
= µ
t
+ h
1/2
t
ǫ
t
(3-1)
where
h
t
= α
0
+
p
i=1
α
i
y
2
ti
(3-2)
that can be rewritten as
h
t
= α
0
+
p
i=1
α
i
ǫ
2
ti
(3-3)
where ǫ
t
is a noise usually a N(0, 1) random variable and µ
t
is the conditional
mean that we will be always considering conditionally deterministic, or more
precisely, F
t1
measurable, sometimes even being considered to be zero for
stationarity purposes.
When we want to model the conditional volatility taking in account not
only the past errors but also the past volatilities we should use a General
Autoregresive Conditional Heterokesdastic model (henceforth GARCH) which
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 27
is modeled as below:
y
t
= µ
t
+ h
1/2
t
ǫ
t
(3-4)
with
h
t
= α
0
+
p
i=1
α
i
y
2
ti
+
q
j=1
β
j
h
tj
(3-5)
Considering the same observations for µ
t
and ǫ
t
as above. For simplicity let´s
suppose it zero.
Another way of writing the same thing (but note the different alpha) is:
h
t
= α
0
+
p
i=1
α
i
ǫ
2
ti
+
q
j=1
β
j
h
tj
(3-6)
In the next subsection we are going to show a more general GARCH-like
model, viz., the FC-GARCH by Medeiros and
´
Alvaro, that poorly speaking,
gives a GARCH to each regime of the economy.
3.2
Flexible Coefficient Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedas-
tic (FC-GARCH)
First, we consider a discrete-time financial model consisting of one risk-
free bond B and one risky stock S. We consider a complete probability space
(Ω, F, P) with P being the r eal-world probability measure. Let T denote the
time index set {0, 1, 2, . . . , T } of the financial model. Let r denote a constant
continuously compounded risk-free rate of interest or force of interest. Under
P, the dynamics of the bond-price process {B
t
}
t∈T
satisfy, for each t T \{0}:
B
t
= B
t1
e
r
, B
0
= 1 . (3-7)
Let ǫ = {ǫ
t
}
t∈T
denote the innovations of the returns from the risky stock S,
where ǫ
0
= 0. We assume that {ǫ
t
}
t∈T
are i.i.d. with distribution D(0, 1), where
D(0, 1) represents a general distribution with mean zero and unit variance.
Let S := {S
t
}
t∈T
denote the price process of the risky asset S. Let
Y
t
:= ln(S
t
/S
t1
), which represents the continuously compounded rate of
return from the risky asset S over the time horizon [0, t]. We suppose t hat the
return process Y := {Y
t
}
t∈T
follows a first-order flexible coefficient Generalized
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 28
Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedastic model with m = H + 1 limiting
regimes, henceforth, FC-GARCH(m, 1, 1) as below:
Y
t
= µ
t
+ h
1/2
t
ǫ
t
h
t
= G(w
t
; ψ) . (3-8)
Here G(w
t
; ψ) is a nonlinear function of a vector of variables w
t
=
[Y
t1
, h
t1
, s
t
]
T
(i.e. T
′′
represents the transpose of a vector or a matrix) de-
fined by:
G(w
t
; ψ) := α
0
+ β
0
h
t1
+ λ
0
Y
2
t1
+
H
i=1
[α
i
+ β
i
h
t1
+ λ
i
Y
2
t1
]f(s
t
; γ
i
, c
i
), t = 1, ..., T.
where
1. for each i = 1, 2, . . . , H, the logistic function
f(s
t
, γ
i
, c
i
) :=
1
1 + e
γ
i
(s
t
c
i
)
;
2. The vector of parameters
ψ := [α
0
, β
0
, λ
0
, α
1
, ..., α
H
, β
1
, ..., β
H
, λ
1
, ..., λ
H
, γ
1
, ..., γ
H
, c
1
, ..., c
H
]
T
R
3+5H
;
3. The parameter γ
i
, i = 1, ..., H is called the slop e parameter. Wh en
γ
i
, the function becomes a step function. Here, we consider the
case when s
t
= Y
t1
.
The rationale of introducing the FC-GARCH model is to provide a useful
and practical way to incorporate the asymmetric effect of the sign and the
size of the previous return Y
t1
on the current variance level h
t
. It can also
capture the heavy-tailedness of return’s distribution and the slow decaying of
the autocorrelation of the squared returns process {Y
2
t
}
t∈T
. The FC-GARCH
model can also incorporate another important stylized empirical feature of
returns data, namely, the Taylor effect, first documented by Taylor (1986)(44).
The Taylor effect refers to th e strong autocorrelation of absolute daily returns
data. This also relates to the long-memory eff ect of volatility; that is, the decay
of the autocorrelations of volatility is too slow to be described by any short
memory autoregressive moving average time series models. We are going to get
back to this model in Chapter 5.
4
Option Pricing
This Chapter explains basically how should we price an option.
In a first Finance Mathematics course we are thaught the concept of
present value, which consists in discounting by a constant risk free interest
rate some value in the future so that we can find the price of it in the present.
It is correct if we think of loans and bank accounts with fixed interest
rates because we know the evolution of these values, so we can track it and
use it in a reverse way to find the present value, but not in general. For risky
assets we don’t know the evolution of the price so we cannot discount by a
proper rate.
On the other hand Probability Theory have some answers to solve that
problem. Under some assumptions, if we change properly the measure in which
we take expectations we can think of any discounted portfolio as a risk neutral
one in t hat measure. That’s why such measures are more usually called Risk
Neutral Measures than Equivalent Martingale Measures. The latter name is
because under that new equivalent measure, the discounted portfolio becomes
a martingale.
4.1
Pricing Formula in the Risk-Neutral Measure
For this section, we follow the chapter 5 in Shreve (41) for the background
and to show the Black-Scholes example.
Let D
t
= e
t
0
r(u)du
be a discount factor process and X
t
be a self-financing
portfolio made of fixed interest investment and risky assets where the amount
invested into risky assets in time t is
t
. It means that changes in the value
of the portfolio are due to changes in the price of the risk asset and changes
in the safe investment and not for putting more money into this portfolio.
Mathematically we ask that
dX
t
=
t
dS
t
+ r
t
(X
t
t
S
t
)dt
Note that according to th e Itˆo product rule, asking for being self-financing
is very restrictive because we lose some terms in the equation above. Suppose
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 30
also that the asset follows
dS
t
= α
t
S
t
dt + σ
t
S
t
dW
t
(4-1)
or as in example 25 of the use of Itˆo’s Lemma:
S
t
= S
0
e
t
0
σd
W
s
+
t
0
(
r
1
2
σ
2
)
ds
(4-2)
By the Itˆo Lemma, we get first that
dD
t
= e
t
0
r(u)du
r(t)dt = D
t
r
t
dt
Then
dX
t
=
t
dS
t
+ r
t
(X
t
t
S
t
)dt (4-3)
=
t
α
t
S
t
dt +
t
σ
t
S
t
dW
t
+ r
t
(X
t
t
S
t
)dt (4-4)
= (∆
t
α
t
S
t
dt + r
t
X
t
r
t
t
S
t
)dt +
t
σ
t
S
t
dW
t
(4-5)
= (r
t
X
t
+ (α
t
r
t
)∆
t
S
t
)dt +
t
σ
t
S
t
dW
t
(4-6)
= r
t
X
t
dt + σ
t
t
S
t
(θ
t
dt + dW
t
) (4-7)
= r
t
X
t
dt + σ
t
t
S
t
d
W
t
. (4-8)
where
W
t
is a Brownian Motion by Girsanov’s Theorem and θ
t
=
(α
t
r
t
)
σ
t
.
Proposition 30 D
t
X
t
is a martingale under Q
Proof : We will proceed as Shreve (41). By the product rule (example 23 of
the use of Itˆo’s Lemma) we have
d(D
t
X
t
) = X
t
dD
t
+ D
t
dX
t
+ dD
t
dX
t
(4-9)
= X
t
(D
t
r
t
)dt + D
t
dX
t
+ 0 (4-10)
= X
t
D
t
r
t
dt + D
t
(r
t
X
t
dt + σ
t
t
S
t
d
W
t
) (4-11)
= D
t
σ
t
t
S
t
d
W
t
. (4-12)
The G irsanov’s Theorem garantee us that
W
t
is a Brownian Motion and
so, as a stochastic integral with respect to a Brownian Motion is a martingale,
D
t
X
t
is a martingale.
Let t he value of some derivative V
T
be F
T
-measurable. We want to know
what is the initial money X
0
and which process
t
are required to be in a
portfolio so that an investor can hedge a position in this derivative, i.e., such
that
X
T
= V
T
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 31
If we can do that, given that D
t
X
t
is a martingale under Q we have
D
t
X
t
= E
Q
[D
T
X
T
|F
t
] = E
Q
[D
T
V
T
|F
t
]
Then, D
t
X
t
is the amount required in t to make the hedge of this
derivative with payoff V
T
. We can then say that the price of the derivative
in t is V
t
where
D
t
V
t
= E
Q
[D
T
V
T
|F
t
] 0 t T (4-13)
or
V
t
= E
Q
[e
T
t
r(u)du
V
T
|F
t
] 0 t T (4-14)
4.2
Black-Scholes-Merton Formula
The most famous finance formula is the Black-Scholes formula. It is easy
to find in many books the proof that consists in deriving the Black-Scholes
PDE and then turning it in a heat equation problem. Here we present it under
the risk-neutral framework as in Shreve (41).
The Black-Scholes-Merton Model supposes that the interest rate and the
volatility are fixed. For an European Call option, we have the payoff
V
T
= (S
T
K)
+
(4-15)
Using the pricing formula just discussed we need to calculate
V
t
= E
Q
[e
r(T t)
(S
T
K)
+
|F
t
] (4-16)
Let’s think of the formula above as a function of t and S
t
:
C(t, S
t
) = E
Q
[e
r(T t)
(S
T
K)
+
|F
t
] (4-17)
The equation
S
t
= S
0
e
t
0
σd
W
s
+
t
0
(
r
1
2
σ
2
)
ds
(4-18)
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 32
can be written as
S
T
= S
t
e
T
t
σd
W
s
+
T
t
(
r
1
2
σ
2
)
ds
(4-19)
= S
t
e
σ(
W
T
W
t
)+
(
r
1
2
σ
2
)
τ
(4-20)
where τ = T t. If we further define Y =
W
T
W
t
T t
we can write
S
T
= S
t
e
σ
τY +
(
r
1
2
σ
2
)
τ
(4-21)
Then, as S
t
is F
t
-measurable and e
σ
τY +
(
r
1
2
σ
2
)
τ
is independent of F
t
:
C(t, x) = E
Q
[e
(S
T
K)
+
] (4-22)
=
1
2π
−∞
e
(xe
σ
τY +
(
r
1
2
σ
2
)
τ
K)
+
e
1
2
y
2
dy (4-23)
Now, note that (xe
σ
τY +
(
r
1
2
σ
2
)
τ
K)
+
is positive if and only if
y < d
1
σ
τ
ln
x
K
+
r
1
2
σ
2
τ
(4-24)
Indeed,
e
σ
τy+
(
r
1
2
σ
2
)
τ
> K/x e
σ
τy
> (K/x)e
(
r
1
2
σ
2
)
τ
σ
τy > ln(K/x)
r
1
2
σ
2
τ
(1)
y <
1
σ
τ
ln
x
K
+
r
1
2
σ
2
τ
We don’t have to consider the integral when it is zero. This leads us to:
C(t, x) =
1
2π
d
−∞
e
(xe
σ
τy+
(
r
1
2
σ
2
)
τ
K)e
1
2
y
2
dy
=
1
2π
d
−∞
xe
1
2
y
2
σ
τy+
(
1
2
σ
2
)
τ
dy
d
−∞
e
Ke
1
2
y
2
dy
=
1
2π
d
−∞
xe
(y+σ
τ )
2
2
dy Φ(d
)e
K
z=y+σ
τ
= x
1
2π
d
+σ
τ
−∞
e
(z)
2
2
dz Φ(d
)e
K
= xΦ(d
+
) Φ(d
)e
K
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 33
where
d
+
= d
+ σ
τ
=
1
σ
τ
ln
x
K
+
r
1
2
σ
2
τ
+ σ
τ
=
ln
x
K
+
r
1
2
σ
2
τ + σ
2
τ
σ
τ
=
ln
x
K
+
r +
1
2
σ
2
τ
σ
τ
4.3
Put-Call Parity
Now, we will see that who can solve the problem of pricing the European
Call option, can also find the price of an Europena Put Option.
Build a portfolio made of:
Buy a stock.
Buy a put option with this stock bought as the underlying.
Sell a call option also based in the stock bought.
Then, if we call this portfolio Π, we can write:
Π
t
= S
t
+ P
t
C
t
.
But then at time T we will have:
payoff
T
(Π) = S
T
+ (K S
T
)
+
(S
T
K)
+
=
S
T
+ K S
T
, if S
T
K
S
T
(S
T
K) , if S
T
> K
= K.
This portfolio always gives a return K, the exercise price. Then, because
it is a deterministic portfolio, we can think of its present value being that of
K discounted:
Π
t
= Ke
r(T t)
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 34
Then we have:
Ke
r(T t)
= S
t
+ P
t
C
t
P
t
= Ke
r(T t)
+ C
t
S
t
.
4.4
Incomplete Markets
Here we are going to show two well known techniques for pricing in
incomplete markets, viz. the Davis method and the Esscher method.
When we can not find a hedge for some asset in the economy we say
that the market is incomplete and t hen it is known that there are infinite
equivalent martingale measures. The risk neutral way of pricing do not involve
requirements concerning the risk preferences of the investors, but in order to
justify the choice of one particular risk neutral measure among many, we will
have to think about a reasonable way to select it.
Besides the two methodologies that we are going to discuss briefly here,
there are other approaches to hedging and pricing in incomplete markets, such
as the quadratic hedging approach. They are mainly interested in minimizing
risk, Maximizing expected utility or minimize loss. For a comprehensible
reading see Bingham and Kiesel (2004)(5).
4.4.1
Davis Method
We start by the method of Davis. Let Φ
a
be the set of all self-financing
strategies (i.e. in which you can not inject money in the portfolio. For details
see (21)and (26)) and write
˜
U(x) = sup
ϕΦ
a
E[U(V
ϕ,x
(T ))]
for the maximum expected utility of an investor and suppose p is the price of
the asset X.
Let
W (δ, x, p) = sup
ϕΦ
a
E[U(V
ϕ,xδ
(T ) +
δ
p
X)]
be a disturb created for being able to sense the effect of changing the strategy.
If the maximum utility does not get affected by this “tilt”, ˆp is the fair price
for the option.
Under some conditions, ˆp is the unique solution of
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 35
W
δ
W (0, p, x) = 0
which is the fair price of the option in t = 0. Furthermore, this value is
given by:
ˆp =
E[U
(V
ϕ
,x
(T ))X]
˜
U
(x)
For more details see Davis(1994)(13) and Bingham and Kiesel(2004) (5).
4.4.2
Esscher Method
Now let’s see the Esscher method. Let S
t
= S
0
e
X
t
be the model for the
asset prices where X
t
has independent and stationary increments. Assume that
M(h, t) = M(h, 1)
t
= E[e
hX
t
] (4-25)
Then, having that in mind, let’s define
Λ
t
=
e
hX
t
E[e
hX
t
]
= e
hX
t
M(h, 1)
t
=
S
h
t
E[S
h
t
]
; t 0 (4-26)
that is a positive martingale and will be used for the change of measure.
Now, by the Baye’s rule,
E
h
[Ψ(Y )] = E[Ψ(Y ); h] =
E[Ψ(Y )e
hY
]
E[e
hY
]
(4-27)
= E
t
Ψ(Y )] (4-28)
where Y is a random variable and Ψ is a measurable function. For
example Ψ(Y ) could be the logreturn e
X
t
.
We will call Q the Esscher measure of parameter h = h
if {e
rt
S
t
}
t0
is
a martingale.
By the condition on the asset prices we have the following equivalences:
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 36
E[e
rt
S
t
, h
] = S
0
E
S
t
S
0
, h
= e
rt
(4-29)
E[e
X
t
, h
] = e
rt
(4-30)
E
e
X
t
e
h
X
t
M(h
, 1)
t
= e
rt
(4-31)
E[e
X
t
(h
+1)
]
M(h
, 1)
t
= e
rt
(4-32)
M(h
+ 1, 1)
t
M(h
, 1)
t
= e
rt
(4-33)
M(h
+ 1, 1)
M(h
, 1)
t
= e
rt
(4-34)
M(h
+ 1, 1)
M(h
, 1)
= e
r
(4-35)
(4-36)
The equation
M(h
+ 1, 1)
M(h
, 1)
= e
r
(4-37)
determines the parameter h
uniquely. We will be interested in this
parameter for finding the risk neutral measure to be used in the option pricing.
There is a useful result that we should show here. It is known as the
factorization formula:
Theorem 31 Let g be a measurable function and h, k and t be real values
with t 0, then
E[S
k
t
g(S
t
); h] = E[S
k
t
; h]E[g(S
t
); k + h]. (4-38)
Proof :
E[S
k
t
g(S
t
); h] = E[S
k
t
g(S
t
)e
hX
t
M(h, 1)
t
] (4-39)
= E
S
k
t
g(S
t
)
S
h
t
E[S
h
t
]
(4-40)
=
E[S
k+h
t
]E[S
k+h
t
g(S
t
)]
E[S
h
t
]E[S
k+h
t
]
(4-41)
= E[S
k
t
; h]E[g(S
t
); k + h] (4-42)
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 37
For more details see Gerber and Shiu (1994)(31) and Bingham and
Kiesel(2004)(5). Some of the points discussed above will be revisited in the
conditional Esscher Tr ansform section.
4.5
Duan’s breakthrough
In 1995, Duan developped a method for pricing options under GARCH
processes. Although there are economic restrictions and is valid only for
normal noises, it was a milestone in Finance. He also developped some papers
concerning the relationship between the diffusions and the econometric models
and their risk neutral versions. This discussion doesn’t help us in this thesis
and it can b e found in Duan(1997)(18). Here we show the main results from
the paper published in 1995 (17).
Consider the model:
ln
X
t
X
t1
= r + λ
h
t
1
2
h
t
+ ξ
t
where
ξ
t
|φ
t1
N(0, h
t
) under mesure P
h
t
= α
0
+
q
i=1
α
i
ξ
2
ti
+
p
j=1
β
j
h
tj
Basically the paper raises the question: What would the risk-neutral
GARCH be?
For answering this question, he defines the concept of Local Risk Neutral
Valuation Relationship hereafter LRNVR, as below:
A measure Q satisfies the LRNVR if:
1 Q is mutually absolutely continuous with respect to measure
P.(Equivalents)
2
X
t
X
t1
is lognormally distributed (und er Q)
3 E
Q
[
X
t
X
t1
|φ
t1
] = e
r
4 V ar
Q
(ln
X
t
X
t1
|φ
t1
) = V ar
P
(ln
X
t
X
t1
|φ
t1
) a.s.
Having in mind this concept we can state the main Theorem of the paper:
Theorem 32 Supposing the LRNVR, under Q we have:
ln
X
t
X
t1
= r
1
2
h
t
+ ǫ
t
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 38
where:
ǫ
t
|φ
t1
N(0, h
t
)
h
t
= α
0
+
q
i=1
α
i
(ǫ
ti
λ
h
ti
)
2
+
p
j=1
β
j
h
tj
Proof : It follows exactly as in Duan (17). Since
X
t
X
t1
|φ
t1
lognormally dis-
tributed under measure Q, it can be written as:
ln
X
t
X
t1
= v
t
+ ǫ
t
,
where v
t
is the conditional mean and ǫ
t
is a Q-normal random variable. The
conditional mean of ǫ
t
is zero and its conditional variance is to be determined.
The proof is in two parts.
First we prove that v
t
= r
h
t
2
. Indeed,
E
Q
X
t
X
t1
|φ
t1
= E
Q
[e
v
t
+ǫ
t
|φ
t1
] = e
v
t
+
h
t
2
where h
t
= V ar
P
[
X
t
X
t1
|φ
t1
] = V ar
Q
[
X
t
X
t1
|φ
t1
] by the LRNVR.
Since E
Q
[
X
t
X
t1
|φ
t1
] = e
r
also by the LRNVR, it follows that v
t
= r
h
t
2
.
Now we prove the second part. It remains to prove that h
t
can indeed
be expressed as stated in th e Theorem. By the preceding result and the model
under P:
ln
X
t
X
t1
= r + λ
h
t
h
t
2
+ ξ
t
, (4-43)
we have, comparing the logs:
r + λ
h
t
h
t
2
+ ξ
t
= r
h
t
2
+ ǫ
t
. (4-44)
so that ξ
t
= ǫ
t
λ
h
t
. Substituting ǫ
t
into the conditional variance
equation yields the desired result:
h
t
= α
0
+
q
i=1
α
i
(ǫ
ti
λ
h
ti
)
2
+
p
j=1
β
j
h
tj
The result just proved can be found as a particular case of the method
described in the next section. This verification can be found in section 3.1
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 39
in the paper by Siu et al. (2004)(43). The method below doesn’t require the
noises to be normal, they just have to have a moment generation function.
5
Option Pricing under a Nonlinear and Nonnormal GARCH
This chapter is based in a pap er written together with both my advisor
and my co-advisor, Professors
´
Alvaro Veiga and Ken Siu respectively. We
investigate the pricing of options in a class of discrete-time Flexible Coefficient
Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedastic (FC-GARCH) models
with non-normal innovations. A conditional Esscher transform was used to
select a price kernel for valuation in the incomplete market. This choice of the
pricing kernel can be justified by an economic equilibrium argument based on
maximizing the expected power utility. We provide a numerical study on the
pricing results when the GARCH innovations have a normal distribution or
a shifted-Gamma distribution and identify some key features of the pricing
results.
The conditional Esscher transform provides a convenient and flexible way
to determine a price kernel under nonlinear time series models. Here we exploit
this important tool in actuarial science to determine a price kernel for option
valuation.
5.1
Flexible Coefficient Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedas-
tic (FC-GARCH) models for Asset Returns
We consider a discrete-time economy with a bond B and a share S. Let T de-
note the time index set {0, 1, 2, . . . , T } of the economy. To model uncertainty,
we fix a complete probability space (Ω, F, P) where P is a real-world prob-
ability measure. To simplify our analysis, we assume that the continuously
compounded rate of interest from the bond is a constant, say r per period.
Consequently, th e bond-price process {B
t
|t T } evolves over time as:
B
t
= B
t1
e
r
, B
0
= 1 . (5-1)
Let ǫ = {ǫ
t
}
t∈T
be the return innovations of the share S, where
we take ǫ
0
= 0 by convention. Suppose {ǫ
t
|t T \{0}} are independent
and identically distributed, (i.i.d.), with common distribution D(0, 1), where
D(0, 1) represents a general distribution with zero mean and unit variance.
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 41
Let S := {S
t
}
t∈T
be the price process of the share S. Let Y
t
:=
ln(S
t
/S
t1
), which is the continuously compounded rate of return from the
share S from time t 1 and time t. Then we assume that the return
process Y := {Y
t
|t T } follows a first-order Flexible Coefficient Generalized
Autoregressive Conditional Heteroscedastic model with m = H + 1 limiting
regimes, henceforth, FC-GARCH (m, 1, 1):
Y
t
= µ
t
+ h
1/2
t
ǫ
t
,
h
t
= G(w
t
; ψ) . (5-2)
Here G(w
t
; ψ) is a nonlinear function of a vector of variables w
t
:=
(Y
t1
, h
t1
, s
t
)
, (i.e. represents the transpose of a matrix, or in particu-
lar a vector), defined by:
G(w
t
; ψ) := α
0
+ β
0
h
t1
+ λ
0
Y
2
t1
+
H
i=1
[α
i
+ β
i
h
t1
+ λ
i
Y
2
t1
]f(s
t
; γ
i
, c
i
) ,
where
1. for each i = 1, 2, . . . , H, the logistic function
f(s
t
, γ
i
, c
i
) :=
1
1 + e
γ
i
(s
t
c
i
)
;
2. the vector of parameters
ψ := (α
0
, β
0
, λ
0
, α
1
, ··· , α
H
, β
1
, ··· , β
H
, λ
1
, ··· , λ
H
, γ
1
, ··· , γ
H
, c
1
, ··· , c
H
)
R
3+5H
;
3. for each i = 1, 2, ··· , N, the parameter γ
i
is the slope parameter and
is considered positive. When γ
i
, the function becomes a step
function. Please refer to Medeiros and Veiga(2009)(36), for a complete
list of assumptions made on the parameters. Note that their restrictions
are for a simpler FC-GARCH in which the conditional mean is constant.
Here, we consider a simple case that s
t
= Y
t1
.
The class of FC-GARCH models provides the flexibility in incorporating
the asymmetric effect of the sign and the size of the previous return Y
t1
on the current variance level h
t
. It can also capture the heavy-tailedness of
return’s distribution and the slow decay of the autocorrelation of the squared
returns process {Y
2
t
|t T }. In addition, the FC-GARCH model can capture
another important stylized empirical feature of returns data, namely, the
Taylor effect, first documented by Taylor (1986)(44). The Taylor effect refers
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 42
to the strong autocorrelation of absolute daily returns data. This also relates to
the long-memory effect of volatility; that is, the decay of th e autocorrelations
of volatility is too slow to be described by any short memory autoregressive
moving average time series models. In the empirical studies by Ding et al.
(1993) (16), it has been documented that the realized volatility decays in a
hyperparabolic rate.
When γ
i
= 0, or α
i
, β
i
, λ
i
= 0, i = 1, 2, ··· , H, the FC-GARCH model
reduces to the GARCH(1,1) model. The FC-GARCH model also nests other
important ARCH-type models in the literature. Some examples include the
LST-GARCH(1,1) model, the GJR-GARCH(1,1) model, the VS-GARCH(1,1)
model, the ANST-GARCH(1,1) model, the DT-ARCH(1,1) model, the DT-
GARCH(1,1) model, and others. For detail, interested readers may refer to
Medeiros and Veiga(2009)(36).
5.2
The Conditional Esscher Transform
In this section, we recall the method of the conditional Esscher transform
described in Siu et al. (2004) (43) to determine a pricing kernel for option
valuation. The method applies to determine a price kernel for a general FC-
GARCH model in the next section.
For each t T , write F
t
for the P-completed, σ-field generated by the
share price process up to and including time t and write also F := {F
t
|t T }.
We assume that under P,
Y
t
= µ
t
+ ξ
t
.
where ξ
t
is an i.i.d innovation pro cess having distribution D(0, h
t
) and µ
t
and
h
t
are F
t1
-measurable.
We noticed while p reparing that paper that the methodology is applied
not only to the FC-GARCH but also for any model that has a µ
t
and h
t
structure being F
t1
measurable and noises given by a infinitely divisible
distribution having a moment generation function. As many of the GARCH
especifications has those properties, the Siu et al. methodology can be used
very broadly.
We now define the conditional Esscher transform. Let {θ
t
|t T \{0}} be
an F -predictable, real-valued, process on (Ω, F, P). It means we know in time
t 1 its value in time t. Denote, for each t T \{0}, the moment generating
function of Y
t
given F
t1
under P evaluated at z by M
Y
(t, z); that is,
M
Y
(t, z) := E[e
zY
t
|F
t1
] .
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 43
Here E is expectation under P. Assume that, for each t T \{0} and z ,
M
Y
(t, z) exists and consider an F-adapted process {Λ
t
|t T } on (Ω, F, P)
with Λ
0
= 1, P-a.s., defined by:
Λ
t
:=
t
k=1
e
θ
k
Y
k
M
Y
(k, θ
k
)
, t T \{0} .
Then, it is easy to check that {Λ
t
}
tτ
is an (F, P)-martingale. So, E
T
] = 1.
Now we define a new probability measure P
θ
equivalent to P on F
T
by
setting
dP
θ
dP
F
T
:= Λ
T
. (5-3)
We call P
θ
the conditional Esscher transform associated with θ.
Let M
θ
Y
(t, z) be the moment generating function of the return Y
t
given
F
t1
under the new measure P
θ
. Write E
θ
[·] for expectation under P
θ
. Then,
by the Bayes’ rule, it is easy to check that
M
θ
Y
(t, z) =
M
Y
(t, θ
t
+ z)
M
Y
(t, θ
t
)
. (5-4)
Indeed, by the Bayes’ rule (Theorem 45 in the Appendix),
M
θ
Y
(t, z) := E
θ
[e
zY
t
|F
t1
]
=
E[e
zY
t
Λ
t
|F
t1
]
E
t
|F
t1
]
= E
Λ
t
Λ
t1
e
zY
t
|F
t1
=
E[e
(z+θ
t
)Y
t
|F
t1
]
M
Y
(t, θ
t
)
=
M
Y
(t, θ
t
+ z)
M
Y
(t, θ
t
)
. (5-5)
According to the fundamental theorem of asset pricing (see Harrsion
and Kreps(1979)(33) and Harrsion and Pliska (1981, 1983))(34) and (35), the
absence of arbitrage opportunities is “essentially” equivalent to the existence
of an equivalent martingale measure under which discounted price processes
are martingales. We call the latter a martingale condition. Please refer to Siu
et al.(43) for the economic argument to select the measure. A similar argument
will be shown in chapter 6.
Now we write
˜
S
t
:= e
rt
S
t
, which is the discounted asset price at time t,
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 44
for each t T . Then in our case, the martingale condition is:
˜
S
u
= E
θ
[
˜
S
t
|F
u
] , for all u, t T with u t . (5-6)
Here E
θ
is expectation under P
θ
.
The following proposition gives the necessary and sufficient condition for
the martingale condition. It is in Siu et al. (2004)(43).
Proposition 33 The martingale condition is satisfied if and only if there
exists an F -predictable process {θ
t
|t T \{0}} such that
r = ln M
Y
(t, θ
t
+ 1) ln M
Y
(t, θ
t
) . (5-7)
Proof :
Let Y
t
= ln
S
t
S
t1
, such that e
Y
t
=
S
t
S
t1
.
() First we prove that
˜
S
t1
= E
θ
[
˜
S
t
|F
t1
]
Indeed, if r = ln
M
Y
(t,θ
t
+1)
M
Y
(t,θ
t
)
, then
e
r
=
M
Y
(t, θ
t
+ 1)
M
Y
(t, θ
t
)
= M
Y
(t, 1) = E
θ
[e
Y
t
|F
t1
]. (5-8)
Then,
E
θ
[e
rt
S
t
|F
t1
] = S
t1
e
rt
E
θ
[e
Y
t
|F
t1
] (5-9)
= S
t1
e
rt
E
θ
[e
Y
t
|F
t1
] (5-10)
= S
t1
e
rt
E[e
Y
t
(θ
t
+1)
|F
t1
]
E[e
Y
t
θ
t
|F
t1
]
(5-11)
= S
t1
e
rt
M
Y
(t, θ
t
+ 1)
M
Y
(t, θ
t
)
(5-12)
= S
t1
e
r(t1)
(5-13)
Now, we will show that for any u, t τ with u < t,
E
θ
[e
rt
S
t
|F
t1
] = e
ru
S
u
, a.s. with respect to P.
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 45
E
θ
[e
rt
S
t
|F
u
] = E
θ
[e
rt
S
t1
e
Y
t
|F
u
] (5-14)
= E
θ
[e
rt
S
t1
E
θ
[e
Y
t
|F
t1
]|F
u
] (5-15)
= E
θ
[e
r(t1)
S
t1
e
r
E
θ
[e
Y
t
|F
t1
]|F
u
] (5-16)
= E
θ
[e
r(t1)
S
t1
|F
u
] (5-17)
= ... (5-18)
= E
θ
[e
r(u +1)
S
u+1
|F
u
] (5-19)
= e
ru
S
u
(5-20)
almost surely with respect to P as desired.
() Now we are going to prove that if
˜
S
u
= E
θ
[
˜
S
t
|F
u
] u t (5-21)
then
r = ln
M
Y
(t, θ
t
+ 1)
M
Y
(t, θ
t
)
.
In particular, the hypothesis is true at u = t 1. Then
S
t1
e
r(t1)
= E
θ
[S
t
e
rt
|F
t1
]
e
r(t1)
= E
θ
[
S
t
S
t1
|F
t1
]
e
r
= E
θ
[e
Y
t
|F
t1
]
r = ln E
θ
[e
Y
t
|F
t1
]
r = ln
E[e
Y
t
(θ
t
+1)
|F
t1
]
E[e
Y
t
θ
t
|F
t1
]
r = ln
M
Y
(t, θ
t
+ 1)
M
Y
(t, θ
t
)
.
The existence and uniqueness of the pr ocess θ can be established using
some standard arguments.
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 46
Consider an European-style option with payoff V (S
T
) at maturity T .
Then, a conditional price of the option at time t given F
t
is determined as:
V
t
= e
r(T t)
E
θ
[V (S
T
)|F
t
] . (5-22)
The expected value of V (S
T
) is calculated via Monte Carlo simulation.
To obtain the results we also use some variance reduction techniques: control
variate (the Black and Scholes option price as the benchmark) and antithetic
variables (Normal case only).
5.3
Some Parametric Cases
In this section, we consider some parametric cases of our model when the
GARCH innovations have a normal distribution and a shifted gamma distri-
bution. The development in this section follows that of Siu et al. (2004)(43).
In this section two of the main theoretical results of our research will appear,
viz., Theorems 35 and 36.
5.3.1
Normal innovations
Firstly, under P, consider some F
t1
measurable conditional mean µ
t
an the model below.
Y
t
= µ
t
+ ξ
t
ξ
t
|F
t1
= N(0, h
t
)
h
t
= α
0
+ β
0
h
t1
+ λ
0
ξ
2
t1
+
H
i=1
(α
i
+ β
i
h
t1
+ λ
i
ξ
2
t1
)f(s
t
; γ
i
, c
i
),
where
f(s
t
, γ
i
, c
i
) :=
1
1 + e
γ
i
(s
t
c
i
)
.
Then, under P, Y
t
|F
t1
N(µ
t
, h
t
), as µ
t
depends only on information
available in F
t1
.
In order to find the Esscher parameter:
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 47
r = ln(M
Y
t
|F
t1
(1, θ
t
)) = ln
M
Y
t
|F
t1
(1 + θ
t
)
M
Y
t
|F
t1
(θ
t
)
(5-23)
= ln
e
µ
t
(1+θ
t
)+
(1+θ
t
)
2
h
t
2
e
µ
t
θ
t
+
θ
2
t
h
t
2
= ln(e
µ
t
+h
t
θ
t
+
h
t
2
) = µ
t
+ h
t
θ
t
+
h
t
2
(5-24)
i.e.,
r = µ
t
+ h
t
θ
t
+
h
t
2
or
r µ
t
h
t
2
= h
t
θ
t
which gives us θ
t
=
rµ
t
h
t
2
h
t
. (The Esscher parameter)
Using that θ
t
=
r
(
µ
t
+
h
t
2
)
h
t
in the relation
M
Y
t
|F
t1
(z, θ
t
) =
M
Y
t
|F
t1
(z + θ
t
)
M
Y
t
|F
t1
(θ
t
)
,
we have
M
Y
t
|F
t1
(z, θ
t
) =
e
µ
t
(z+θ
t
)+
(z+θ
t
)
2
h
t
2
e
µ
t
θ
t
+
θ
2
t
h
t
2
(5-25)
= e
µ
t
z+
t
h
t
+
z
2
h
t
2
(5-26)
= e
µ
t
z+z
(
r
(
µ
t
+
h
t
2
))
+
z
2
h
t
2
(5-27)
= e
z
(
r
h
t
2
)
+
z
2
h
t
2
, (5-28)
which is the mgf of a normal, i.e.,
Y
t
|F
t1
N
P
θ
r
h
t
2
, h
t
under P
θ
. By the dynamics
Y
t
= µ
t
+ ξ
t
; ξ
t
= h
1/2
t
ǫ
t
,
we have
E
θ
P
[ξ
t
|F
t1
] = E
θ
P
[Y
t
|F
t1
] µ
t
= r µ
t
h
t
2
.
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 48
V ar
θ
P
[ξ
t
|F
t1
] = V ar
θ
P
[Y
t
|F
t1
] = h
t
= V ar
P
[ξ
t
|F
t1
].
Note that the variance does not change but the mean does and we want a
zero mean variable. So make ǫ
t
:= ξ
t
r+µ
t
+
h
t
2
such that ǫ
t
|F
t1
N
θ
P
(0, h
t
).
Then, we can write the model under measure P
θ
as
Y
t
= r
h
t
2
+ ǫ
t
, (5-29)
where
h
t
= α
0
+ β
0
h
t1
+ λ
0
ǫ
t1
+ r µ
t
h
t1
2
2
(5-30)
+
H
i=1
α
i
+ β
i
h
t1
+ λ
i
ǫ
t1
+ r µ
t
h
t1
2
2
f(s
t
; γ
i
, c
i
)(5-31)
If we take µ
t
= r+λ
h
t
1
2
h
t
to be the conditional mean as Duan(1995),
we would have to consider
ǫ
t
: = ξ
t
r + r + λ
h
t
1
2
h
t
+
h
t
2
(5-32)
= ξ
t
+ λ
h
t
(5-33)
so t hat ǫ
t
|F
t1
N
θ
P
(0, h
t
). And then we would conclude for this particular
case that under P
θ
:
Y
t
= r
h
t
2
+ ǫ
t
, (5-34)
where
h
t
= α
0
+ β
0
h
t1
+ λ
0
(ǫ
t1
λ
h
t
)
2
(5-35)
+
H
i=1
α
i
+ β
i
h
t1
+ λ
i
(ǫ
t1
λ
h
t
)
2
f(s
t
; γ
i
, c
i
) (5-36)
We summarize the discussion above in the following Theorem:
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 49
Theorem 34 Let
Y
t
= r + λ
h
t
1
2
h
t
+ ξ
t
ξ
t
|F
t1
= N(0, h
t
)
h
t
= α
0
+ β
0
h
t1
+ λ
0
ξ
2
t1
+
H
i=1
(α
i
+ β
i
h
t1
+ λ
i
ξ
2
t1
)f(s
t
; γ
i
, c
i
) ,
be the model under P, where
f(s
t
, γ
i
, c
i
) :=
1
1 + e
γ
i
(s
t
c
i
)
.
Then, under the risk neutral measure the model is
Y
t
= r
1
2
h
t
+ ǫ
t
ǫ
t
|F
t1
N
θ
P
(0, h
t
)
h
t
= α
0
+ β
0
h
t1
+ λ
0
(ǫ
t1
λ
h
t
)
2
+
H
i=1
α
i
+ β
i
h
t1
+ λ
i
(ǫ
t1
λ
h
t
)
2
f(s
t
; γ
i
, c
i
)
5.3.2
Shifted-Gamma Innovations
Some authors (Gerber and Shiu(1994) (31) and Siu et al. (2004)(43) )
have been using shifted-gamma innovations to model log-returns in order to
handle the skewness that real financial series usually exhibits. However, the
skewness of the Gamma distribution is strictly positive whilst financial time
series can present both signs. In practice, before adopting the shifted-gamma
model, one may check if there is any skewness to be modeled. Otherwise,
the Normal model should suffice. Then, one should check for the sign of the
skewness so as to select an appropriate formulation of the shifted-gamma
innovations. The positive case is similar and for the GARCH case it has already
documented in Siu et al.(2004) (43). In the following, we develop a model to
incorporate negative skewness.
Suppose that for each t T \{0}, X
t
Ga(a, b), where Ga(a, b)
represents a Gamma distribution with shape parameter a and scale parameter
b. We now suppose that under P the innovation at time t is given by:
ξ
t
:=
h
t
X
t
a/b
a/b
2
, (5-37)
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 50
so we write ξ
t
|F
t1
SGa(0, h
t
).
Then, under P,
Y
t
= r + λ
h
t
1
2
h
t
+ ξ
t
, (5-38)
h
t
= α
0
+ β
0
h
t1
+ λ
0
ξ
2
t1
+
H
i=1
(α
i
+ β
i
h
t1
+ λ
i
ξ
2
t1
)f(s
t
; γ
i
, c
i
) ,(5-39)
where
f(s
t
, γ
i
, c
i
) :=
1
1 + e
γ
i
(s
t
c
i
)
.
The return process Y can be expressed as:
Y
t
= r + λ
h
t
1
2
h
t
+
ah
t
b
h
t
a
X
t
.
Note that b
h
t
a
X
t
Ga(a,
a
h
t
), and that if W Ga(a, b) is a Gamma
random variable, the moment generation function of W is M
W
(t) =
b
b+θ
a
.
Then the moment generation function of Y
t
|F is given by
M
Y
t
|F
t1
(θ
t
) =
a
h
t
a
h
t
+ θ
t
a
e
(r+λ
h
t
1
2
h
t
+
ah
t
)θ
t
(5-40)
provided that θ
t
+
a
h
t
> 0.
Applying the formula
M
θ
t
Y
(z, θ
t
) =
M
Y
(t, θ
t
+ z)
M
Y
(t, θ
t
)
, (5-41)
we have
M
Y
t
|F
t1
(z, θ
t
) =
a
h
t
a
h
t
+θ
t
+z
a
e
(r+λ
h
t
1
2
h
t
+
ah
t
)(θ
t
+z)
a
h
t
a
h
t
+θ
t
a
e
(r+λ
h
t
1
2
h
t
+
ah
t
)θ
t
(5-42)
=
a
h
t
+ θ
t
a
h
t
+ θ
t
+ z
a
e
(r+λ
h
t
1
2
h
t
+
ah
t
)z
(5-43)
as long as z <
a
h
t
+ θ
t
.
By this formula and the relation
r = ln M
Y
t
|F
t1
(1, θ
q
t
)
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 51
we have:
e
r
= e
r+λ
h
t
1
2
h
t
+
ah
t
a
h
t
+ θ
q
t
a
h
t
+ θ
q
t
+ 1
a
(5-44)
or equivalently
1 = e
λ
h
t
1
2
h
t
+
ah
t
a
a
h
t
+ θ
q
t
a
h
t
+ θ
q
t
+ 1
(5-45)
Note that
a
h
t
+ θ
q
t
a
h
t
+ θ
q
t
+ 1
= 1
1
a
h
t
+ θ
q
t
+ 1
(5-46)
Then,
1 e
λ
h
t
1
2
h
t
+
ah
t
a
=
e
λ
h
t
1
2
h
t
+
ah
t
a
a
h
t
+ θ
q
t
+ 1
(5-47)
a
h
t
+ θ
q
t
+ 1 =
e
λ
h
t
1
2
h
t
+
ah
t
a
1 e
λ
h
t
1
2
h
t
+
ah
t
a
(5-48)
θ
q
t
=
e
λ
h
t
1
2
h
t
+
ah
t
a
1 e
λ
h
t
1
2
h
t
+
ah
t
a
a
h
t
1 (5-49)
θ
q
t
=
1
1 e
λ
h
t
1
2
h
t
+
ah
t
a
a
h
t
(5-50)
θ
q
t
=
1
e
λ
h
t
1
2
h
t
+
ah
t
a
1
a
h
t
(5-51)
Consequently, th e martingale condition implies that
θ
q
t
=
1
e
λ
h
t
1
2
h
t
+
ah
t
a
1
a
h
t
(5-52)
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 52
Now if we take b
t
:=
a
h
t
and b
θ
t
:=
1
e
λ
h
t
1
2
h
t
+
ah
t
a
1
, then
b
θ
t
= θ
t
+ b
t
.
Let be “equal in distribution”. Under P
θ
,
Y
t
|F
t1
SGa(a, b
θ
t
, r λ
h
t
+
1
2
h
t
ah
t
) . (5-53)
Then, we can write
Y
t
r + λ
h
t
1
2
h
t
+
ah
t
+ X
θ
t
.
Here X
θ
t
1
b
θ
t
Ga(a, 1)
1
, and
h
t
= α
0
+ β
0
h
t1
+ λ
0
(X
θ
t1
+
ah
t1
)
2
+
H
i=1
[α
i
+ β
i
h
t1
+ λ
i
(X
θ
t1
+
ah
t1
)
2
]f(s
t
; γ
i
, c
i
) .
From the discussion above we have achieved:
Theorem 35 Let the mode l under P be
Y
t
= r + λ
h
t
1
2
h
t
+ ξ
t
,
ξ
t
|F
t1
SGa(0, h
t
),
h
t
= α
0
+ β
0
h
t1
+ λ
0
ξ
2
t1
+
H
i=1
(α
i
+ β
i
h
t1
+ λ
i
ξ
2
t1
)f(s
t
; γ
i
, c
i
),
where
f(s
t
, γ
i
, c
i
) :=
1
1 + e
γ
i
(s
t
c
i
)
.
1
We write Gamma(a, 1) a Gamma random variable with shape parameter a and the
scalar parameter 1.
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 53
Then, under the risk neutral measure, the model is
Y
t
r + λ
h
t
1
2
h
t
+
ah
t
+ X
θ
t
X
θ
t
1
b
θ
t
Ga(a, 1)
h
t
= α
0
+ β
0
h
t1
+ λ
0
(X
θ
t1
+
ah
t1
)
2
+
H
i=1
[α
i
+ β
i
h
t1
+ λ
i
(X
θ
t1
+
ah
t1
)
2
]f(s
t
; γ
i
, c
i
) .
5.4
Simulation Studies
In this section we conduct simulation experiments and compare both Call
and Put option prices arising from different processes for the log-returns of the
underlying asset.
We consider five pricing schemes for options with 90 days to maturity:
the classical Black and Scholes formulae assuming a GBM process and the
conditional Esscher transform method for GARCH and FC-GARCH processes,
each one with Normal and shifted-Gamma innovations.
In the Esscher transform approach, as noted in section 3, the expected
value in equation (3.20) is computed by Monte Carlo simulation. In simulation
experiments, we used a sample of size of 10000 for the Gamma models and
20000 for the Normal ones, due to the antithetic variables.
The five pricing schemes are applied to two artificial series produced
by a FC-GARCH model with Normal and Shifted-Gamma innovations with
3200 data points, obtained after a warm-up period of 1000 observations. The
FC-GARCH parameters used in the simulations are given in table 1. These
parameters, except for the a parameter and the risk-premium, are in Medeiros
and Veiga (2009)(36).
FC-GARCH Parameters
α [9.77 × 10
16
, 5.14 × 10
7
, 1.81 × 10
5
]
β [1.21, 0.32, 0.25]
λ [0.06, 0.01, 0.04]
γ [2.52, 2.85]
c [0.72, 1.56]
Risk Premium 0.0349
a (Gamma case) 100
Table 5.1: Parameters for the FC-GARCH including the values of α, β and λ
in the three different regimes.
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 54
To evaluate the Black and Scholes prices we estimate the volatility
parameters by the sample variances, 4.0812 × 10
5
, for the Normal data and
3.8244 × 10
5
for the Gamma data.
For the estimation of the GARCH parameters we use an iterated two-
stage method. Initially, we suppose h
t
a constant equal to the sample variance.
Then, we estimate the risk premium by weighted least squares (WLS). Then
we fit a GARCH(1,1) model to the residuals of the WLS by performing a Quasi
Maximum Likelihhod. We iterate these two steps until convergence is attained.
The estimated parameters are shown in table 2.
GARCH Parameters in Normal Case
α 7.4079 × 10
7
β 0.9375
λ 0.0445
Risk Premium 0.0288
Table 5.2: Estimated GARCH Parameters in the Normal Case
We estimated the parameters using the two stage procedure as described
before and then for finding a we used the method of moments estimate as in
Siu et al. (2004) (43) as follows:
ˆa =
2
T
t=1
h
3/2
t
T
t=1
ξ
3
t
2
, (5-54)
which led us to the estimated parameters shown in table 3.
GARCH Parameters in Shifted-Gamma Case
α 5.4959 × 10
7
β 0.9461
λ 0.0397
Risk Premium 0.0363
a 79.4022
Table 5.3: Estimated GARCH Parameters in the Gamma Case
As discussed in section 4.2, one must check for the presence and the sign
of the skewness before selecting the Normal or Shifted-Gamma approaches.
The resulting prices are presented in the tables that follows. IV stands
for the initial volatility, here the ratio between the initial variance used for
simulation and the sample variance. For the case where IV = 1.0, after each
option price table there is another table with the ratios between the (FC)-
GARCH prices and the Black-Scholes prices for each model. A graph of these
comparative tables is also shown.
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 55
Call Prices with IV=1.0 for Artificial Normal FCGARCH Series
K/S
0
BS FC-Normal GARCH-Normal FC-Gamma GARCH-Gamma
0.80 20.0002 20.0009 19.9978 20.0149 20.0103
0.85 15.0063 15.0110 15.0079 15.0292 15.0238
0.90 10.0957 10.0939 10.1022 10.1216 10.1227
0.95 5.6537 5.5895 5.6292 5.6255 5.6565
1.00 2.4175 2.2812 2.3714 2.2757 2.3762
1.05 0.7397 0.6704 0.7163 0.6449 0.6845
1.10 0.1575 0.1515 0.1667 0.1362 0.1440
1.15 0.0234 0.0298 0.0310 0.0223 0.0294
1.20 0.0025 0.0049 0.0045 0.0032 0.0050
Table 5.4: Call Prices with IV=1.0 for Artificial Normal FCGARCH Series and
T=90. The parameters used for the FCGARCH are in table 1, and the table
with GARCH parameters are in table 2
K/S
0
BS FC-Normal GARCH-Normal FC-Gamma GARCH-Gamma
0.8 1 1.0000 0.9999 1.0007 1.0005
0.85 1 1.0003 1.0001 1.0015 1.0012
0.9 1 0.9998 1.0006 1.0026 1.0027
0.95 1 0.9886 0.9957 0.9950 1.0005
1 1 0.9436 0.9809 0.9413 0.9829
1.05 1 0.9063 0.9684 0.8718 0.9254
1.1 1 0.9619 1.0584 0.8648 0.9143
1.15 1 1.2735 1.3248 0.9530 1.2564
1.2 1 1.9600 1.8000 1.2800 2.0000
Table 5.5: Call Prices ratios with IV=1.0 for Artificial Normal FCGARCH
Series and T=90
Call Prices with IV=1.2 for Artificial Normal FCGARCH Series
K/S
0
BS FC-Normal GARCH-Normal FC-Gamma GARCH-Gamma
0.80 20.0006 20.0044 20.0013 20.1102 20.0202
0.85 15.0144 15.0151 15.0164 15.1265 15.0386
0.90 10.1509 10.1177 10.1298 10.2467 10.1584
0.95 5.8159 5.6726 5.7121 5.7923 5.7428
1.00 2.6481 2.4260 2.4961 2.4920 2.5059
1.05 0.9156 0.7588 0.8015 0.7778 0.8111
1.10 0.2359 0.1828 0.2016 0.1688 0.2072
1.15 0.0454 0.0354 0.0478 0.0267 0.0367
1.20 0.0066 0.0053 0.0096 0.0043 0.0078
Table 5.6: Call Prices with IV=1.2 for Artificial Normal FCGARCH Series
and T=90. The parameters used are in t able 1, and the table with G ARCH
parameters are in table 2
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 56
Call Prices with IV=1.0 for Artificial Shifted-Gamma FCGARCH Series
K/S
0
BS FC-Gamma GARCH-Gamma FC-Normal GARCH-Normal
0.80 20.0001 20.0149 19.8948 20.0009 20.0079
0.85 15.0045 15.0292 14.9062 15.0110 15.0176
0.90 10.0803 10.1216 9.9955 10.0939 10.1031
0.95 5.6017 5.6255 5.5110 5.5895 5.6136
1.00 2.3402 2.2757 2.2413 2.2812 2.3280
1.05 0.6831 0.6449 0.6171 0.6704 0.6907
1.10 0.1349 0.1362 0.1209 0.1515 0.1537
1.15 0.0180 0.0223 0.0227 0.0298 0.0314
1.20 0.0017 0.0032 0.0041 0.0049 0.0049
Table 5.7: Call Prices with IV=1.0 for Artificial Shifted-Gamma FCGARCH
Series and T=90. The parameters used are in tab le 1, and the table with
GARCH parameters are in table 3
K/S
0
BS FC-Gamma GARCH-Gamma FC-Normal GARCH-Normal
0.80 1.0000 1.0007 0.9947 1.0000 1.0004
0.85 1.0000 1.0016 0.9934 1.0004 1.0009
0.90 1.0000 1.0041 0.9916 1.0013 1.0023
0.95 1.0000 1.0042 0.9838 0.9978 1.0021
1.00 1.0000 0.9724 0.9577 0.9748 0.9948
1.05 1.0000 0.9441 0.9034 0.9814 1.0111
1.10 1.0000 1.0096 0.8962 1.1231 1.1394
1.15 1.0000 1.2389 1.2611 1.6556 1.7444
1.20 1.0000 1.8824 2.4118 2.8824 2.8824
Table 5.8: Call Prices with IV=1.0 for Artificial Shifted-Gamma FCGARCH
Series
Call Prices with IV=1.2 for Artificial Shifted-Gamma FCGARCH Series
K/S
0
BS FC-Gamma GARCH-Gamma FC-Normal GARCH-Normal
0.80 20.0004 20.1102 20.0946 20.0044 20.0052
0.85 15.0109 15.1265 15.1095 15.0151 15.0163
0.90 10.1290 10.2467 10.2206 10.1177 10.1205
0.95 5.7553 5.7923 5.7780 5.6726 5.6910
1.00 2.5635 2.4920 2.4712 2.4260 2.4512
1.05 0.8499 0.7778 0.7554 0.7588 0.7742
1.10 0.2052 0.1688 0.1839 0.1828 0.1851
1.15 0.0362 0.0267 0.0375 0.0354 0.0340
1.20 0.0047 0.0043 0.0073 0.0053 0.0069
Table 5.9: Call Prices with IV=1.2 for Artificial Shifted-Gamma FCGARCH
Series and T=90. The parameters used are in tab le 1, and the table with
GARCH parameters are in table 3
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 57
Figure 5.1: Graphs of Call Prices ratios with IV=1.0 for Artificial
Normal FCGARCH Series
Figure 5.2: Graphs of Call Prices ratios with IV=1.0 for Artificial
Shifted-Gamma FCGARCH Series
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 58
Put Prices with IV=1.0 for Artificial Normal FCGARCH Series
K/S
0
BS FC-Normal GARCH-Normal FC-Gamma GARCH-Gamma
0.80 0.0002 0.0001 0.0008 0.0024 0.0010
0.85 0.0063 0.0083 0.0097 0.0169 0.0107
0.90 0.0957 0.0893 0.0940 0.1095 0.1041
0.95 0.6537 0.5753 0.6230 0.6088 0.6523
1.00 2.4175 2.2835 2.3685 2.3003 2.3666
1.05 5.7397 5.6568 5.7088 5.5981 5.6728
1.10 10.1575 10.1466 10.1593 10.0596 10.1118
1.15 15.0234 15.0281 15.0358 14.9438 14.9701
1.20 20.0025 20.0059 20.0135 19.9292 19.9468
Table 5.10: Put Prices with IV=1.0 for Artificial Normal FCGARCH Series
and T=90. The parameters used are in table 1, , and the table with GARCH
parameters are in table 2
K/S
0
BS FC-Normal GARCH-Normal FC-Gamma GARCH-Gamma
0.8 1 0.5 4 12 5
0.85 1 1.31746 1.539683 2.68254 1.698413
0.9 1 0.933124 0.982236 1.144201 1.087774
0.95 1 0.880067 0.953037 0.931314 0.997858
1 1 0.944571 0.979731 0.95152 0.978945
1.05 1 0.985557 0.994616 0.97533 0.988344
1.1 1 0.998927 1.000177 0.990362 0.995501
1.15 1 1.000313 1.000825 0.994702 0.996452
1.2 1 1.00017 1.00055 0.996335 0.997215
Table 5.11: Put Prices ratios with IV=1.0 for Artificial Normal FCGARCH
Series
Put Prices with IV=1.2 for Artificial Normal FCGARCH Series
K/S
0
BS FC-Normal GARCH-Normal FC-Gamma GARCH-Gamma
0.80 0.0006 0.0015 0.0015 0.0045 0.0016
0.85 0.0144 0.0147 0.0162 0.0248 0.0174
0.90 0.1509 0.1143 0.1325 0.1369 0.1444
0.95 0.8159 0.6534 0.7193 0.6856 0.7842
1.00 2.6481 2.4055 2.4884 2.4509 2.6057
1.05 5.9156 5.7375 5.8160 5.8001 5.9466
1.10 10.2359 10.1780 10.2118 10.2156 10.3430
1.15 15.0454 15.0418 15.0502 15.0689 15.1735
1.20 20.0066 20.0087 20.0134 20.0372 20.1402
Table 5.12: Put Prices with IV=1.0 for Artificial Normal FCGARCH Series
and T=90. The parameters used are in t able 1, and the table with G ARCH
parameters are in table 2
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 59
Put Prices with IV=1.0 for Artificial Shifted-Gamma FCGARCH Series
K/S
0
BS FC-Gamma GARCH-Gamma FC-Normal GARCH-Normal
0.80 0.0001 0.0024 0.0009 0.0001 0.0002
0.85 0.0045 0.0169 0.0099 0.0083 0.0085
0.90 0.0803 0.1095 0.0946 0.0893 0.0948
0.95 0.6017 0.6088 0.5760 0.5753 0.6149
1.00 2.3402 2.3003 2.2122 2.2835 2.3398
1.05 5.6831 5.5981 5.4999 5.6568 5.6952
1.10 10.1349 10.0596 9.9490 10.1466 10.1505
1.15 15.0180 14.9438 14.8426 15.0281 15.0213
1.20 20.0017 19.9292 19.8236 20.0059 19.9995
Table 5.13: Put Prices with IV=1.0 for Artificial Shifted-G amma FCGARCH
Series and T=90. The parameters used are in tab le 1, and the table with
GARCH parameters are in table 3
K/S
0
BS FC-Gamma GARCH-Gamma FC-Normal GARCH-Normal
0.8 1.0000 24.0000 9.0000 1.0000 2.0000
0.85 1.0000 3.7556 2.2000 1.8444 1.8889
0.9 1.0000 1.3636 1.1781 1.1121 1.1806
0.95 1.0000 1.0118 0.9573 0.9561 1.0219
1 1.0000 0.9830 0.9453 0.9758 0.9998
1.05 1.0000 0.9850 0.9678 0.9954 1.0021
1.1 1.0000 0.9926 0.9817 1.0012 1.0015
1.15 1.0000 0.9951 0.9883 1.0007 1.0002
1.2 1.0000 0.9964 0.9911 1.0002 0.9999
Table 5.14: Pu t Prices ratios with IV=1.0 for Artificial Shifted-Gamma FC-
GARCH Series
Put Prices with IV=1.2 for Artificial Shifted-Gamma FCGARCH Series
K/S
0
BS FC-Gamma GARCH-Gamma FC-Normal GARCH-Normal
0.80 0.0004 0.0045 0.0008 0.0015 0.0008
0.85 0.0109 0.0248 0.0184 0.0147 0.0121
0.90 0.1290 0.1369 0.1357 0.1143 0.1086
0.95 0.7553 0.6856 0.7007 0.6534 0.6632
1.00 2.5635 2.4509 2.4390 2.4055 2.4242
1.05 5.8499 5.8001 5.7436 5.7375 5.7507
1.10 10.2052 10.2156 10.1765 10.1780 10.1735
1.15 15.0362 15.0689 15.0415 15.0418 15.0329
1.20 20.0047 20.0372 20.0196 20.0087 20.0058
Table 5.15: Put Prices with IV=1.2 for Artificial Shifted-Gamma FCGARCH
Series and T=90. The parameters used are in tab le 1, and the table with
GARCH parameters are in table 3
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 60
Figure 5.3: Graphs of Put Prices ratios with IV=1.0 for Artificial
Normal FCGARCH Series
Figure 5.4: Graphs of Put Prices ratios with IV=1.0 for Artificial
Shifted-Gamma FCGARCH Series
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 61
We can see that Calls and Puts have a different behavior. In tables 5.11
and 5.14, the put option price ratios have their largest values deep in the money.
The more pronounced effect is in the FC-Gamma scheme. The values are larger
than those in other schemes. Tables 5.5 and 5.8, on the other hand, show their
largest values deep out the money, although its effect is not as significant as in
the pu t case. For call options, the Normal models overprice the other models
whilst in the put options, the Shifted-Gamma models do. This behavior may
be explained by the negative asymmetry we introduced changing the signs of
the innovations, in the Shifted-Gamma case.
To illustrate the changes in the option prices when we change the
measures, we simulated prices under both the physical and risk neutral
measures in all schemes. Then we checked for the proportions of scenarios
where the options were exercised, which then give an estimate of the real-
world probability of exercising an option. We chose S
0
= 100 and K = 100 to
perform this exercise. We notice that in all schemes presented in table 5.16,
the prices under the risk neutral measure are less likely to exceed the strike
price than the prices under the physical measure.
Table 5.16: Average rate of exercising
Model/rate Risk Neutral Measure Physical Measure
FCGARCH Normal 0.4881 0.6197
FCGARCH Gamma 0.5032 0.6198
Gamma GARCH 0.4940 0.6338
Normal Garch 0.4885 0.5939
GARCH-Gamma with Normal data 0.4805 0.5994
GARCH-Normal with Gamma data 0.4870 0.6238
Then we focus on the GARCH-Gamma case using parameters estimated
from artificial FC-GARCH Gamma data to produce the numerical results
presented in the table below. The choice of this scheme is justified by its largest
difference in the estimates ab ove between the two measures. We considered
S
0
= 100 and varied the strike price. Note that for every strike price, the risk
neutral prices have a smaller chance of exceeding the strike price than the
prices in the physical measure.
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 62
Average rate of exercising (Gamma GARCH)
K/S
0
Risk Neutral measure Physical measure
0.80 0.9991 1.0000
0.85 0.9932 0.9978
0.90 0.9491 0.9784
0.95 0.7922 0.8885
1.00 0.4908 0.6336
1.05 0.2004 0.2991
1.10 0.0552 0.0862
1.15 0.0095 0.0162
1.20 0.0015 0.0023
Table 5.17: Average rate of exercising for Artificial Shifted-Gamma GARCH
Series and T=90. The parameters used are in tab le 1, and the table with
GARCH parameters are in table 3
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 63
70 80 90 100 110 120 130
0
50
100
150
200
250
300
350
Figure 5.5: Histogram of S
T
in the physical measure
70 80 90 100 110 120 130
0
50
100
150
200
250
300
350
400
Figure 5.6: Histogram of S
T
in the risk neutral measure
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 64
5.5
Sensitivity Analysis
Now we are going to check how the option prices change when some
of the parameters are perturbed. We performed simulations imposing a small
variation around the values of the parameters.
In some cases, it is important to bear in mind the stationarity condition.
We note that putting the parameters so that the stationarity condition is close
to 2 makes the effect on the option prices more pronounced. The stationarity
condition for the Normal case, what is going to be used as a benchmark, once
we don’t have a stability condition for the Gamma case, is given by:
2λ
1
+ 2β
1
+ β
2
+ λ
2
+ β
3
+ λ
3
< 2.
Proceeding with this exercise we capture the importance of each pa-
rameter in the option prices. We perform this analysis with the FC-GARCH
models having Normal and Shifted-Gamma innovations. Graphs are shown in
the appendix to illustrate such analysis.
5.5.1
Normal innovations
As we increase th e value β
1
by steps of 0.05, the option price also
increases. Note that a larger value of β
1
has a deeper impact than the others.
This is because the last β
1
are closer to the stationarity condition. Then we
increase the value of β
2
by the same increment, we have the same effect. After
that, we notice that changing β
3
doesn’t affect much the option price. When
we repeated the experiment with steps of 0.1, even then the graph was the
same, but we can see a slightly increasing pattern in the output numbers.
For the λ
1
and λ
2
graphs we can see a slightly increase in the option
prices. For the λ
3
, although a slight increase occurs it is not obviously shown
in the graph even when we performed with increments of 0.05. Run ning
γ σ = 1, 6, 11, 16 and 21, no changes are seen in both cases γ
1
and γ
2
.
For the effect of c
1
, we noticed that the option value increases with an
increase in c
1
. On the other hand there is no clear effect of changing c
2
.
The risk premium didn’t show any clear effect. The graphic shows five
variations of the risk premium with steps of 0.05. It seems having an increasing
trend, but it is not clear even performing steps of 0.1.
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 65
5.5.2
Shifted Gamma innovations
For the Gamma case, we chose 0.05 to b e the increment of β
1
. The option
value increases with an increase in the value of β
1
as in the Normal case. Note
that in the last curve, when the stationarity condition exceeds 2, the increase
in option prices has a more pronounced effect. Again, with steps of 0.05 we
perturbed β
2
and the option values were also increased. We can see that as β
2
is closer to 2 the bigger its impact on the option price. In the analysis of β
3
we
can not see the same behavior. It may be attributed to the insignificant effect
of the last regime.
The a parameter doesn’t have a clear effect on the option prices. It varied
from 10 to 190 in steps of 45.
An increase in λ
1
and λ
2
with increments of 0.01 increases the option
prices. We performed the analysis of λ
3
with increments 0.01,0.05 and 0.1. No
significant effect is noticed in any of the cases.
For the c
1
, with 0.1 increments, we see a slight increase of the price of the
option. The c
2
has no significant effect on prices. For the Gamma parameter,
running γ σ = 1, 6, 11, 16 and 21 no changes are seen in both cases γ
1
and γ
2
.
The risk premium has no clear monotonic pattern influence on the option
prices. We simulated with increments of 0.05 and also steps of 0.1, that are
relatively large relative to the initial value 0.0363.
5.6
Discussion of the results
In the tables and graphs of section 5, we noticed that the prices obtained
from the FC-GARCH models are slightly higher than the Black Scholes prices,
but th e FC-GARCH option prices are lower than the GARCH option prices in
both the Normal and Gamma cases for the calls, but for the puts this effect is
only noticed in the normal case.
In the sensitivity analysis, we noticed that the GARCH parameters for
the regime zero and the first regime were the most sensitive to perturbations
of these model parameters while the GARCH parameters of the third regime,
the logistic parameter γ, and the risk premium λ have little or no impact on
option prices.
5.7
Conclusions
In this chapter we adopted the method of Siu et al. (2004) (43) to find
a pricing kernel for the FC-GARCH models with two different parametric
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 66
distributions for innovations, the Normal and the shifted-Gamma cases. We
also performed simulations and showed tables comparing the Black Scholes
prices and the GARCH prices to our simulation results of the FC-GARCH
models as well as we performed a sensitivity analysis to understand how
changes in some parameters affect the option valuation results.
The FC-GARCH models can capture features that some other models
cannot, like the high kurtosis with low first-order autocorrelation of the squared
observations, so that the option prices are more precise if calculated in the way
we did in this chapter. Here we performed simulations with 3 regimes but the
model can mimic an economy with many regimes. A further research would be
developing tests to find the optimal numb er of regimes for each situation.
6
Option Valuation under Mixture GARCH models
This chapter is based in a working paper together with the Professors Ken Siu,
John Lau and
´
Alvaro Veiga.
It has been documented that normal mixture GARCH models can pro-
vide a better description for the leptokurtosis behavior in financial returns
data compared with the GARCH models with normal innovations and the
student’s t-GARCH models (see Alexander and Lazar (2006) (1)). In this pa-
per, we shall consider the pricing of options under the class of discrete-time
mixture of GARCH models with innovations having a finite mixture of in-
finitely divisible distributions. The option valuation model can provide market
practitioners with a convenient and flexible way to price options under various
forms of mixture GARCH models, which can incorporate different degrees of
conditional skewness and conditional leptokurtosis of the distribution of the
asset returns. The market described by the discrete-time mixture GARCH
models is incomplete and, hence, there are infinitely many equivalent mar-
tingale measures. We shall employ the doubly stochastic Esscher transform
to determine an equivalent martingale measure for pricing. The p ricing result
can be justified by a stochastic version of the power utility maximization. Em-
pirical results for comparing the call and put option prices obtained from the
mixture GARCH models with those from the standard Black-Scholes model
based on the recent 25-year S&P 500 data will be presented and discussed.
6.1
Asset Price Dynamics and Pricing Model
We consider a discrete-time financial model consisting of one risk-free bond
B and one risky stock S. We assume that the dynamics of the risky stock
is governed by a mixture GARCH model with innovations having a finite
mixture of infinitely divisible distributions. The mixture GARCH model
can incorporate various parametric forms of the mixture GARCH models,
such as the Normal-Mixture (NM) GARCH models in Alexander and Lazar
(2006)(1), the GARCH models with innovations having a finite mixture of
shifted gamma distributions and a finite mixture of shifted Inverse Gaussian
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 68
distributions. It p rovides market practitioners with a great deal of flexibility
in modelling various empirical “stylised” behavior of asset price dynamics, like
the conditional skewed and leptokurtosis (or heavy-tailed) behaviors of the
asset returns. In the following, we present the setup of the mo del.
First, we describe the general mixture GARCH model. Let (Ω, F, P) be
a complete probability space, where P is a real-world probability. Let T be the
time index set {0, 1, 2, . . . , T } of the financial model. Let S := {S
t
}
t∈T
denote
a stochastic process defined on (Ω, F) with state space R
+
, where R
+
is the
set of non- negative real numbers. For each t T , S
t
represents the price of the
risky stock S at time t. Wr ite F
S
:= {F
S
t
}
t∈T
for the P-augmentation of the
natural filtration generated by the process S. For each t T , F
S
t
represents
the observable information about the prices of the risky stock S up to and
including time t. Let B := {B
t
}
t∈T
denote the price process of the risk-free
bond B, which is assumed to be a deterministic process.
Let {ξ
t
}
t∈T
denote a stochastic process defined on (Ω, F) taking values
on the real line R, with ξ
t
D(0, h
t
) and ξ
0
= 0, which represents t he
random fluctuations of the returns from the risky asset S. For each t T ,
we call ξ
t
the innovation of asset return at time t. For each k = 1, 2, . . . , K,
let h
k
:= {h
kt
}
t∈T \{0}
denote a stochastic process on (Ω, F) with state space
R
+
, where R
+
is the set of positive real numb ers. For each k = 1, 2, . . . , K,
we assume that th e dynamics of h
k
is governed by the following GARCH(p,
q) structure:
h
kt
= α
k0
+
q
j=1
α
kj
ξ
2
tj
+
K
i=1
p
l=1
β
kil
h
i,t1
, (6-1)
where p 1, q 1 and α
k0
> 0, α
kj
0, j {1, 2, . . . , q}, β
kil
0,
l {1, 2, . . . , p} in order to ensure the positivity of h
kt
.
In the particular case of the GARCH(1, 1) that we are going to deal
with, for ensuring covariance stationarity of th e GARCH(1, 1) structure for
each k = 1, 2, . . . , K, we further impose the condition that the matrix
α
1
p
T
+ B
has all the eigenvalues smaller than 1, where α
1
= [α
11
, α
21
, ..., α
K1
]
T
, p =
[p
1
, p
2
..., p
K
]
T
and B = β
ki
; k, i = 1, ..., K.
Write U := {U
t
}
t∈T
for a sequence of independent and identically
distributed (i.i.d.) K-dimensional random vectors, which take values from the
state space U := {e
1
, e
2
, . . . , e
K
}, where e
k
:= (0, 0, . . . , 1, . . . , 0, 0) R
K
is
a unit vector with one in the k
th
component and zero otherwise. We suppose
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 69
that the common probability distribution of U
t
is specified by:
P(U
t
= e
k
) = p
k
, k = 1, 2, . . . , K , (6-2)
where p
k
0 and
K
k=1
p
k
= 1.
Let H := {H
t
}
t∈T \{0}
denote a stochastic process on (Ω, F) with
state space H := {h
1t
, h
2t
, . . . , h
Kt
}. For each t T \{0}, let H
t
:=
(h
1t
, h
2t
, . . . , h
Kt
). Then, we can write H
t
as follows:
H
t
=< H
t
, U
t
>=
K
k=1
< H
t
, e
k
>< U
t
, e
k
> . (6-3)
Write F
U
t
for the information set generated by the values of the pro cess U up
to and including time t. Write F
t
for the enlarged information set F
S
t1
F
U
t
generated by F
S
t1
and F
U
t
. We shall specify the distributional structure of the
process {ξ
t
}
t∈T
.
F (x|0, H
t
) =
K
k=1
F (x|0, < H
t
, e
k
>) < U
t
, e
k
>=
K
k=1
F (x|0, h
kt
) < U
t
, e
k
> .(6-4)
Hence, the conditional distribution of ξ
t
given the observable information set
F
S
t1
is given by the following finite mixture of infinitely divisible distributions:
F
ξ
(x|F
S
t1
) =
K
k=1
p
kt
F (x|0, h
kt
) , (6-5)
where F (···|0, h
kt
) is the mixing kernel of the mixture distribution.
We write ξ
t
|F
S
t1
MID(p
1
, . . . , p
K
; h
1t
, . . . , h
Kt
), which represents the
finite mixture of infinitely divisible distributions. We shall introduce the price
dynamics of the risk-free bond B and the underlying risky asset S. Let r
t
be the
continuously compounded risk-free interest rate of the bond B over the time
interval [t 1, t], where t T \{0}; λ
t
the unit risk premium over the time
interval [t 1, t]. We suppose that both r
t
and λ
t
are deterministic functions
of time t. Then, we assume that, under P, the dynamics of the bond-price
process {B
t
}
t∈T
and the stock-price process {S
t
}
t∈T
satisfy:
B
t
= B
t1
e
r
t
, B
0
= 1 ,
S
t
= S
t1
exp(r
t
+ λ
t
< H
t
, U
t
>
1
2
< H
t
, U
t
> +ξ
t
) , S
0
= s ,(6-6)
for each t T \{0}.
For each t T \{0}, Y
t
denotes the continuously compounded one-p eriod
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 70
rate of return ln(
S
t
S
t1
) of the stock S. Clearly, Y
t
is measurable with respect
to the observable information set F
S
t
. Then, under P, the dynamics of Y
t
is
governed by the following GARCH(p, q) model with innovations having a finite
mixture of infinitely divisible distributions:
Y
t
= r
t
+ λ
t
< H
t
, U
t
>
1
2
< H
t
, U
t
> +ξ
t
,
ξ
t
|F
S
t1
MID(p
1
, . . . , p
K
; h
1t
, . . . , h
Kt
) ,
h
kt
= α
k0
+
q
j=1
α
kj
ξ
2
tj
+
K
i=1
p
l=1
β
kil
h
i,t1
. (6-7)
The above model is called MID(K)-GARCH (p, q) model. It can in-
corporate the general form NM(K)-GARCH(p, q) specified by Haas, Mit-
tnik and Paolella ( 2002) (32) without explanatory variables and the NM(K)-
GARCH(1,1) examined by Alexander and Lazar (2006)(1). The model by
Haas, Mittnik and Paolella (2002)(32) can incorporate the cross dependence
of individual conditional variances by assuming the inter-dependent autore-
gressive evolution of the time series of conditional variances. Alexander and
Lazar (2006)(1) mentioned that the mixture GARCH model can be related to
other important GARCH models with non-normal innovations and the class
of Markov-Switching GARCH models. In fact, the MID(K)-GARCH (p, q)
model can be considered a particular case of a general class of regime-switch ing
GARCH(p, q) models with innovations having a finite mixture of infinitely di-
visible distributions and the GARCH dynamics driven by a hidden Markov
chain model. The MID(K)-GARCH (p, q) model is different from the one in
Alexander and Lazar (2006)(1) in two aspects. First, the proposed mixture
GARCH model here has a time-varying drift depending on the conditional
volatility of the return’s process while the mixture GARCH m odel in Alexan-
der and Lazar (2006)(1) has a constant drift. Second, the proposed mixture
GARCH model has a general mixing kernel, which is specified by an infinite
divisible distribution with a finite moment generating function. Hence, it is
flexible enough to incorporate the Normal-Mixture (NM) GARCH models in
Alexander and Lazar (2006)(1), the GARCH models with innovations having
a finite mixture of shifted gamma distributions and a finite mixture of shifted
Inverse Gaussian distributions, and others. This provides market practitioners
with a great deal of flexibility in modelling different empirical “stylised” behav-
iors of asset price dynamics, such the skewed behavior and the leptokurtosis
behavior of the distribution of asset’s returns.
We shall present the discrete-time doubly stochastic Esscher transform in
the sequel. The doubly stochastic Esscher transform is defined by the product
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 71
of two stochastic processes. The idea is similar with the conditional Esscher
transform introduced in B¨uhlmann et al. (1996)(9). Elliott, Siu and Chan
(2006)(23) considered a similar type of doubly stochastic Esscher transform,
namely the regime-switching Esscher transform, in the context of a continuous-
time regime-switching Geometric Brownian Motion model. The discrete-time
version of the regime-switching Esscher transform has been adopted in Elliott,
Siu and Chan (2006)(23) for pricing options under a discrete-time Markov-
switching GARCH models.
First, we consider a real-valued stochastic process {Θ
t
}
t∈T
\{0} defined
on (Ω, F). We assume th at for each t T \{0}, Θ
t
is measurable with respect
to F
U
t
.
Let M
Y
(t, Θ
t
) denote the moment generating function of Y
t
given F
S
t1
under P; that is,
M
Y |F
S
t1
(t, Θ
t
) := E
P
(e
Θ
t
Y
t
|F
S
t1
) . (6-8)
We assume that E
P
(e
Θ
t
Y
t
|F
S
t1
) < , for t T \{0}. As in uhlmann et al.
(1996)(9), we define a sequence {Λ
t
}
t∈T
with Λ
0
= 1 as follows:
Λ
t
=
t
u=1
e
Θ
u
Y
u
M
Y
(u, Θ
u
)
, t T \{0} , (6-9)
where Λ
t
is specified by a product of two stochastic p rocesses {Θ
t
}
t∈T \{0}
and
{Y
t
}
t∈T \{0}
.
Lemma 36 {Λ
t
}
t∈T
is a (F, P)-martingale.
Proof : From its definition, Λ
t
is F
t+1
-measurable, for each t T and that
E
P
Λ
t
Λ
t1
F
S
t1
= E
P
e
Θ
t
Y
t
E
P
(e
Θ
t
Y
t
|F
S
t1
)
F
S
t1
= 1 , P a.s. (6.1)
Hence, the result follows.
Then, the doubly stochastic Esscher transform P
Θ
P on F
t
with
respect to {Θ
1
, Θ
2
, . . . , Θ
t1
} is given by:
dP
Θ
dP
F
t
:= Λ
t1
, t = 2, 3, . . . , T + 1 . (6-2)
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 72
Let M
Y
(z, t; Θ) be the moment generating function of Y
t
given F
t
under P
Θ
.
Then, we have the following lemma:
Lemma 37
M
Y
(z, t; Θ) =
M
Y
(t, z + Θ
t
)
M
Y
(t, Θ
t
)
. (6-3)
Proof : The proof is adapted to the argument in Elliott, Siu and Chan
(2006)(23) in the case of mixture GARCH models. By Baye’s rule,
M
Y
(z, t; Θ) = E
P
Θ
(e
zY
t
|F
S
t1
)
=
E
P
t
e
zY
t
|F
S
t1
)
E
P
t
|F
S
t1
)
= E
P
Λ
t
Λ
t1
e
zY
t
F
S
t1
=
E
P
(e
(z
t
)Y
t
|F
S
t1
)
E
P
(e
Θ
t
Y
t
|F
S
t1
)
=
M
Y
(t, z + Θ
t
)
M
Y
(t, Θ
t
)
. (6-4)
Hence, the result follows.
Harrison and Krep (1979) (33)and Harrison and Pliska (1981, 1983)(34,
35) provided a solid theoretical foundation to establish the relationship be-
tween the absence of arbitrage and the existence of an equivalent martingale
measure using the modern language of probability. They introduced the fun-
damental theorem of asset pricing which states that the absence of arbitrage is
equivalent to the existence of an equivalent martingale measure under which
the discounted asset price process is a martingale. The fundamental theorem of
asset pricing was then further extended by Dybyig and Ross (1987)(20), Back
and Pliska (1991)(2), Schachermayer (1992)(39) and Delbaen and Schacher-
mayer (1994)(15). Back and Pliska (1991)(2) has shown that the absence of
arbitrage is equivalent to the existence of an equivalent m artingale measure in
a discrete-time and an infinite-state-space setting.
We shall determine an equivalent martingale measure using the doubly
stochastic Esscher transform P
Θ
. The sufficient condition on Θ
t
for P
Θ
to be
an equivalent martingale measure is presented in the following proposition.
Proposition 38 (Martingale Condition) Suppose Θ
t
satisfies the following
condition:
M
Y
(t, Θ
t
+ 1)
M
Y
(t, Θ
t
)
= e
r
t
. (6-5)
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 73
Then, the discounted price process {exp(
t
u=1
r
u
)S
t
}
t∈T
is a (F, P
Θ
)-
martingale.
Proof :
E
P
Θ
e
t
u=1
r
u
S
t
F
S
t1
= e
t1
u=1
r
u
S
t1
E
P
Θ
(e
Y
t
r
t
|F
S
t1
)
= e
t1
u=1
r
u
S
t1
E
P

Λ
t
Λ
t1
e
Y
t
r
t
F
S
t1
= e
t1
u=1
r
u
S
t1
e
r
t
E
P
(e
t
+1)Y
t
|F
S
t1
)
E
P
(e
Θ
t
Y
t
|F
S
t1
)
= e
t1
u=1
r
u
S
t1
e
r
t
M
Y
(t, Θ
t
+ 1)
M
Y
(t, Θ
t
)
= e
t1
u=1
r
u
S
t1
, P a.s. (6-6)
Hence, the result follows.
Note that the existence and uniqueness of Θ
t
satisfying the condition
in Proposition 2.3 can be proved by following the arguments in Chan and
van-der Hoek (2003) (11). The martingale condition with respect to the
enlarged filtration {F
t
}
t∈T
is stronger than that with respect to the observable
information structure {F
S
t
}
t∈T
. In other words, if there exists a probability
measure P
Θ
satisfying the martingale condition with respect to {F
t
}
t∈T
, P
Θ
also satisfies the martingale condition with respect to {F
S
t
}
t∈T
. This can be
verified easily by the double expectation formula for conditional expectations.
Then, given F
t
:= F
S
t1
F
U
t
, the price of a European-style contingent
claim written on the underlying stock S with payoff V (S
T
) at maturity T is
given by:
V (t 1, T |F
t
) = E
P
Θ
exp
T
u=t
r
u
V (S
T
)
F
t
. (6-7)
Given the observable information F
S
t1
, the price of the option can be deter-
mined as follows:
V (t 1, T |F
S
t1
) = E
P
Θ
[V (t 1, T |F
t
)|F
S
t1
]
= E
P
Θ
exp
T
u=t
r
u
V (S
T
)
F
S
t1
.
In order to compute the option price V (t 1, T |F
S
t1
) under a given para-
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 74
metric distribution for the innovations, we first need to estimate the unknown
parameters of the mixture GARCH model using the observed market price
data for S under P and then simulate the terminal stock prices from the mix-
ture GARCH model under P
Θ
for approximating V (t 1, T |F
S
t1
) via Monte
Carlo simulation coupled with its control variates technique. Due to the struc-
ture of the mixture GARCH model, its likelihood function can be determined
completely given the observed market price data F
S
t1
. Hence, we do not need
to use information from the values of the hidden mixing process {U
t
}
t∈T \{0}
for the estimation part. However, in the Monte Carlo simulation, we need to
generate the values of the pro cess {U
t
}
t∈T \{0}
and the values of the innova-
tions process {ξ
t
}
t∈T \{0}
for simulating the terminal stock prices. In section 4,
we shall discuss in some detail the estimation and simulation procedures for
computing the prices of a European call option under two parametric mixture
GARCH models described in Section 3.
We shall justify the pricing result by a power utility maximization
problem with respect to F
t
. For each t T \{0}, let ζ
t
denote a random
variable measurable with respect to F
t
. Then, for each t T \{0}, we consider
a power utility function u
t
with the stochastic risk-averse parameter ζ
t
; that
is, for each t T \{0},
u
t
(x) =
x
1ζ
t
1ζ
t
if ζ
t
= 1,
ln x if ζ
t
= 1.
Equivalently, the power utility function can be written as:
u
t
(x) =
x
1ζ
t
1 ζ
t
I
{ζ
t
=1}
+ (ln x)I
{ζ
t
=1}
. (6-8)
We call the above power utility function a stochastic power utility function. We
assume that an economic agent can adjust the stochastic risk-averse parameter
ζ
t
based on F
t
. For each t T \{0}, following Gerber and Shiu (1994) (31),
we impose the following assumptions:
1. The economic agent has m
t
units of stock S and η
t
units of the option
from time t 1 to time t, where m
t
, η
t
F
t
.
2.
˜
V (t 1, T |F
t
) represents the economic agent’s equilibrium price at time
t 1 of the option with maturity at time T so that it is optimal for the
agent not to buy or sell any units of the option at time t 1.
For each t T \{0}, the conditional expected utility function U
t
on the
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 75
economic agent’s wealth at time t given F
t
under P is given by:
U
t
(η
t
)
= E
P
u
t
m
t
S
t
+ η
t
˜
V (t, T |F
t+1
) e
r
t
˜
V (t 1, T |F
t
)

F
t
, (6-9)
where η
t
is the choice variable.
The following proposition justifies the pricing result by the doubly
stochastic Esscher transform.
Proposition 39 For each t T \{0},
V (t 1, T |F
t
) =
˜
V (t 1, T |F
t
) , (6-10)
and
ζ
t
= Θ
t
. (6-11)
Proof : We follow the argument in Gerber and Shiu (1994)(31). The optimal
condition of the conditional expected utility function on the economic agent’s
wealth is equivalent to that U
t
(η
t
) attains its maximum value when η
t
= 0, for
each t T \{0}. Mathematically, this can be translated to:
U
t
(η
t
)|
η
t
=0
= 0 , (6-12)
where U
t
is the derivative of U
t
with respect to η
t
.
For simplicity, we write
˜
V
t1
for
˜
V (t 1, T |F
t
). Then, the optimal
condition implies that
˜
V
t1
= e
r
t
E
P
[
˜
V
t
u
t
(m
t
S
t
)|F
t
]
E[u
t
(m
t
S
t
)|F
t
]
, (6-13)
where u
t
is the derivative of u
t
with respect to η
t
.
We notice that
u
t
(x) = x
ζ
t
I
{ζ
t
=1}
+ (1/x)I
{ζ
t
=1}
. (6-14)
Then,
˜
V
t1
= e
r
t
E[
˜
V
t
(m
t
S
t
)
ζ
t
|F
t
]
E[(m
t
S
t
)
ζ
t
|F
t
]
I
{ζ
t
=1}
+
E[
˜
V
t
/(m
t
S
t
)|F
t
]
E[1/(m
t
S
t
)|F
t
]
I
{ζ
t
=1}
= e
r
t
E[
˜
V
t
(m
t
S
t
)
ζ
t
|F
t
]
E[(m
t
S
t
)
ζ
t
|F
t
]
. (6-15)
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 76
Since the above result applies for any option, it can be applied for the
underlying asset S. Hen ce,
S
t1
= e
r
t
E(S
1ζ
t
t
|F
t
)
E(S
ζ
t
t
|F
t
)
= e
r
t
S
t1
E(e
(1ζ
t
)Y
t
|F
t
)
E(e
ζ
t
Y
t
|F
t
)
= e
r
t
S
t1
M
Y
(t, 1 ζ
t
)
M
Y
(t, ζ
t
)
. (6-16)
Then,
M
Y
(t, 1 ζ
t
)
M
Y
(t, ζ
t
)
= e
r
t
. (6-17)
Hence, by uniqueness of Θ
t
satisfying the martingale condition,
ζ
t
= Θ
t
, (6-18)
and
˜
V
t1
= V
t1
. (6-19)
6.2
Parametric Cases
In this section, we deal with some parametric cases, namely the Normal-
Mixture (NM) GARCH model and the mixture GARCH mo del with innova-
tions having a finite mixture of shifted gamma distributions. We consider K-
component first-order mixture GARCH models in this section. The derivation
of the pricing result for the case when the innovations have a finite mixture
of shifted inverse Gaussian distributions is very similar to that of the finite
mixture of shifted gamma distributions. We are able to pr eserve the paramet-
ric forms of the distributions for the GARCH innovations under the change of
probability measures using the doubly stochastic Esscher tranform in Section
2.
6.2.1
Normal-Mixture (NM) GARCH models
First, we assume that under P, the conditional distribution of ξ
t
given
F
S
t1
is a normal distribution N(0, < H
t
, U
t
>) with mean 0 and conditional
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 77
variance < H
t
, U
t
>, for each t T \{0}. Then, the conditional distribution
of ξ
t
given F
S
t1
under P is given by the following finite mixture of normal
distributions:
F
ξ
(x|F
S
t1
) =
K
k=1
p
k
N(x|0, h
kt
) ,
K
k=1
p
k
= 1 . (6-20)
The conditional distribution of Y
t
given F
S
t1
under P is a normal distri-
bution N(r
t
+ λ
t
< H
t
, U
t
>
1
2
< H
t
, U
t
>, < H
t
, U
t
>) with mean
r
t
+ λ
t
< H
t
, U
t
>
1
2
< H
t
, U
t
> and variance < H
t
, U
t
>, where the distri-
bution of U
t
is given by:
P (U
t
= e
k
) = p
k
,
and the dynamics of h
k
is governed by:
h
kt
= α
k0
+ α
k1
ξ
2
t1
+
K
k=1
β
ki1
h
i,t1
,
for each k = 1, 2, . . . , K. Hence we have
Y
t
= r
t
+ λ
t
< H
t
, U
t
>
1
2
< H
t
, U
t
> +ξ
t
,
ξ
t
|F
S
t1
NM(p
1
, . . . , p
K
; h
1t
, . . . , h
Kt
) ,
h
kt
= α
k0
+ α
k1
ξ
2
t1
+
K
i=1
β
ki1
h
i,t1
.
Then,
M
Y
t
|F
S
t1
(t, Θ
t
) = exp
Θ
t
r
t
+ λ
t
< H
t
, U
t
>
1
2
< H
t
, U
t
>
+
1
2
Θ
2
t
< H
t
, U
t
>
.(6-21)
From the martingale condition proposition, the risk-neutralized stochastic
Esscher parameter Θ
t
is given by:
Θ
t
=
λ
t
< H
t
, U
t
>
= λ
t
K
k=1
1
h
kt
< U
t
, e
k
> , t T \{0} . (6-22)
The moment generating function M
Y
t
|F
S
t1
(z, t; Θ) is given by:
M
θ
Y
t
|F
S
t1
(z, t; Θ) = exp[z(r
1
2
< H
t
, U
t
>) +
1
2
z
2
< H
t
, U
t
>] .(6-23)
Hence, under P
Θ
, the conditional distribution of Y
t
given F
S
t1
is a normal
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 78
distribution with conditional mean r
t
1
2
< H
t
, U
t
> and conditional variance
< H
t
, U
t
>, where
P (U
t
= e
k
) = p
k
, (6-24)
and
h
kt
= α
k0
+ α
k1
ξ
2
t1
+
K
i=1
β
ki1
h
i,t1
. (6-25)
for each k = 1, 2, . . . , K.
Note that ξ
t
|F
S
t1
N(λ
t
< H
t
, U
t
>, < H
t
, U
t
>) under P
Θ
. Let ǫ
t1
:=
ξ
t1
+ λ
t1
< H
t1
, U
t1
>. Then, under P
Θ
, ǫ
t
|F
S
t1
N(0, < H
t
, U
t
>). We
can write the dynamics of h
kt
as follows:
h
kt
= α
k0
+ α
k1
(ǫ
t1
λ
t1
< H
t1
, U
t1
>)
2
+
K
i=1
β
ki1
h
i,t1
.(6-26)
We have just proved the following Theorem:
Theorem 40 Let
Y
t
= r
t
+ λ
t
< H
t
, U
t
>
1
2
< H
t
, U
t
> +ξ
t
,
ξ
t
|F
S
t1
NM(p
1
, . . . , p
K
; h
1t
, . . . , h
Kt
) ,
h
kt
= α
k0
+ α
k1
ξ
2
t1
+
K
i=1
β
ki1
h
i,t1
.
be the model in the real world probability P. Then, the risk neutral version of
the model is:
Y
t
= r
t
1
2
H
t
, U
t
+ ǫ
t
ǫ
t
|F
S
t1
N (0, H
t
, U
t
)
h
kt
= α
k0
+ α
k1
ǫ
t1
λ
t1
H
t1
, U
t1
2
+
K
i=1
β
ki1
h
i,t1
6.2.2
Shifted-Gamma-Mixture (SGM) GARCH models
We assume t hat the innovations for the general mixture GARCH model in
Section 2 follow a finite mixture of shifted gamma distributions. First, for each
k = 1, 2, . . . , K, we consider a sequence of i.i.d. random variables {X
(k)
t
}
t∈T \{0}
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 79
with common distribution being a gamma distribution Ga(a
k
, b) with shape
parameter a
k
and scale parameter b. For each t T \{0}, we define the random
variable ν
(k)
t
by standardizing the gamma random variable X
t
as follows:
ν
(k)
t
:=
X
(k)
t
a
k
/b
a
k
/b
2
. (6-27)
Note that ν
(k)
t
follows a standard shifted gamma distribution SGa(·|0, 1) with
zero mean and unit variance, for each k = 1, 2, . . . , K. For each t T \{0}, let
V
t
:= (ν
1
, ν
2
, . . . , ν
K
) and ν
t
be defined as follows:
ν
t
:=< V
t
, U
t
>=
K
k=1
< V
t
, e
k
>< U
t
, e
k
>=
K
k=1
ν
k
< U
t
, e
k
> . (6-28)
Then, ν
t
follows a standard shifted gamma distribution SGa(·|0, 1) with zero
mean and unit variance.
We assume that ξ
t
:=
< H
t
, U
t
t
; then, ξ
t
=
K
k=1
h
kt
ν
(k)
t
<
U
t
, e
k
>. Hence, the conditional distribution of ξ
t
given F
S
t1
under P is
minus a shifted gamma distribution SGa(·|0, < H
t
, U
t
>) with zero mean and
variance < H
t
, U
t
>=
K
k=1
h
kt
< U
t
, e
k
>. Then, the conditional distribution
of ξ
t
given F
S
t1
is given by the following finite mixture of shifted gamma
distributions:
F
ξ
(x|F
S
t1
) =
K
k=1
p
k
SGa(x|0, h
kt
) ,
K
k=1
p
k
= 1 , (6-29)
where SGa(·|0, h
kt
) is the probability distribution of a shifted gamma distri-
bution with mean 0 and variance h
kt
.
We write ξ
t
|F
S
t1
MSGa(p
1
, . . . , p
K
; h
1t
, . . . , h
Kt
). Hence, under
P, the conditional distribution of Y
t
given F
S
t1
is minus a shifted gamma
distribution SGa(·|r
t
+ λ
t
< H
t
, U
t
>
1
2
< H
t
, U
t
>, < H
t
, U
t
>) with mean
r
t
+ λ
t
< H
t
, U
t
>
1
2
< H
t
, U
t
> and variance < H
t
, U
t
>. Then, under
P, the dynamics of Y
t
is governed by the following K-component first-order
mixture GARCH model with innovations having a finite mixture of shifted
gamma distributions:
Y
t
= r
t
+ λ
t
< H
t
, U
t
>
1
2
< H
t
, U
t
> +ξ
t
,
ξ
t
|F
S
t1
MSGa(p
1
, . . . , p
K
; h
1t
, . . . , h
Kt
) ,
h
kt
= α
k0
+ α
k1
ξ
2
t1
+
K
i=1
β
ki1
h
i,t1
. (6-30)
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 80
Let A := (a
1
, a
2
, . . . , a
K
) and A
t
be defined as follows:
A
t
:=< A, U
t
>=
K
k=1
a
k
< U
t
, e
k
> . (6-31)
We can also write the dynamics of {Y
t
}
t∈T \{0}
under P as follows:
Y
t
=
K
k=1
r
t
+ λ
t
< H
t
, e
k
>
1
2
< H
t
, e
k
> +
< A, e
k
>< H
t
, e
k
>
b
< H
t
, e
k
>
< A, e
k
>
X
(k)
t
< U
t
, e
k
>
=
K
k=1
r
t
+ λ
t
h
kt
1
2
h
kt
+
a
k
h
kt
b
h
kt
a
k
X
(k)
t
< U
t
, e
k
> .(6-32)
Define B
t
as
A
t
H
t
; that is,
B
t
=
K
k=1
a
k
h
kt
< U
t
, e
k
> . (6-33)
Then, the conditional distribution of Y
t
given F
S
t1
is minus a shifted gamma
distribution with shape parameter A
t
, scale parameter B
t
and shifted param-
eter r
t
λ
t
< H
t
, U
t
> +
1
2
< H
t
, U
t
>
< A, U
t
>< H
t
, U
t
>. Hence, the
moment generating function of Y
t
given F
S
t1
under P is given by:
M
Y |F
S
t1
(t, Θ
t
) =
B
t
B
t
+ Θ
t
A
t
e
(
r
t
+λ
t
H
t
1
2
H
t
+
A
t
H
t)
Θ
t
, (6-34)
where 0 < B
t
+ Θ
t
.
Hence, u nder P
Θ
, the moment generating fun ction of Y
t
given F
S
t1
is
given by:
M
θ
Y |F
S
t1
(t, z; Θ
t
) =
B
t
+ Θ
t
B
t
+ Θ
t
z
A
t
e
(
r
t
+λ
t
H
t
1
2
H
t
+
A
t
H
t)
z
. (6-35)
From the martingale condition, the risk-neutralized stochastic Esscher param-
eter Θ
t
is given by:
Θ
t
=
e
λ
t
H
t
1
2
H
t
+
A
t
H
t
A
t
1
1
B
t
(6-36)
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 81
Then, we define the parameter
˜
B
t
as follows:
˜
B
t
:= B
t
+ Θ
t
=
e
λ
t
H
t
1
2
H
t
+
A
t
H
t
A
t
1
1
=
K
k=1
e
λ
t
h
kt
1
2
h
kt
+
a
k
h
kt
a
k
1
1
< U
t
, e
k
> , t T \{0} .
Hence, under P
Θ
, Y
t
|F
S
t1
follows a minus shifted gamma distribution with
shape parameter A
t
, scale parameter
˜
B
t
and shifted parameter r
t
λ
t
< H
t
, U
t
> +
1
2
< H
t
, U
t
>
< A, U
t
>< H
t
, U
t
>, where
P (U
t
= e
k
) = p
k
. (6-37)
Let X
q
t
denote a random variable such that X
q
t
|F
S
t1
1
˜
B
t
Ga(A
t
, 1). Then,
h
kt
= α
k0
+ α
k1
X
q
t1
+
A
t1
H
t1
2
+
K
i=1
β
ki1
h
i,t1
,
where k = 1, 2, . . . , K.
From the discussion above we have:
Theorem 41 Let the mode l under P be:
Y
t
= r
t
+ λ
t
< H
t
, U
t
>
1
2
< H
t
, U
t
> +ξ
t
,
ξ
t
|F
S
t1
MSGa(p
1
, . . . , p
K
; h
1t
, . . . , h
Kt
)
h
kt
= α
k0
+ α
k1
ξ
2
t1
+
K
i=1
β
ki1
h
i,t1
.
Then, under the risk neutral measure the model becomes:
Y
t
= r
t
+ λ
t
< H
t
, U
t
>
1
2
< H
t
, U
t
> +
< A, U
t
>< H
t
, U
t
> + X
q
t
,
X
q
t
|F
S
t1
1
˜
B
t
Ga(A
t
, 1)
h
kt
= α
k0
+ α
k1
X
q
t1
+
A
t1
H
t1
2
+
K
i=1
β
ki1
h
i,t1
,
Finally, we note that the scale parameter b does not appear in both the
real-world and the risk-neutral dynamics due to the structure of the mixture
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 82
shifted-gamma model for the innovations.
6.3
Empirical Results and Discussion
In this section we conduct a simulation exercise in order to compare the
option prices induced by assuming different processes for the log-returns of th e
underlying asset.
We consider the two-component mixture GARCH(1, 1) models with a
finite mixture of normal innovations and a finite mixture of shifted gamma
innovations for illustration. We employ the daily close values of S&P500 index
from November 7, 1980, to November 4, 2005, 25 years of data with 6,130
observations. The data were obtained from the database in Yahoo Finance.
We estimate the parameters underlying the option pricing models for empirical
studies using the 25-year S&P500 index data. We assume that the risk-free
interest rate r is zero and that the unit risk premium is a constant λ throughout
this section as in Duan (1995)(17) and Siu et al. (2004)(43).
We shall discuss the estimation procedures and the estimation results for
the two-mixture GARCH models in the sequel. Tong (1990)(45) and Fan and
Yao (2003)(27) mentioned that the conditional maximum likelihood estimation
enjoys some desirable sampling and asymptotic properties. For estimating
the two-component mixture GARCH model with a finite mixture of normal
innovations, we employ the conditional maximum likelihoo d estimation. For
estimating the two-component mixture GARCH mo dels with a finite mixture of
shifted gamma distributions, we use a two-stage estimation procedure adopted
in Siu et al. (2004) (43). In the first-stage, the quasi-maximum likelihood
estimation (QMLE) is used to estimate the mixture GARCH parameters,
namely p
k
, α
k0
, α
k1
, β
k11
and β
k21
, where k = 1, 2. The QMLE is an
approximation to the exact MLE by assuming that the innovations of a time
series model follow a normal distribution even though the “true” innovations
may not be normally distributed. In the QMLE, the exact likelihood is replaced
by the normal likelihood. Franses and van Dijk (2000) (30) mentioned that if
it is not sure whether the specified parametric assumption for the GARCH
innovations is correct, the QMLE can be employed for estimation. Fan and
Yao (2003) (27) pointed out that one does not know the “true” distribution
for the innovations in practice and, hence, the QMLE can provide a practical
way to estimate the parameters in a GARCH model. In fact, the QMLE
method can provide market practitioners with a convenient way to estimate
non-normal GARCH models since many standard computing and statistical
packages have included the conditional MLE for GARCH models with n ormal
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 83
innovations. One undesirable feature of the QMLE is that the standard errors
of the estimates are larger than those obtained by the exact MLE in the
finite sample case. However, the QMLE also enjoys some d esirable asymptotic
properties and the standard errors of the est imates from the QMLE can be
reduced by estimating the model using a large data set. In the second-stage
of our estimation, we adopt the method of moments approach to estimate
the unknown parameters in the finite mixture of shifted gamma distributions.
Tong (1990) (45) mentioned that the method of moments is one of the common
approaches to estimate parametric non-linear time series models. Gerber and
Shiu (1994)(31) employed the method of moments approach to estimate the
unknown parameter in the shifted gamma distribution underlying th eir option
pricing model. Taylor (1986)(44) pioneered the use of the method of moments
approach for estimating stochastic volatility mod els. Here, given the observed
market data of the logarithmic returns {Y
1
, Y
2
, . . . , Y
N
} and the values of
the estimated parameters ˆp
k
, ˆα
k0
, ˆα
k1
,
ˆ
β
k11
and
ˆ
β
k21
(k = 1, 2), we can
employ the three realized time series {ξ
1
, ξ
2
, . . . , ξ
N
}, {h
11
, h
12
, . . . , h
1N
} and
{h
21
, h
22
, . . . , h
2N
} to evaluate the method of moments estimators for the
shifted gamma parameters, namely ˆa
1
and ˆa
2
. By using the method of moments
approach for the mixture GARCH model and matching the theoretical and
the empirical third moments of the shifed-gamma innovations, we provide the
following formula for the method of moments estimators ˆa
1
and ˆa
2
:
ˆa
1
=
1
B+
1p
1
p
1
A B
2
2
and ˆa
2
=
1
B+
p
1
1p
1
A B
2
2
where
B =
1
2
N
t=1
ξ
3
t
N
t=1
h
3/2
t
and A =
1
6
N
t=1
ξ
4
t
N
t=1
h
2
t
1
2
and
ξ
3
t
= p
1
Y
t
λ
h
1,t
1
2
h
1,t

3
+ (1 p
1
)
Y
t
λ
h
2,t
1
2
h
2,t

3
h
3/2
t
= p
1
h
3/2
1,t
+ (1 p
1
) h
3/2
2,t
ξ
4
t
= p
1
Y
t
λ
h
1,t
1
2
h
1,t

4
+ (1 p
1
)
Y
t
λ
h
2,t
1
2
h
2,t

4
h
2
t
= p
1
h
2
1,t
+ (1 p
1
) h
2
2,t
The first table below, displays th e estimation results for the mixture
GARCH parameters p
k
, α
k0
, α
k1
, β
k11
and β
k21
(k = 1, 2) using the QMLE in
the first-stage of the est imation procedure. Both the estimation results based
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 84
on the 25-year S&P 500 index data are presented. The estimation results were
obtained u sing R package “rgenoud” to search for an optimum of the log-
likelihood.
We consider five pricing schemes for options with 90 days to maturity: the
classical Black and Scholes formulae assuming a GBM process and the discrete-
time doubly stochastic Esscher transform method for GARCH and Mixture of
GARCHs (henceforth MGARCH) processes, each one with Normal and shifted-
Gamma innovations(henceforth NMGARCH and SGMGARCH respectively).
In th e Normal and Gamma codes we simulated 10000 times but as in the
Normal case we used the antithetic method we actually have 20000 prices. In
both cases the control variate technique was used.
The five pricing schemes are applied to two artificial series pro duced by a
Mixture of GARCH model with Normal and Shifted-Gamma innovations with
3200 data points, obtained after a warm-up period of 1000 observations. The
MGARCH parameters are given in the table 6.1.
Mixture of GARCHs Parameters
α [1.275531 × 10
4
, 0.433127; 1.965270 × 10
9
, 4.315862 × 10
2
]
β [0.383459, 0.182873; 3.035471 × 10
3
, 0.935921]
λ 7.715479 × 10
2
p [0.068147, 0.9319]
a (Gamma case) [0.0964, 6.0256]
Table 6.1: Parameters for the Mixture of GARCHs. Each line in the matrices
α, β contains the parameters of a regime.
In order to find the Black and Scholes price we only need th e volatility
estimated by the sample variance, 2.0186 × 10
4
, for the Normal data and
6.0211 × 10
5
for the Gamma data. because the drift is not required by the
Black Scholes formulae.
For the estimation of the GARCH parameters we use an iterated two-
stage method. Initially, we suppose h
t
a constant equal to the sample variance.
Then, we estimate the risk premium by weighted least squares(WLS). Next,
we fit a GARCH(1,1) model to the residuals of the WLS by performing a Quasi
Maximum Likelihhod. We iterate these two steps until convergence is attained.
The estimated parameters are shown in table 6.2.
GARCH Parameters in Normal Case
α 5.1325 × 10
6
β 0.9114
λ 0.0673
Risk Premium 0.1343
Table 6.2: Estimated GARCH Parameters in the Normal Case
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 85
We estimated the parameters using the two stage procedure as described
before and then for finding a we used the method of moments as in Siu et
al(2004)(43) to obtain the expression:
ˆa =
2
T
t=1
h
3/2
t
T
t=1
ξ
3
t
2
(6-38)
which led us to the parameters shown in table 6.3.
GARCH Parameters in Shifted-Gamma Case
α 3.7707 × 10
6
β 0.8631
λ 0.0702
Risk Premium 0.0798
a 22.5253
Table 6.3: Estimated GARCH Parameters in the Gamma Case
Some authors (Gerber and Shiu(1994) (31) and Siu et al. (2004) (43)
) have been using shifted-gamma innovations to mo del log-returns in order
to handle the skewness that real financial series usually exhibits as can be
seen in Medeiros and Veiga (2009)(36). However, the skewness of the Gamma
distribution is strictly positive whilst financial time series can present both
signs. In practice, before adopting the shifted-gamma model, one may check
if there is any skewness to be modeled. The sign of the asymmetry in the
data, has to be taken into consideration too. Then, one should check for the
sign of the skewness so as to select an appropriate formulation of the shifted-
gamma innovations. In Section 4, we develop a model to incorporate negative
skewness. The positive case is similar, and for the GARCH case it has already
been documented in Siu et al.(2004) (43) but accounts for positive skewness
only. Here, in the Shifted-Gamma case, we perform an experiment consisting of
using a mixture of positive and negative noises. The fi srt regime, will provide
positive innovations whilst the second negative ones.
The resulting prices are presented in tables that follows. We show both
Call and Put option prices. After each option price table there is another table
with the ratio between the price and the the Black S choles price for each model.
A graph of these comparative tables is also shown.
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 86
Artificial MGARCH Call Prices (Normal data)
K/S
0
BS NMGARCH GARCH-Normal SGMGARCH GARCH-Gamma
0.80 20.2451 20.0396 20.3704 20.6131 19.9422
0.85 15.6879 15.1600 15.8647 16.3017 15.0241
0.90 11.5852 10.5621 11.7831 12.4678 10.3457
0.95 8.1130 6.6096 8.3018 9.2143 6.3225
1.00 5.3731 3.6432 5.5584 6.6011 3.3357
1.05 3.3638 1.7641 3.5860 4.6039 1.5130
1.10 1.9930 0.7591 2.2336 3.1507 0.5988
1.15 1.1203 0.3048 1.3582 2.1351 0.2060
1.20 0.5994 0.1208 0.8043 1.4586 0.0720
Table 6.4: Artificial MGARCH Call Prices, and T=90. The parameters used
are in table 1
Table 6.5: Artificial MGARCH Call Price ratios (Normal data)
K/S
0
BS NMGARCH GARCH-Normal SGMGARCH GARCH-Gamma
0.8 1.0000 0.9898 1.0062 1.0182 0.9850
0.85 1.0000 0.9663 1.0113 1.0391 0.9577
0.9 1.0000 0.9117 1.0171 1.0762 0.8930
0.95 1.0000 0.8147 1.0233 1.1357 0.7793
1 1.0000 0.6780 1.0345 1.2285 0.6208
1.05 1.0000 0.5244 1.0661 1.3687 0.4498
1.1 1.0000 0.3809 1.1207 1.5809 0.3005
1.15 1.0000 0.2721 1.2124 1.9058 0.1839
1.2 1.0000 0.2015 1.3418 2.4334 0.1201
Call Option ratio (Normal data)
Figure 6.1: Graph of the ratio of Call options
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 87
Artificial MGARCH Call Prices (Gamma data)
K/S
0
BS SGMGARCH GARCH-Gamma NMGARCH GARCH-Normal
0.80 20.0023 20.6131 20.0617 20.0396 19.9935
0.85 15.0324 16.3017 15.0553 15.1600 15.0185
0.90 10.2388 12.4678 10.0617 10.5621 10.1955
0.95 6.0304 9.2143 5.3346 6.6096 5.9153
1.00 2.9361 6.6011 1.8991 3.6432 2.7815
1.05 1.1469 4.6039 0.4111 1.7641 1.0286
1.10 0.3553 3.1507 0.0464 0.7591 0.3053
1.15 0.0875 2.1351 0.0042 0.3048 0.0724
1.20 0.0174 1.4586 0.0010 0.1208 0.0157
Table 6.6: Artificial MGARCH Call Prices, and T=90. The parameters used
are in table 1
Table 6.7: Artificial MGARCH Call Price ratios (Gamma data)
K/S
0
BS SG MGARCH GARCH-Gamma NMGARCH GARCH-Normal
0.8 1.0000 1.0305 1.0030 1.0019 0.9996
0.85 1.0000 1.0844 1.0015 1.0085 0.9991
0.9 1.0000 1.2177 0.9827 1.0316 0.9958
0.95 1.0000 1.5280 0.8846 1.0960 0.9809
1 1.0000 2.2483 0.6468 1.2408 0.9473
1.05 1.0000 4.0142 0.3584 1.5381 0.8969
1.1 1.0000 8.8677 0.1306 2.1365 0.8593
1.15 1.0000 24.4011 0.0480 3.4834 0.8274
1.2 1.0000 83.8276 0.0575 6.9425 0.9023
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 88
Call Option ratio (Gamma data)
Figure 6.2: Graph of the ratio of Call options
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 89
Artificial MGARCH Put Prices (Normal data)
K/S
0
BS NMGARCH GARCH-Normal SGMGARCH GARCH-Gamma
0.80 0.2451 0.0487 0.3486 0.4922 0.0259
0.85 0.6879 0.1752 0.8335 1.0361 0.0844
0.90 1.5852 0.5728 1.7654 2.0291 0.3973
0.95 3.1130 1.5923 3.3021 3.6551 1.3615
1.00 5.3731 3.6200 5.5684 5.9864 3.3947
1.05 8.3638 6.7476 8.5754 8.9910 6.6014
1.10 11.9930 10.7743 12.2063 12.5913 10.7275
1.15 16.1203 15.3253 16.3190 16.6484 15.3697
1.20 20.5994 20.1390 20.7742 21.0324 20.2601
Table 6.8: Artificial MGARCH Put Prices, and T=90. The parameters used
are in table 1
Table 6.9: Artificial MGARCH Put Price ratios (Normal data)
K/S
0
BS NMGARCH GARCH-Normal SGMGARCH GARCH-Gamma
0.8 1.0000 0.1987 1.4223 2.0082 0.1057
0.85 1.0000 0.2547 1.2117 1.5062 0.1227
0.9 1.0000 0.3613 1.1137 1.2800 0.2506
0.95 1.0000 0.5115 1.0607 1.1741 0.4374
1 1.0000 0.6737 1.0363 1.1141 0.6318
1.05 1.0000 0.8068 1.0253 1.0750 0.7893
1.1 1.0000 0.8984 1.0178 1.0499 0.8945
1.15 1.0000 0.9507 1.0123 1.0328 0.9534
1.2 1.0000 0.9776 1.0085 1.0210 0.9835
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 90
Put Option ratio (Normal data)
Figure 6.3: Graph of the ratio of Put Options
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 91
Artificial MGARCH Put Prices (Gamma data)
K/S
0
BS SGMGARCH GARCH-Gamma NMGARCH GARCH-Normal
0.80 0.0023 0.4922 0.0097 0.0487 0.0030
0.85 0.0324 1.0361 0.0122 0.1752 0.0305
0.90 0.2388 2.0291 0.0489 0.5728 0.2198
0.95 1.0304 3.6551 0.4256 1.5923 0.9632
1.00 2.9361 5.9864 2.0676 3.6200 2.8462
1.05 6.1469 8.9910 5.5272 6.7476 6.0732
1.10 10.3553 12.5913 10.1236 10.7743 10.3267
1.15 15.0875 16.6484 15.0670 15.3253 15.0818
1.20 20.0174 21.0324 20.0585 20.1390 20.0158
Table 6.10: Artificial MGARCH Put Prices, and T=90. The parameters used
are in table 1
Table 6.11: Artificial MGARCH Put Price ratios (Gamma data)
K/S
0
BS SG MGARCH GARCH-Gamma NMGARCH GARCH-Normal
0.8 1.0000 214.0000 4.2174 21.1739 1.3043
0.85 1.0000 31.9784 0.3765 5.4074 0.9414
0.9 1.0000 8.4971 0.2048 2.3987 0.9204
0.95 1.0000 3.5473 0.4130 1.5453 0.9348
1 1.0000 2.0389 0.7042 1.2329 0.9694
1.05 1.0000 1.4627 0.8992 1.0977 0.9880
1.1 1.0000 1.2159 0.9776 1.0405 0.9972
1.15 1.0000 1.1035 0.9986 1.0158 0.9996
1.2 1.0000 1.0507 1.0021 1.0061 0.9999
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 92
Put Option ratios (Gamma data)
Figure 6.4: Graph of the ratio of Put options
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 93
We can see that Calls and Puts have a different behavior. In tables 6.9 and
6.11, the put option price ratios have their largest values deep in the money.
The more pronounced effect is in the SGMGARCH scheme. The values are
larger than those in other schemes. Tables 6.5 and 6.7, on the other hand,
show their largest values deep out the money. The more pronounced effect is
again in the SGMGARCH scheme. The values of the SGMGARCH scheme are
much more drastic when the data is generated by Shifted-Gamma noises than
with Normal noises as we can see in the figures. The second largest values
alternates between the NMGARCH scheme for Shift-Gamma d ata and the
GARCH-Normal for Normal data. The smallest values appears in the GARCH-
Gamma scheme.
To illustrate the changes in the option prices when we change the
measures, we simulated prices under both the physical and risk neutral
measures in all schemes. Then we checked for the proportions of scenarios
where the options were exercised, which then give an estimate of the real-
world probability of exercising an option. We chose S
0
= 100 and K = 100 to
perform this exercise. We notice that in all schemes presented in table 6.12,
the prices under the risk neutral measure are less likely to exceed the strike
price than the prices under the physical measure. Note also that the difference
is more pronounced than in the FC-GARCH schemes in chapter 5.
Table 6.12: Average rate of exercising
Model/rate Risk Neutral Measure Physical Measure
NMGARCH 0.4824 0.7720
SGMGARCH 0.4665 0.7620
Gamma GARCH 0.4832 0.7652
Normal Garch 0.4692 0.8872
GARCH-Gamma with Normal data 0.4827 0.8813
GARCH-Normal with Gamma data 0.4856 0.7639
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 94
6.4
Sensitivity Analysis
Now we are going to check how the option prices change when some
of the parameters are disturbed. We performed simulations imposing a small
variation around the values of the parameters.
Proceeding with this exercise we capture the importance of each param-
eter in the option prices. We perform this analysis with the MGARCH models
having Normal and Shifted-Gamma innovations.
6.4.1
Normal innovations
If we increase the value of α
12
, by steps of 0.05 the option price does not
change significantly. We made 5 variations in steps of 0.01 for α
22
and as we
increase its value, the option value also increases.
We made β
11
with increments of 0.05, and for β
21
in steps of 0.001 and
the option price slightly increased. For β
12
the effect is not clear. On the other
hand for the β
22
with 0.05 increments, we can clearly see the increase effect on
option prices.
The p parameter increases the value of the option as is shown in figure
11. We performed 5 varations from 0.0081 to 0.1281 in steps of 0.03.
The risk premium didn’t show any clear effect. The graphics shows five
variations of the risk premium with steps of 0.05 and 0.1. It seems having an
increasing trend, but this increase is very slightly even performing steps of 0.1.
6.4.2
Shifted Gamma innovations
If we increase the value of α
12
and α
22
, by steps of 0.05 and 0.01
respectively the option price does not have a monotonic pattern.
We made for β
11
increments of 0.05, and the option price does not have
a monotonic pattern. For β
12
, β
21
and β
22
the effect is not clear too.
We performed 5 varations of the p parameter from 0.0081 to 0.1281 in
steps of 0.03. No clear effect was noticed.
The a
1
parameter doesn’t have a clear effect on the option prices. a
1
was varied swith increments of 0.01 and 0.03. In any of the cases there was
a monotonic pattern. a
2
started from its value having increments of 0.03 and
also varied but without a monotonic clear effect.
The risk premium has no clear monotonic pattern influence on the option
prices. We simulated with increments of 0.03 and also steps of 0.1,
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 95
In summary, in the Gamma case, maybe due to the mixture of signs
in the noises, even when the prices varied significantly, no monotonic pattern
could be detected.
6.5
Summary and discussion
In this paper we adopted the discrete-time doubly stochastic Esscher
transform to find a pricing kernel for the MGARCH models with two dif-
ferent p arametric distributions for innovations, the Normal and the shifted-
Gamma cases. We also performed simulations and showed tables comparing
the Black Scholes prices and the GARCH prices to our simulation results of the
MGARCH models as well as we performed a sensitivity analysis to understand
how changes in some parameters affect the option valuation results.
In the tables and graphs of section 5, we noticed large values for the
SGMGARCH scheme and small values for the GARCH schemes. In the
sensitivity analysis, we noticed that the GARCH parameters β
22
and p were
the most sensitive to perturbations of these model parameters in the Normal
case, while the other parameters and the risk premium have little or no impact
on option prices. In the Gamma case, maybe due to the mixture of signs in the
noises, we could not measure the importance of any of the parameters. Even
when the prices varied significantly, no monotonic pattern could be detected.
The MGARCH models can capture features that some other models
cannot like the high kurtosis, so the option prices are more precise if calculated
in the way we did in this paper. Here we performed simulations with a mixture
of 2 regimes but the model can mimic an economy with many regimes.
7
Future works and finak remarks
This work concerned option pricing of two special GARCH models, viz
the FC-GARCH and the Mixture of GARCHs. We found the theoretical risk
neutral version of those models and also simulated the option prices under
different schemes. We also discuss the possibility of using negative noise to the
Shifted-Gamma case and perform the calculations in both models as well as
we performed simulation experiments. Then we made some sensibility analysis
to the paramters. The only theoretical contributions we achieve in these two
papers are the four theorems relating the econometric models in the original
P measure and in the risk neutral measure, viz., Theorems 35, 36, 41 and 42
showed in chapters 5 and 6.
We intend to continue in this direction, studying pricing methods and
applying them in more complex models and more sofisticated kind of contracts
so that practioners have a variety of possibilities of models to choose from.
According to our results, if the d ata comes from one of those two models
proposed, there is a significant difference among the option prices in the
different schemes. It shows that it is worth pricing using a reasonable model
and with the proper innovation distribution in order to obtain more precise
option prices.
We tried to extend the methodology in Siu et al.(43) to characteristic
functions, but the imaginary i brought us concern when dealing with the
martingale condition. It would be nice if we could find a way in solving this
issue and generalize the methodology.
Another possible improvement is to create a trading scheme to compare
our results to the obtained by real options data. In such a paper we intend
to compare real data prices with both the FC-GARCH and the Mixture of
GARCHs option prices.
Bibliography
[1] ALEXANDER, C.; LAZAR, E. Normal mixture garch(1,1): applica-
tions to foreign exchange markets. Journal of Applied Econometrics,
21, 2006.
[2] BACK, K.; PLISKA, S. R. On the fundamental theorem of asset
pricing with an infinite state space. Journal of Mathematical
Economics, 20:1–18, 1991.
[3] BARONE-ADESI, G.; ENGLE, R. ; MANCINI, L. A garch option pric-
ing model with filtered historical simulation. Review of Financial
Studies, 21, 2008.
[4] BILLINGSLEY. Probability and Measure. Wiley-Interscience, New
York, 1995.
[5] BINGHAM, N. H.; KIESEL, R. Risk-Neutral Valuation: Pricing and
Hedging of Financial Derivatives. Springer, 2004.
[6] BLACK, F.; SCHOLES, M. The pricing of options and corporate
liabilities. Journal of Political Economy, 81:637–659, 1973.
[7] BOLLERSLEV, T. Generalized autoregressive conditional het-
eroskedasticity. Journal of Econometrics, 31:307–327, 1986.
[8] BOLLERSLEV, T.; CHOU, R. Y. ; KRONER, K. F. Arch modeling in
finance: A selective review of the theory and empirical evidence.
Journal of Econometrics, 3:5–59, 1992.
[9] B
¨
UHLMANN, H.; DELBAEN, F.; EMBRECHTS, P. ; SHIRYAEV, A. N.
No-arbitrage, change of measure and conditional esscher trans-
forms. CWI Quarterly, 9, 1996.
[10] B
¨
UHLMANN, H.; DELBAEN, F.; EMBRECHTS, P. ; SHIRYAEV, A. N.
On esscher transforms in discrete finance models. ASTIN Bulletin,
28, 1998.
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 98
[11] CHAN, T.; VAN DER HOEK, J. Pricing and hedging contingent
claims in incomplete markets: Discrete time models. Working
Paper, Department of Actuarial Mathematics and Statistics, Heriot-Watt
University,United Kingdom, 300:463–520, 2003.
[12] COX, J. C.; ROSS, S. A. ; RUBINSTEIN, M. Option pricing: A
simplified approach. Journal of Financial Economics, 7:229–263, 1979.
[13] DAVIS, M. H. A. A general option pricing formula. Preprint,
Imperial College, 1994.
[14] DAVIS, M. H. A. Option pricing in incomplete markets. Mathe-
matics of Derivative Securities, 1997.
[15] DELBAEN, F.; SCHACHERMAYER, W. A general version of funda-
mental theorem of asset pricing. Mathematische Annalen, 300:463–
520, 1994.
[16] DING, Z.; GRANGER, C. ; ENGLE, R. A long memory property
of stock market returns and a new model. Journal of Empirical
Finance, 1:83–106, 1993.
[17] DUAN, J.-C. The garch option pricing model. Mathematical Finance,
5:13–32, 1995.
[18] DUAN, J.-C. Augmented garch(p,q) process and its diffusion
limit. Journal of Econometrics, 79:97–127, 1997.
[19] DUAN, J.-C.; POPOVA, I. ; RITCHKEN, P. Option pricing under
regime switching. Quantitative Finance, 2:116–132, 2002.
[20] DYBVIG, P. H.; ROSS, S. A. Arbitrage. the New Palsgrave: A dictionary
of Economics, 1:100–106, 1987.
[21] ELLIOTT, R. Mathematics of Financial Markets. Springer, New
York, 2004.
[22] ELLIOTT, R. . J.; CHAN, L. ; SIU, T. K. Option pricing and esscher
transform under regime switching. Annals of Finance, 1, 2004.
[23] ELLIOTT, R. J.; SIU, T. K. ; CHAN, L. Option pricing for garch
models with markov switching. International Journal of Theoretical
and Applied Finance (IJTAF), 9, 2006.
[24] EMBRECHTS, P. Actuarial versus financial pricing of insurance.
Journal of Financial Economics, 1, 2000.
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 99
[25] ESSCHER, F. On the probability function in the collective theory
of risk. Skandinavisk Aktuarietidskrift, 15:175–195, 1932.
[26] EVANS, L. C. An introduction to stochastic differential equations.
[27] FAN, J.; YAO, Q. Nonlinear Time Series: Nonparametric and
Parametric Models. Springer-Verlag, New York, 2003.
[28] F
¨
OLLMER, H.; SCHWEIZER, M. Hedging of contingent claims
under incomplete information. Applied Stochastic Analysis, p. 389–
414, 1991.
[29] F
¨
OLLMER, H.; SONDERMANN, D. Hedging of contingent claims
under incomplete information. Contributions to Mathematical Eco-
nomics., p. 205–223, 1986.
[30] FRANSES, P. H.; VAN DIJK, D. Non-linear Time Series Models in
Empirical Finance. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 2000.
[31] GERBER, H. U.; SHIU, E. S. W. Option pricing by esscher trans-
forms (with discussions). Transactions of the Society of Actuaries,
46:99–191, 1994.
[32] HAAS, M.; MITTNIK, S. ; PAOLELLA, M. Mixed normal conditional
heteroskedasticity. Centre for Financial Studies, 10, 2002.
[33] HARRISON, J. M.; KREPS, D. M. Martingales and arbitrage in
multiperiod securities markets. Journal of Economic Theory, 20:381–
408, 1979.
[34] HARRISON, J. M.; PLISKA, S. R. Martingales and stochastic
integrals in the theory of continuous trading. Stochastic Processes
and Their Applications, 11:215–280, 1981.
[35] HARRISON, J. M.; PLISKA, S. R. A stochastic calculus model of
continuous trading: Complete markets. Stochastic Processes and
Their Applications, 15:313–316, 1983.
[36] MEDEIROS, M. C.; VEIGA, A. Modeling multiple regimes in finan-
cial volatility with a flexible coefficient garch model. Econometric
Theory, 2008.
[37] MERTON, R. C. The theory of rational option pricing. Bell Journal
of Economics and Management Science, 4:141–183, 1973.
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 100
[38] OKSENDAL, B. Stochastic Differential Equations, An introduc-
tion with Applications. Springer, 2005.
[39] SCHACHERMAYER, W. A hilbert space proof of the fundamen-
tal theorem of asset pricing in finite discrete time. Insurance:
Mathematics and Economics, 11:249–257, 1992.
[40] SCHWEIZER, M. Approximation pricing and the variance-
optimal martingale measure. Annals of Probability, 24:206–236, 1991.
[41] SHREVE. Stochastic Calculus for Finance II: Continuous-Time
Models volume 2. Springer, New York, 2004.
[42] SIU, T. K.; TONG, H. ; YANG, H. Bayesian risk measures f or deriva-
tives via random esscher transform. North American Actuarial Jour-
nal, 5, 2001.
[43] SIU, T. K.; TONG, H. ; YANG, H. On pricing derivatives under
garch models: A dynamic gerber-shiu approach. North American
Actuarial Journal, 8, 2004.
[44] TAYLOR, S. J. Modelling Financial Time Series. John Wiley &
Sons, New York, 1992.
[45] TONG, H. Nonlinear Time Series Analysis: A Dynamical Ap-
proach. Oxford University Press, Oxford, 1990.
[46] YAO, Y. State price density, esscher transforms, and pricing
options on stocks, bonds, and foreign exchange rates. North
American Actuarial Journal, 5, 2001.
A
Appendix
Definition 42 (Conditional Expectation). The conditional expectati on of a
nonnegative random variable ξ with respect to the σ-algebra G is a nonnegative
extended random variable, denoted by E[ξ|G] or E[ξ|G](ω), such that
(a) E[ξ|G] is G-measurable;
(b) For every A G,
A
ξdP =
A
E[ξ|G]dP. (A-1)
Theorem 43 Let G, H be σ-algebras such that G H. Then
E[X|G] = E[E[X|H]|G] (A-2)
Proof : If G G then G H and therefore
G
E[X|H]dP =
G
XdP. (A-3)
Hence
E[E[X|H]|G] = E[X|G]. (A-4)
Corollary 44 (Iterated expectations)
E[E[X|H]] = E[X]. (A-5)
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 102
Proof : In particular take G = and we will have
E[X|H]dP =
XdP (A-6)
Theorem 45 (Baye’s rule) Let µ and ν be two probability measures on a
measurable space (Ω, G) such that
(ω) = f (ω)(ω)
for some f L
1
(µ). Let X be a random variable on (Ω, G) such that
E
ν
[|X|] =
|X(ω)|f(ω)(ω) < (X is ν integrable) (A-7)
Let H be a σ-algebra, H G. Then,
E
ν
[X|H ].E
µ
[f|H] = E
µ
[fX|H] a.s.
or
E
ν
[X|H ] =
E
µ
[fX|H]
E
µ
[f|H]
a.s. (A-8)
Proof : By the definition of conditional expectation we have that if H H
then
H
E
ν
[X|H ]f =
H
E
ν
[X|H ] =
H
X (A-9)
=
H
Xf =
H
E
µ
[fX|H]dµ. (A-10)
On the other hand, by iterated expectations we have
H
E
ν
[X|H ]f = E
µ
[E
ν
[X|H ]f χ
H
] (A-11)
= E
µ
[E
µ
[E
ν
[X|H ]f χ
H
|H]] (A-12)
= E
µ
[χ
H
E
ν
[X|H ]E
µ
[f|H]] (A-13)
=
H
E
ν
[X|H ]E
µ
[f|H] (A-14)
Combining (3.3) and (3.8) we get
H
E
ν
[X|H ]E
µ
[f|H] =
H
E
µ
[fX|H] (A-15)
Risk Neutral Option Pricing under some special GARCH models 103
Since this holds for all H H,
E
ν
[X|H ]E
µ
[f|H] = E
µ
[fX|H] a.s. (A-16)
Livros Grátis
( http://www.livrosgratis.com.br )
Milhares de Livros para Download:
Baixar livros de Administração
Baixar livros de Agronomia
Baixar livros de Arquitetura
Baixar livros de Artes
Baixar livros de Astronomia
Baixar livros de Biologia Geral
Baixar livros de Ciência da Computação
Baixar livros de Ciência da Informação
Baixar livros de Ciência Política
Baixar livros de Ciências da Saúde
Baixar livros de Comunicação
Baixar livros do Conselho Nacional de Educação - CNE
Baixar livros de Defesa civil
Baixar livros de Direito
Baixar livros de Direitos humanos
Baixar livros de Economia
Baixar livros de Economia Doméstica
Baixar livros de Educação
Baixar livros de Educação - Trânsito
Baixar livros de Educação Física
Baixar livros de Engenharia Aeroespacial
Baixar livros de Farmácia
Baixar livros de Filosofia
Baixar livros de Física
Baixar livros de Geociências
Baixar livros de Geografia
Baixar livros de História
Baixar livros de Línguas
Baixar livros de Literatura
Baixar livros de Literatura de Cordel
Baixar livros de Literatura Infantil
Baixar livros de Matemática
Baixar livros de Medicina
Baixar livros de Medicina Veterinária
Baixar livros de Meio Ambiente
Baixar livros de Meteorologia
Baixar Monografias e TCC
Baixar livros Multidisciplinar
Baixar livros de Música
Baixar livros de Psicologia
Baixar livros de Química
Baixar livros de Saúde Coletiva
Baixar livros de Serviço Social
Baixar livros de Sociologia
Baixar livros de Teologia
Baixar livros de Trabalho
Baixar livros de Turismo