Download PDF
ads:
IMPA
Doctor of Philosophy Dissertation
Price Discrimination without the
Single-Crossing
by
Sergei Vieira Silva
Supervisor: Alo´ısio Araujo Co-Supervisor: Humberto Moreira
Rio de Janeiro, 2008
ads:
Livros Grátis
http://www.livrosgratis.com.br
Milhares de livros grátis para download.
ads:
Contents
Contents i
1 Nonlinear Pricing 3
1.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3
1.2 Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4
1.3 Unidimensional Screening . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6
1.3.1 Unidimensional Screening under the SMC . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6
1.3.2 Unidimensional Screening without the SMC . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11
1.4 Multidimensional Screening . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13
1.5 Final Remarks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15
2 Nonlineard Pricing Without a Single-Crossing Tariff 21
2.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21
2.2 Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23
2.2.1 The Model Setup . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24
2.3 Incentive Compatibility Conditions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26
2.4 The Monopolist’s Problem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28
2.4.1 Single-Crossing Tariff . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29
2.4.2 Non Single-Crossing Tariff . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32
2.5 An Example . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35
2.6 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39
3 Bidimensional Screening 47
i
ii CONTENTS
3.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47
3.2 Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48
3.3 Discrete-Continuous Type . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49
3.3.1 Optimality Conditions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51
3.3.2 An Example . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54
3.4 Bicontinuous Type . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 56
3.4.1 Examples . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61
3.5 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 64
Bibliography 69
Acknowledgements
Em primeiro lugar, eu gostaria de agradecer a meus pais pela forma¸ao, pelo apoio e pelo
incentivo em minhas escolhas e decis˜oes. Estendo o agradecimento a toda a minha fam´ılia que
sempre foi muito presente e importante em minha vida.
Agrade¸co o Professor Alo´ısio Araujo, que aceitou a ´ardua tarefa de me orientar, e com o
qual tive o privil´egio de ter excelentes conversas e discuss˜oes sobre os mais variados assuntos,
inclusive sobre economia matem´atica. Agrade¸co tamb´em o Professor Humberto Moreira, que
foi meu co-orientador e meu primeiro professor no curso de ver˜ao em Economia Matem´atica no
IMPA, pela dedica¸ao e energia que empenhou nesse projeto.
Gostaria tamb´em de agradecer ao IMPA que me proporcionou um excelente ambiente
acadˆemico, uma estrutura impec´avel e de bom gosto al´em de todo o apoio necess´ario para
realizar pesquisa. Agrade¸co a todos os seus professores com destaque `aqueles que me minis-
traram cursos e em especial ao saudoso Professor Carlos Isnard. Agrade¸co tamb´em a todos os
funcion´arios do IMPA, muito prestativos e competentes, essenciais no bom funcionamento de
toda a estrutura do instituto.
Gostaria de agradecer aos colegas do IMPA pela companhia, entusiasmo e por compartil-
harem comigo o gosto pela matem´atica.
Por fim gostaria de agradecer ao CNPq, que forneceu o apoio financeiro sem o qual essa
tarefa seria muito mais dif´ıcil.
1
Chapter 1
Nonlinear Pricing
1.1 Introduction
Nonlinear pricing schemes are widely used in many markets such as mobile telephony, fixed
telephony, electricity and gas supply, postal services, air and railroad transport, cable TV and
internet, hardware and software, cars. For this reason, it has attracted a lot of attention from
both theoretical and applied economists.
Our research is about the design of an optimal nonlinear pricing mechanism for a monopolist
who has incomplete information about the characteristics of the customers. Although there are
theoretical results available in the literature, some of them are valid only under restrictive
conditions, for instance the Spence and Mirrlees condition (SMC). Our goal is to take some
steps in relaxing some of these conditions.
For a deeper understanding of these problems, however, much more have to be done. We
believe that a more general treatment requires new mathematical tools which are still to be
developed. This seems to be especially true when we are in a multidimensional context.
In this chapter we make a brief survey of the literature and the objective is to place our
research in the proper context. It is organized as follows. In Section 2 we present the model
we are using. Then, in Section 3 we study the problem in a one-dimensional context. First
we consider it under the Spence and Mirrlees condition (SMC), and we describe three different
approaches for solving it. Then we present a model relaxing the SMC. In Section 4 we present
3
4 CHAPTER 1. NONLINEAR PRICING
some results from the literature of multidimensional screening problems. Finally, in Section 5
we present the directions undertaken by our research.
1.2 Model
The customer has a quasi-linear utility function depending on his type θ Θ R
N
, which is
private information:
V (q, t, θ) = v(q, θ) t,
where q Q R
M
+
is the customer’s decision and t is the monetary transference.
The firm is a profit-maximizing monopolist producing any q Q R
M
+
and incurring in
a cost C(q). It does not observe θ and has a prior distribution P over Θ. His revenue is also
quasi-linear:
Π(q, t) = t C(q).
We formulate the monopolist’s problem as choosing a decision function q : Θ Q and a
monetary transfer t : Θ R that solves:
max
{q(·),t(·)}
Θ
{t(θ) C(q(θ))}dP (θ), (Π)
subject to the individual rationality constraints:
v(q(θ), θ) t(θ) 0 θ Θ, (IR)
and the incentive compatibility constraints:
θ arg max
θ
Θ
{v(q(θ
), θ) t(θ
)}, θ Θ. (IC)
The allocation rule represented by the pair (q, t) is called a contract. We say that a contract
(q, t) is incentive compatible when it satisfies the IC constraints. The decision function q is
implementable if there exists a monetary transfer t such that (q, t) is incentive compatible.
Hammond [11] and Guesnerie [9] have showed that a contract is incentive compatible if and
only if there exists a nonlinear tariff T : Q R such that:
q(θ) arg max
qQ
{v(q, θ) T (q)}, θ Θ.
1.2. MODEL 5
This is known as the ‘Taxation Principle’ and it easily follows from the fact that t depends on
θ only through the decision q(θ).
One of the greatest difficulties related to the monopolist’s problem is how to deal with the IC
constraints. In general, the binding IC constraints may be determined only endogenously which
makes it a rather difficult task. There are some technical results about the characterization of
incentive compatible decisions in Rochet [25] which uses the concept of cyclical monotonicity
and Carlier [6] who uses abstract convexity concepts. Without imposing further structure on
the utility function v(q, θ), however, no much can be said about implementability.
In the unidimensional (N=M=1) case, for instance, there is a condition that provides a very
simple characterization of implementable decisions:
Definition 1. (The Spence and Mirrlees Condition.) Suppose that v : Q × Θ R is
twice differentiable. Then v satisfies SMC if and only if only one of the two possibilities below
is valid:
v
qθ
> 0 on Q × Θ (CS
+
)
v
qθ
< 0 on Q × Θ (CS
).
(SMC)
The SMC, also known as the single-crossing condition, is an standard assumption in the
literature of monopolistic screening. Under the SMC a decision function is implementable if and
only if it is monotonic.
1
The monotonicity of the decision function is related to the first- and
second-order conditions of the customer’s maximization problem (IC). Consequently, under the
SMC the first- and second-order conditions are necessary and sufficient for implementability.
2
In the multidimensional case, when the monopolist sells a single good and the customer has
multidimensional type, there is the generalized single-crossing condition defined by McAfee and
McMillan [17]:
Definition 2. (The Generalized Single-Crossing Condition.) Suppose that v : Q×Θ R
is twice differentiable. Then v satisfies the generalized single-crossing property if for all q, θ
1
and θ
0
there exists λ(q, θ
1
, θ
0
) > 0 such that:
v
q
(q, θ
1
) v
q
(q, θ
0
) = λ
θ
v
q
(q, θ
0
) · (θ
1
θ
0
). (GSC)
1
See Rochet [25].
2
See Guesnerie and Laffont [10].
6 CHAPTER 1. NONLINEAR PRICING
Under this condition, we also have that the first- and second-order conditions are necessary
and sufficient for implementability. This condition is too restrictive as it imposes that the set
of types who choose the same allocation is a linear subspace. In the third chapter, we find an
example of optimal contract that does not satisfy the GSC.
1.3 Unidimensional Screening
In this section we present some methods for solving the monopolist’s problem (Π) under the
assumption of a single characteristic (N = 1) and a single instrument (M = 1). The type space
is Θ = [θ, θ]. The common strategy for all these methods is to derive a relaxed problem for the
monopolist. Then, if we find a solution for the relaxed problem that satisfies the constraints of
the original problem, then this solution is also a solution for the original problem.
1.3.1 Unidimensional Screening under the SMC
We present three approaches for monopolist’s problem under the (SMC). We assume the fol-
lowing conditions:
H1. v(q, θ) C
3
,
H2. v
qq
< 0 and v
θ
> 0,
3
H3. v
q
2
θ
> 0 and v
qθ
2
> 0,
H4. C(0) = 0, C
(q) > 0 and C

(q) < 0.
We also assume the (CS
+
). In this case, a decision q is implementable if and only if it is
increasing.
4
Mussa and Rosen’s approach:
One of the seminal papers in the field of nonlinear pricing is by Mussa and Rosen [20].
They study monopoly pricing problems involving a quality-differentiated spectrum of goods.
We are going to reproduce their derivation for the monopolist’s problem. Suppose that (q, t) is
incentive compatible and define the informational rent by:
V (θ) = v(q(θ), θ) t(θ).
3
When the signal of v
θ
is not constant and/or when the individual rationality (IR) constraints are type
dependent, we have countervailing incentive problem. This problem was studied by Jullien [13]. In Araujo and
Moreira [1] there is a discussion about the possibility of countervailing incentives due to the absence of the SMC.
4
The term increasing refers to both weakly and strictly increasing functions.
1.3. UNIDIMENSIONAL SCREENING 7
If we plug V into the monopolist’s objective function of problem (Π), we get:
θ
θ
{v(q(θ), θ) C(q(θ)) V (θ)}. (1.1)
By the envelope theorem (see Milgrom and Segal [18]), we have that:
V
(θ) = v
θ
(q(θ), θ).
Using assumption H2 and the fundamental theorem of calculus, we get:
5
V (θ) =
θ
θ
v
θ
(q(θ), s)ds. (1.2)
Plugging equation (1.2) into equation (1.1) and using an integration by parts we finally get:
θ
θ
{v(q(θ), θ) C(q(θ)) +
P (θ) 1
p(θ)
v
θ
(q(θ), θ)}p(θ)dθ. (1.3)
Let us define:
f(q, θ) = v(q(θ), θ) C(q(θ)) +
P (θ) 1
p(θ)
v
θ
(q(θ), θ). (1.4)
Dropping the global IC constraints, we can define a relaxed version of the monopolist’s problem:
max
{q(·)}
θ
θ
f(q(θ), θ)p(θ)dθ.
MR
)
This is a classical problem in the calculus of variations.
6
The Euler’s equation gives the necessary
condition for an extremum of problem (Π
MR
):
f
q
(q, θ) = 0. (1.5)
Let us denote the solution of equation (1.5) by q
MR
(θ). If q
MR
(θ) is increasing, then it is the
solution of the monopolist’s problem (Π). If q
MR
(θ) is not increasing, then we must use the
ironing procedure on q
MR
(θ) to find the solution.
In the Figure 1.1 we illustrate the ironing procedure. Notice that q
MR
(θ) is decreasing in
the interval [θ
M
, θ
m
]. The procedure consists in optimally choosing an interval I = [θ
1
, θ
2
]
such that the optimal decision q
(θ) = q
b
, θ I. In this solution, we have a bunching of
5
By assumption H2, V is increasing and we can set V (θ) = 0, eliminating the IR constraints.
6
We suggest Petrov [22] as a basic reference for calculus of variations and optimal control.
8 CHAPTER 1. NONLINEAR PRICING
θ
θ
θ
θ
1
θ
2
q
b
θ
M
θ
m
q
q
(θ )
q
MR
(θ )
Figure 1.1: The ironing procedure.
customers choosing the same decision q
b
. Using optimal control, the optimal bunching can be
characterized by:
θ
2
θ
1
f
q
(q
b
, θ)p(θ) = 0.
Goldman, Leland and Sibley’s approach:
The second approach we are going to present was introduced by Goldman, Leland and
Sibley [8]. They study nonlinear pricing through quantity discounts. Remember that under the
(CS
+
), an incentive compatible decision q must be increasing so we can define its pseudo-inverse
ψ(q). It is called the type assignment function, as it assigns quantities q to the type θ = ψ(q)
choosing q. Notice that ψ(q) must be also increasing. In this approach, the monopolist’s
objective function will depend on ψ(q). Then the monopolist has to optimally choose ψ(q).
Consider an incentive compatible contract (q, t). Using the taxation principle, we have that
T (q(θ)) = t(θ). Using the fundamental theorem of calculus, and supposing that T (0) = C(0) =
0,
7
we can write the monopolist’s objective function of problem (Π) as:
θ
θ
{T (q(θ)) C(q(θ))}p(θ) =
θ
θ
q(θ)
0
{T
(q) C
(q)}p(θ)dq,
and using Fubinis’ theorem and the customer’s first-order condition:
θ
θ
q(θ)
0
{T
(q) C
(q)}p(θ)dq =
q
0
θ
ψ(q)
{v
q
(q, ψ(q)) C
(q)}p(θ)dq.
Let us define:
F (q, ψ) =
θ
ψ
{v
q
(q, ψ) C
(q)}p(θ).
7
This is a simplifying hypothesis.
1.3. UNIDIMENSIONAL SCREENING 9
Dropping the global IC constraints, now related to the monotonicity of the type assignment
function ψ(q), we can define a relaxed version of the monopolist’s problem:
max
{ψ(·)}
q
0
F (q, ψ(q))dq.
GR
)
The Euler’s equation for the problem (Π
GR
) is given by:
F
ψ
(q, ψ(q)) = 0. (1.6)
Let us denote by ψ
GR
(q) the solution of equation (1.6). If ψ
GR
(q) is increasing, then it is
the solution of the monopolist’s problem (Π). If ψ
GR
(q) is not increasing, then the bunching
condition for the decision function q translates into an optimal jump condition for the optimal
type assignment function ψ
:
8
F (q
b
, ψ
(q
b
+)) = F (q
b
, ψ
(q
b
)) = max
{θ[θ]}
F (q
b
, θ).
q
q
ψ
(q
b
+)
ψ
(q
b
)
q
b
θ
θ
Figure 1.2: The optimal jump condition.
We will see that this approach provides a very convenient way to deal with the monopolist’s
problem without the SMC. The difference is that we will have two type assignment functions,
because the decision functions may not be monotonic.
Demand Profile approach:
The demand profile approach was introduced by Brown and Sibley [5]. The derivation we
do here, however, can be found in Wilson [29], which provides a detailed description of this
8
This result was established by Nˆldeke and Samuelson [21].
10 CHAPTER 1. NONLINEAR PRICING
approach, with many examples and applications to nonlinear pricing via quantity discounts.
This approach results in an optimization problem depending on the marginal tariff T
(q).
The demand profile is a function representing the fraction of customers purchasing at least
q units when the monopolist chooses the tariff T :
N(T (·), q) = Pr
θ [θ, θ]|∃x arg max
x0
{v(x, θ) T (x)} and x q
.
In general N(T (·), q) may depend on the entire tariff T (·) and this could make the problem
rather complicated. However, it is possible to simplify the demand profile by assuming an
aditional condition.
Definition 3. (Single-Crossing Tariff.)
9
A tariff is said to be single-crossing at q if, for
any θ such that v
q
(q, θ) T
(q), v
q
(q
, θ) T
(q
) for q
q. If T (q) is single-crossing for all
q, we term it a single-crossing tariff.
When we have a single-crossing tariff, the demand profile depends only on the marginal
tariff T
(q). In this case it is denoted by N(T
(q), q) and we have that:
N(T
(q), q) = Pr
θ Θ|v
q
(q, θ) T
(q)
.
The derivation of the monopolist’s optimization problem resembles the previous one from Gold-
man, Leland and Sibley. Using the fundamental theorem of calculus, Fubini’s theorem and
supposing that T (0) = C(0) = 0, we have that:
θ
θ
{T (q(θ)) C(q(θ))}p(θ) =
θ
θ
q(θ)
0
{T
(q) C
(q)}dqp(θ)
=
θ
θ
0
{T
(q) C
(q)}1
{qq(θ)}
dqp(θ)
=
0
{T
(q) C
(q)}Pr(q q(θ))dq.
Finally, if T is a single-crossing tariff, then Pr(q q(θ)) = N(T
(q), q), so we can write the
monopolist’s objective function as:
0
{T
(q) C
(q)}N(T
(q), q)dq.
9
This definition was taken from [8].
1.3. UNIDIMENSIONAL SCREENING 11
Again, we define the relaxed version of the monopolist’s problem:
max
{T
(·)}
0
{T
(q) C
(q)}N(T
(q), q)dq.
DR
)
The Euler’s equation for the problem (Π
DR
) is given by:
N(T
(q), q) + {T
(q) C
(q)}N
1
(T
(q), q) = 0, (1.7)
where N
1
denotes the derivative of N with respect to its first variable.
We have to check ex-post whether the optimal marginal tariff T
(q) is single-crossing. In
this formulation, bunching emerges as the result of jumps in the optimal marginal tariff T
(q)
obtained from equation (1.7).
1.3.2 Unidimensional Screening without the SMC
Without the SMC the problem becomes rather complex. Unlike the previous case, a deci-
sion function satisfying the first- and second-order conditions of the customer’s maximization
problem may not be implementable.
Araujo and Moreira [1] introduced a model where the SMC is relaxed to:
AM1 v
qθ
(ξ, θ) = 0 defines a decreasing function q
0
: θ R
+
such that:
θ Θ v
qθ
(ξ, θ) 0 ξ q
0
(θ). (1.8)
So the curve q
0
divides the (θ, q) plane in two regions: CS
+
, where v
qθ
> 0 and CS
, where
v
qθ
< 0.
Using the first- and second-order conditions, one can show that an implementable decision
must be increasing in CS
+
and decreasing in CS
so the typical decision function will have
a U-shaped form. This shape allows that two distinct customers θ
1
and θ
2
choose the same
decision q. Analysing the first-order conditions for the pooling types θ
1
and θ
2
, we have another
necessary condition for implementability imposing that their marginal utility from choosing q
must be the same: v
q
(q, θ
1
) = v
q
(q, θ
1
). This identity between the marginal utilities of pooling
types is called the U-condition (UC). The derivation consists in incorporating the UC into the
monopolist’s objective function. The Goldman, Leland ans Sibley’s approach is convenient for
this task, because it allows the UC to be treated separetely for each q. The difference is that
now we will have two type assignment functions ψ
b
(q) and ψ
s
(q). We are going to adapt their
12 CHAPTER 1. NONLINEAR PRICING
q
CS
+
CS
q
0
θ
θ
q
q
0
q
ψ
b
(q)
ψ
s
(q)
θ
m
q
q
θ
m
q
q(θ)
Figure 1.3: The decision function q and its type assignment functions.
derivation to Araujo and Moreira’s setup. Considering and implementable decision q, we can
write the monopolist’s objective function as:
θ
θ
f(q(θ), θ)p(θ)dθ, (1.9)
where f(q, θ) is define by equation (1.4).
Using the fundamental theorem of calculus and the Fubini’s theorem, we can write:
θ
θ
f(q(θ), θ)p(θ) =
θ
θ
q(θ)
0
f
q
(q, θ)dq
p(θ) +
θ
θ
f(0, θ)p(θ)
=
q
0
{F (q, ψ
s
(q)) F (q, ψ
b
(q))}dq +
θ
θ
f(0, θ)p(θ),
where F is defined as:
F (q, ψ) =
ψ
θ
f
q
(q, θ)p(θ).
So we can define a relaxed version of the monopolist’s optimization problem as:
10
max
{ψ
b
(·)
s
(·)}
q
0
{F (q, ψ
s
(q)) F (q, ψ
b
(q))}dq +
θ
θ
f(0, θ)p(θ),
s.t. v
q
(q, ψ
b
(q)) v
q
(q, ψ
s
(q)) 0.
AMR
)
With an abuse of notation the constraint in problem (Π
AMR
) is called UC. The Euler’s
equation of problem above depends on whether the UC constraint is binding or not:
11
10
In Araujo and Moreira there are two distinct classes of solutions, one considering the constraint v
q
(q, ψ
b
(q))
v
q
(q, ψ
s
(q)) 0 and the other considering v
q
(q, ψ
b
(q)) v
q
(q, ψ
s
(q)) 0. We restrict our description to the first
kind of solution.
11
We refer the reader to Araujo and Moreira [1] for more details.
1.4. MULTIDIMENSIONAL SCREENING 13
If UC is slack and θ < ψ
b
(q) < ψ
s
(q) = θ then:
f
q
(q, ψ
b
(q)) = 0,
If UC is binding and θ < ψ
b
(q) < ψ
s
(q) < θ then:
f
q
(q, ψ
s
(q))
v
qθ
(q, ψ
s
(q))
=
f
q
(q, ψ
b
(q))
v
qθ
(q, ψ
b
(q))
,
If the condition UC is binding and θ < ψ
b
(q) < ψ
s
(q) = θ then:
v
q
(q, ψ
b
(q)) = v
q
(q, θ).
The optimal solution will be obtained as a combination of the pointwise conditions above. In
the appendix show that the tariff that implements the solutions in Araujo and Moreira [1] is
single-crossing. This means that the demand profile approach could have been used extended
to this non single-crossing setup. As far as we know, this methodology has never been used for
this kind of problem. Under the demand profile approach, however, the drawback is that the
computations are more complicated.
1.4 Multidimensional Screening
As we saw in the previous section, the solution of the monopolist’s optimization problem is
straightforward in the unidimensional case under the SMC. In the multidimensional case, how-
ever, the characterization of the optimal contract is a very complex problem. One of the
main difficulties refers to the fact that the binding IC constraints may be determined only en-
dogenously and we don’t have a satisfatory way of incorporating them into the maximization
problem. So there are only partial responses for this problem.
12
Matthews and Moore [16] studied the monopolistic screening problem with a two-dimensional
product space, representing the quality spectrum and the warranty. The customers are rep-
resented by a discrete parameter. Their goal was to extend Mussa and Rosen [20], and they
observed that some global IC constraints may be binding in the optimal decision.
12
We recommend the excellent survey in Multidimensional Screening by Rochet and Stole [27].
14 CHAPTER 1. NONLINEAR PRICING
McAfee and McMillan [17] studied the problem of a multi-product monopolist who faces a
customer with multidimensional characteristics with (M N). They introduced the General-
ized Single-Crossing (GSC)
13
, a condition under which the first- and second-order conditions
for the customer’s problem are necessary and sufficient for implementability. They also charac-
terized the optimal contract when (M = 1, N 1) under the (GSC).
Armstrong [2] studied the problem of multiproduct monopolist who faces customer’s with
multidimensional characteristics (N 1, M 1). He gave closed form solutions for some
examples in this multidimensional context. One of his main contributions was to discover the
exclusion property. This property states that the optimal contract leaves a positive measure
set of customers excluded from consumption.
Rochet and Chon
`
E [26] established the existence of the optimal contract and provided the
characterization in the case of a multiproduct monopolist who faces a customer with multidi-
mensional characteristics. They assume the number of products and characteristics to be the
same (N = M 1) and also that the parametrization of customer’s preferences is linear with
types. They introduced the sweeping procedure as a generalization of the ironing procedure for
dealing with bunching in the multidimensional context.
Basov [3] introduced the Hamiltonian approach as a tentative of generalizing Rochet and
Chon
`
E [26] to the case when the number of products and characteristics may be different
(N 1, M 1). Later on, these techniques were extended in his book [4] to deal with more
general customer’s preferences.
Parallel to this literature, there were some works analysing the existence of a solution for the
monopolist’s maximization problem (Π). We highlight the papers by Monteiro and Page [19]
and by Carlier [6]. The former uses compactness properties resulting from budget constraints
considerations and the latter using direct methods and concepts of abstract convexity. However,
these approaches do not actually provide any recipe for the characterization of the optimal
contract.
13
The GSC was defined on Section 1.2.
1.5. FINAL REMARKS 15
1.5 Final Remarks
Our research concerns the problem of a single-product monopolist who faces a customer with
two dimensions of heterogeneity. We assume neither the Spence and Mirrlees condition nor the
Generalized Single-Crossing.
In the second chapter we study this problem in a particular context. In our model these two
dimensions have antagonic effects in the decision q. We further assume that they are dependent
in a way that we can reduce the problem into a one-dimensional screening model. The Spence
and Mirrlees condition, however, is no longer valid because there is only one dimension to cope
with the antagonic effects of the original parameters.
Comparing our results with Araujo and Moreira [1] we present some advances. The optimal
decision we found Pareto dominates theirs and besides it is not implemented by a single-crossing
tariff. We were able to incorporate a new global IC constraint into the monopolist’s problem,
and this gives rise to a new optimality condition for this problem. This condition is new in the
literature of monopolistic screening.
In the third chapter we extend the techniques developed by Araujo and Moreira [1] to a
bidimensional screening context. This chapter is divided in two main sections contemplating
two cases.
In the first one, called discrete-continuous, one of the customer’s characteristic is discrete
and the other is continuous. We derived optimality conditions analogous to the ones in [1] and
then we show how to use them to construct an optimal contract.
In the second one, called bicontinuous, both customers’ characteristics are continuous. This
case is close to McAfee and McMillan [17] generalization of Laffont, Maskin and Rochet [14].
The difference is that we did not assume their Generalized Single-Crossing (GSC). We solved
an example where the (GSC) is not valid.
16 CHAPTER 1. NONLINEAR PRICING
Appendix
Our goal is to prove that the optimal decisions in Araujo and Moreira [1] is implemented by
a single-crossing tariff. In all that follows R(q) denotes the range of the function q. We begin
defining the pseudoinverse of a monotonic function:
Definition 4. Consider a monotonic function q : [θ, θ] R along with its upper contour set
S
q(·)
(q) = {θ [θ, θ] : q(θ) q}.
If q is decreasing, we define ψ
s
: R [θ, θ] as:
ψ
s
(q) =
sup S(q), if S(q) = ,
θ, if S(q) = .
If q is increasing, we define ψ
b
: R [θ, θ] as:
ψ
b
(q) =
inf S(q), if S(q) = ,
θ, if S(q) = .
In both cases, ψ
b
and ψ
s
are monotonic and they are denoted the pseudoinverses of q.
Then we establish the following result:
Lemma 1. Consider a monotonic function q : [a, b] R along with its pseudoinverse ψ(·).
For all x in the range of q, we have that:
(i) q(θ) x θ ψ(x), if q(·) is increasing;
(ii) q(θ) x θ ψ(x), if q(·) is decreasing.
Proof. We will only prove (i):
() It follows from the increasingness of q.
() It follows from the definition of the pseudoinverse.
We can do the same for proving (ii).
As a direct consequence of Lemma 1, we can state:
1.5. FINAL REMARKS 17
Lemma 2. Consider q : [a, b] R. Suppose that there exists θ
m
(a, b), point of continuity of
q, such that the restrictions, q
b
= q|
[a,θ
m
]
and q
s
= q|
[θ
m
,b]
, are monotonic, with q
b
decreasing
and q
s
increasing. Let ψ
b
and ψ
s
be their pseudoinverses. We have:
(i) If x R(q
b
) R(q
s
), then q(θ) x θ ψ
b
(x) or θ ψ
s
(x),
(ii) If x R(q
s
) R(q
b
)
c
, then q(θ) x θ ψ
s
(x),
(iii) If x R(q
b
)
c
R(q
s
), then q(θ) x θ ψ
b
(x).
q
CS
+
CS
q
0
θ
m
θ
θ
θ
d
θ
q
CS
+
CS
q
0
θ
m
θ
θ
θ
d
θ
Figure 1.4: The (DD) decision function.
We divide the optimal decisions in Araujo Moreira in two kinds; the first one is denoted the
discontinuous decision (DD) and the second one is denoted the continuous decision (CD).
The discontinuous decision (DD) is characterized by:
(1a) q(θ) < q(θ),
(1b) θ
m
(θ, θ) continuity point of q, such that:
(θ, q(θ)) CS
if θ θ θ
m
,
(θ, q(θ)) CS
+
if θ
m
θ θ,
q
b
= q|
[θ,θ
m
]
is decreasing,
q
s
= q|
[θ
m
]
is increasing,
(1c) q is discontinuous at θ
d
(θ
m
, θ),
(1d) ψ
b
: [q(θ
m
), q(θ)] [θ, θ
m
] is continuous,
18 CHAPTER 1. NONLINEAR PRICING
(1e) ψ
s
: [q(θ
m
), q(θ)] [θ
m
, θ] is continuous,
(1f) v
q
(q, ψ
b
(q)) = v
q
(q, ψ
s
(q)) q [q(θ
m
), q(θ)],
(1g) v
q
(q, θ) v
q
(q, ψ
s
(q)) q (q(θ), q(θ)].
q
CS
+
CS
q
0
θ
m
θ
θ
θ
q
CS
+
CS
q
0
θ
m
θ
θ
θ
Figure 1.5: The (CD) decision function.
The second is denoted the continuous decision (CD), characterized by:
(2a) q(θ) > q(θ),
(2b) θ
m
(θ, θ) continuity point of q, such that:
(θ, q(θ)) CS
if θ θ θ
m
,
(θ, q(θ)) CS
+
if θ
m
θ θ,
q
b
= q|
[θ,θ
m
]
is decreasing,
q
s
= q|
[θ
m
]
is increasing,
(2c) q is continuous,
(2d) ψ
b
: [q(θ
m
), q(θ)] [θ, θ
m
] is continuous except on q(θ),
(2e) ψ
s
: [q(θ
m
), q(θ)] [θ
m
, θ] is continuous except on q(θ),
(2f) v
q
(q, ψ
b
(q)) = v
q
(q, ψ
s
(q)) q [q(θ
m
), q(θ)],
(2g) v
q
(q, ψ
b
(q)) v
q
(q, θ) q (q(θ), q(θ)].
1.5. FINAL REMARKS 19
We have the following result for the optimal decisions in Araujo and Moreira: For a DD
solution, we have the followinf result.
Proposition 1. Let q be a decision and T : R(q) R be the tariff that implements it. If q is
(DD) or (CD), then T is a single-crossing tariff.
Proof. We will only prove the case (DD). The other case is analogous. If we consider the agent’s
maximization problem, the first-order conditions gives:
T
(q) = v
q
(q, ψ
s
(q)).
Assumption (AM1), items (1f) and (1g) imply that:
q [q(θ
m
), q(θ)] v
q
(q, θ) T
(q) θ ψ
b
(q) or θ ψ
s
(q),
q (q(θ), q(θ)] v
q
(q, θ) T
(q) θ ψ
s
(q).
Finally, by Lemma 2, we conclude that:
q(θ) q v
q
(q, θ) T
(q)
And the result follows.
Chapter 2
Nonlineard Pricing Without a
Single-Crossing Tariff
2.1 Introduction
Nonlinear pricing schemes are widely used in many markets such as mobile telephony, fixed
telephony, electricity and gas supply, postal services, air and railroad transport, cable TV
and internet. For this reason, it has attracted a lot of attention over the past decades from
economists. One of the seminal papers in this field is by Mussa and Rosen [20], who analysed
nonlinear prices for the provision of quality-differentiated goods. Other contributions were made
by Goldman, Leland and Sibley [8], who studied price discrimination via quantity discounts
and by Maskin and Riley [15] who observed that all these models belong to the same class of
principal-agent problems.
On the other hand, the demand profile approach is an alternative formulation for the mo-
nopolistic screening problem, introduced in the literature by Brown and Sibley [5] and then
thoroughly expounded in Wilson [29]
1
. The basis for this approach is the requirement that the
marginal tariff T
(q) cuts the customer’s demand curve once from below. When satisfied, we
have that the customer’s maximization problem is quasiconcave so its demand behavior can be
1
In a survey on multidimensional screening, Rochet and Stole [27] make a distinction between the approach
adopted by Mussa and Rosen, and Maskin and Riley, called parameter utility approach and the other one called
demand profile approach.
21
22 CHAPTER 2. NONLINEARD PRICING WITHOUT A SINGLE-CROSSING TARIFF
deduced completely from the marginal benefit of consumption. In Goldman, Leland and Sibley,
a tariff satisfying this requirement is called a single-crossing tariff, a terminology that we will
also use in this chapter.
All these methods work fine and equivalently when the Spence and Mirrlees condition (SMC)
is satisfied. The main reason is that it provides a natural ordering for the customer’s demand
curves. As a consequence, the monopolist is able to induce any monotonic decision for the
customers by selecting a compatible tariff.
We study a nonlinear pricing model where the monopolist has incomplete information about
the slope and the intercept of the customer’s demand curve, represented by α and β. In our
model these two dimensions have antagonic effects in the decision q which should increase with
α and decrease with β. We further assume that these two dimensions are dependent in a way
that we can reduce it into a one-dimensional screening model with parameter θ. Now a bigger θ
will represent at the same time as a bigger α and β and the monopolist does not know which of
the antagonic effects will dominate the other. By having only one dimension summarizing the
effects of those two parameters, it ends up in a model where the SMC is not satisfied anymore.
Without the SMC the problem becomes rather complex, in part due to the absence of this
natural ordering. As a consequence the decision q may be nonmonotonic. Besides the local
incentive compatibility conditions may not be sufficient as new global conditions arise. This
problem without the SMC was studied by Araujo and Moreira [1]. Although they relax the
Spence and Mirrlees condition, the optimal contract proposed there is compatible with the
demand profile approach, because it is implemented by a single-crossing tariff and consequently
the customers face a quasiconcave problem.
Our goal is to show that in our monopolistic screening model without the SMC, the contract
resulting from a single-crossing tariff, compatible with the demand profile approach may be
suboptimal for the monopolist. We present another contract that provides a larger profit for
the monopolist. This contract is not compatible with the demand profile approach because
the tariff is not single-crossing. Moreover the optimal contract is discontinuous and induces a
separation in the quality spectrum between two groups: one who buys low quality goods, and
the other who buys high quality goods. The tariff should be adjusted in a way that one group
does not envy the other.
2.2. MODEL 23
The chapter is organized as follows. In Section 2.2 we define the model we are using. Then,
in Section 2.3 we present some results related to the incentive compatibility condition. In
Section 2.4 we derive the monopolist’s optimization problem using an approach adapted from
Goldman, Leland and Sibley, we establish the pointwise optimality conditions for the monop-
olist’s problem and finally we solve some examples. In Section 2.6 we present the conclusions.
All proofs are given in the Appendix.
2.2 Model
We use the Principal-Agent framework to analyse the monopolistic screening problem. In this
model, each customer has a quasi-linear preference:
V (q, t, θ) = v(q, θ) t,
where t represents the monetary transfer. The parameter θ is a random variable with a positive
and continuous density representing the customer’s type. The firm is a profit-maximizing
monopolist which can produce any quality q Q R
+
incurring in a cost C(q). Q represents
the quality spectrum. The monopolist’s revenue is given by:
Π(q, t) = t C(q).
Using the ‘Revelation Principle’
2
the monopolist’s problem can be stated as choosing the
allocation rule (q, t) : Θ R
+
× R that solves:
max
{q(·),t(·)}
Θ
Π(q(θ), t(θ))p(θ)dθ, (2.1)
subject to the individual-rationality constraints:
v(q(θ), θ) t(θ) 0 θ Θ, (IR)
and the incentive compatibility constraints:
θ arg max
θ
Θ
{v(q(θ
), θ) t(θ
)}, θ Θ. (IC)
2
The ‘Revelation Principle’ has been enunciated in Gibbard [7].
24 CHAPTER 2. NONLINEARD PRICING WITHOUT A SINGLE-CROSSING TARIFF
Remark 1. The ‘Taxation Principle’
3
states that any allocation (q, t) satisfying the IC con-
straints can be implemented by a nonlinear tariff T : Q = q(Θ) R where:
T (q(θ)) = t(θ), θ Θ.
2.2.1 The Model Setup
We consider a monopolist who produces a single good and is uncertain about the slope and
the intercept of the customer’s demand curves. The utility function of each customer is
parametrized according to:
v(q, α, β) = αq β
q
2
2
,
and the individual inverse demand curve is given by:
p(q) = α βq.
The cross derivatives of v satisfy: v
qα
> 0 and v
qβ
0. These conditions imply that an incentive
compatible decision q must increase with α and decrease with β (see Rochet [25]). Hence the
effects of these parameters on q are antagonic.
We analyse the case when the random variables α and β are dependent in the following
manner:
α = θ,
β =
2
,
with θ uniformly distributed on [θ, θ] = [a, a + 1]. Now we have then only one parameter θ to
cope with the effects of α and β. A bigger θ means bigger α and β, so the decision will increase
or decrease depending on which effect is dominant. This results in the following setup:
v(q, θ) = θq
2
q
2
2
,
C(q) = c
q
2
2
,
and we assume that a, b and c are nonnegative constants.
The inverse demand function is now given by
p(q) = θ
2
q,
3
This principle can be found in Guesnerie [9], Hammond [11] and Rochet [24].
2.2. MODEL 25
and the elasticity of demand is
(q, θ) = 1
1
q
.
The demand function for types θ
1
and θ
2
are drawn in Figure 2.1. For θ-type customer, the
ratio q = 1/() measures the market size and the intercept θ represents the minimum price
such that this customer’s demand is zero.
p
q
θ
1
θ
2
1
bθ
1
1
bθ
2
p(q, θ
1
)
p(q, θ
2
)
q
1
q
2
Figure 2.1: Demand curves for θ
1
and θ
2
customers.
When b = 0 the specification of this model is the same as Mussa and Rosen [20], but when
b > 0 the Spence and Mirrlees condition
4
is no longer satisfied and the solution of v
qθ
(q, θ) = 0
determines a decreasing function given by
q
0
(θ) =
1
2
. (2.2)
This function gives a limit curve that divides the (θ, q) plane in two regions denoted by CS
+
,
where v
qθ
> 0 and CS
, where v
qθ
< 0. The consequence is the lack of an ordering of the
demand curves as we can see in Figure 2.1, where we have the following inequalities for the
marginal utility: v
q
(q
1
, θ
1
) < v
q
(q
1
, θ
2
) and v
q
(q
2
, θ
1
) > v
q
(q
2
, θ
2
).
Unlike the SMC case, it is not possible to know a priori which customer will consume
more, as this is determined endogenously as a response to the nonlinear tariff adopted by the
monopolist. The decision now may be nonmonotonic, increasing in CS
+
and decreasing in CS
and these conditions suggest a bell-shaped form for the decision function q.
26 CHAPTER 2. NONLINEARD PRICING WITHOUT A SINGLE-CROSSING TARIFF
2.3 Incentive Compatibility Conditions
Without the Spence and Mirrlees condition there is not a simple rule for characterizing an incen-
tive compatible allocation and the problem becomes very complex. There are some necessary
conditions, however, that should be taken into account.
In all that follows, we assume that the allocation rule (q, t) is bounded and incentive com-
patible. The informational rent V : Θ R
+
is given by:
V (θ) = v(q(θ), θ) t(θ), (2.3)
and T : q(Θ) R is the tariff resulting from the ‘Revelation Principle’.
We begin by establishing a basic property regarding the Lipschitz continuity of both T and
V .
Lemma 3. (Differentiability Condition.) The tariff T and the informational rent V are
Lipschitz continuous.
Notice that Lemma 3 guarantees that both T and V are absolute continuous and then a.e.
differentiable and now we are able to deduce the following envelope conditions involving their
derivatives.
Lemma 4. (Envelope Conditions for V and T .)
(i) If V is differentiable at θ int(Θ) and q q(θ), then
V
(θ) = v
θ
(q, θ). (2.4)
(ii) If T is differentiable at q q(θ) int(q(Θ)), then
T
(q) = v
q
(q, θ). (2.5)
Notice that Lemma 4 (ii) can be understood as the first order condition of the θ-customer
maximization problem:
max
qQ
{v(q, θ) T (q)}.
4
The Spence and Mirrlees condition states that the cross derivative v
does not change its signal. When
satisfied the incentive compatibility is equivalent to the monotonicity of the decision function q. See Rochet [25],
for instance.
2.3. INCENTIVE COMPATIBILITY CONDITIONS 27
With the SMC a decision is incentive compatible if and only if is monotonic. However,
without the SMC we may have a nonmonotonic incentive compatible decision. The next result
is related to the local monotonicity conditions on the decision q.
Lemma 5. (Local Monotonicity Conditions.) Suppose that q is continuous at θ
0
. Then:
(i) If q(θ
0
) > q
0
(θ
0
) then q is increasing at θ
0
,
(ii) If q(θ
0
) < q
0
(θ
0
) then q is decreasing at θ
0
,
where q
0
is defined in equation (2.2).
The new possibilities for q coming from Lemma 5 motivates us to define the bell-shaped
decisions.
Definition 5. (Bell-Shaped Decisions.) The decision q : Θ R
+
is bell-shaped if there
exists a continuity point θ
m
Θ such that the restrictions:
q|
[θ,θ
m
]
is increasing and q|
[θ
m
]
is decreasing.
For a bell-shaped decision, we may have a discrete pooling situation, when types θ
1
and
θ
2
choose the same decision q. Using Lemma 4 (ii), we can easily deduce a new necessary
condition for incentive compatibility relating the marginal valuations of the pooled types.
Corollary 1. (Bell-Shaped Condition.) Suppose that T is differentiable at q q(θ
1
) q(θ
2
)
an interior point of Q = q(Θ). Then
v
q
(q, θ
1
) = v
q
(q, θ
2
). (BS)
This marginal utility equality in Corollary 1 will be denoted BS-condition, and it says that
pooled types must pay the same marginal tariff for the chosen decision q.
28 CHAPTER 2. NONLINEARD PRICING WITHOUT A SINGLE-CROSSING TARIFF
2.4 The Monopolist’s Problem
Suppose first that the alocation rule (q, t) is incentive compatible. Let us now deduce the
monopolist’s maximization problem, using the same derivation as Mussa and Rosen [20]. From
the definition of the informational rent V (equation (2.3)) we can write the monetary transfer
as t(θ) = v(q(θ), θ) V (θ) and then substitute it in equation (2.1). The result is the following
problem:
max
{q(·)}
Θ
{v(q(θ), θ) C(q(θ)) V (θ)}. (2.6)
Now using Lemma 4 and an integration by parts procedure, we can rewrite the problem above
as
5
:
max
{q(·)}
θ
θ
f(q(θ), θ),
R
)
where f(q, θ) is given by:
f(q, θ) = v(q(θ), θ) C(q(θ)) + (θ a 1)v
θ
(q(θ), θ).
This is called the relaxed version of the monopolist’s maximization problem, because the
monotonicity constraints are not considered in this problem. The inconvenience of the derivation
above is that in many situations the solution of Problem (Π
R
) is far from being incentive
compatible. One reason is that it does not consider the (BS) condition. We are going to derive
the monopolist’s optimization problem in a way that the (BS) necessary condition given by
Corollary 1 can be taken into account. We need the following definitions:
Definition 6. Consider a monotonic function q : [θ, θ] R along with its upper contour set
S(q) = {θ [θ, θ] : q(θ) q}.
If q is decreasing, we define ψ
s
: R [θ, θ] as:
ψ
s
(q) =
sup S(q), if S(q) = ,
θ, if S(q) = .
If q is increasing, we define ψ
b
: R [θ, θ] as:
ψ
b
(q) =
inf S(q), if S(q) = ,
θ, if S(q) = .
In both cases, ψ
b
and ψ
s
are monotonic and they are denoted the pseudoinverses of q.
5
We are implicitily assuming that V
(θ) 0. For a more general case we refer to Jullien [13].
2.4. THE MONOPOLIST’S PROBLEM 29
For a bell-shaped decision, using a procedure similar to Goldman, Leland and Sibley [8], we
can reformulate the problem (Π
R
). First we use the fundamental theorem of calculus to write:
θ
θ
f(q(θ), θ) =
θ
θ
q(θ)
q
f
q
(q, θ)dq.
Then, we use Fubini’s theorem, and the following problem results:
max
{ψ
b
s
}
q
q
{F (q, ψ
s
(q)) F (q, ψ
b
(q))}dq +
θ
θ
f(q, θ).
(2.7)
F is given by the following equation:
F (q, ψ) =
ψ
θ
f
q
(q, θ), (2.8)
and besides ψ
b
is the pseudoinverse of the increasing part of q and ψ
s
is the inverse of the
decreasing part of q. They are denoted type assignment functions, because they relate q with the
type who purchases it. Notice that the integration variable on the left hand side of equation (2.7)
is q, and now we can treat the constraint imposed by the condition (BS) condition for each q
separately.
2.4.1 Single-Crossing Tariff
First let us define a single-crossing tariff
6
:
Definition 7. (Single-Crossing Tariff.) A tariff is said to be single-crossing at q if, for any
θ such that v
q
(q, θ) T
(q), v
q
(q
, θ) T
(q
) for q
q. If T (q) is single-crossing for all q, we
term it a single-crossing tariff schedule.
If the tariff is single-crossing and continuous, then the customer’s maximization problem is
quasiconcave.
Using the concept of a single-crossing tariff, we will be able to define the following optimiza-
tion problem for the monopolist, when q(θ) < q(θ)
7
:
max
{ψ
b
s
}
q
q
{F (q, ψ
s
(q)) F (q, ψ
b
(q))}dq +
θ
θ
f(q, θ),
s.t. v
q
(q, ψ
b
(q)) v
q
(q, ψ
s
(q)) 0.
BS
)
6
This definition was taken from Goldman, Leland and Sibley [8].
7
The other case, when q(θ) > q(θ), is treated analogously, and we only have to reverse the inequality in
problem Π
BS
.
30 CHAPTER 2. NONLINEARD PRICING WITHOUT A SINGLE-CROSSING TARIFF
Notice that the problem Π
BS
is coherent with a single-crossing tariff T . In this case, when
q(θ) < q(θ) and q < q(θ), then v
q
(q, ψ
b
(q)) v
q
(q, ψ
s
(q)), because T
(q) = v
q
(q, ψ
b
(q)) and
v
q
(q, θ) T
(q).
Once we find the optimal type assignment functions ψ
b
and ψ
s
we can invert them and find
the optimal decision q.
Now let us establish the optimality conditions for Π
BS
.
Theorem 1. The solution of Π
BS
is characterized by the following conditions:
(i) If the condition BS is not binding and θ < ψ
b
(q) < ψ
s
(q) = θ then:
f
q
(q, ψ
b
(q)) = 0, (2.9)
(ii) If the condition BS is binding and θ < ψ
b
(q) < ψ
s
(q) < θ then:
f
q
(q, ψ
s
(q))
v
qθ
(q, ψ
s
(q))
=
f
q
(q, ψ
b
(q))
v
qθ
(q, ψ
b
(q))
, (2.10)
(iii) If the condition BS is binding and θ < ψ
b
(q) < ψ
s
(q) = θ then:
v
q
(q, ψ
b
(q)) = v
q
(q, θ). (2.11)
q
CS
+
CS
q
0
θ
θ
m
q
q
θ
θ
q
1
q
2
Figure 2.2: A typical solution for Π
BS
.
In Figure 2.2, we show the typical solution for the optimization problem Π
BS
resulting from
Theorem 1. For q < q
1
, we use condition (i), for q (q
1
, q
2
) we use condition (iii) and finally for
2.4. THE MONOPOLIST’S PROBLEM 31
q (q
2
, q) we use condition (ii). As we can see there is a problem related with the monotonicity
condition resulting from Lemma 5.
We have two alternatives for fixing this lack of monotonicity. The first one is a vertical
ironing compatible with a single-crossing tariff T and the next proposition shows how restrictive
this condition is.
Proposition 2. If the tariff T is single-crossing then the decision q is convex valued.
As a consequence of Proposition 2, if the decision q jumps at θ
d
, then the marginal tariff
for q [q(θ
d
), q(θ
d
+)] is given by T
(q) = v
q
(q, θ
d
) and this affects the decision for customers
with types θ close to θ. The reason is simple: with a single-crossing tariff, the marginal
net benefit determines the customer’s choice and when a jump occurs, the marginal tariff is
automatically defined for all the intermediate quantities and of course this may affect some
customer’s decisions.
q
CS
+
CS
q
0
θ
θ
m
q
q
θ
θ
θ
d
ˆ
θ
d
q(θ
d
+)
q(θ
d
)
Figure 2.3: The vertical ironing procedure.
The decision function that emerges from this vertical ironing is given by:
q
θ
d
(θ) =
q
R
(θ) , if θ < θ
d
,
q
B
(θ) , if θ
d
θ
ˆ
θ
d
,
q
C
(θ, θ
d
) , if
ˆ
θ
d
θ
θ,
(2.12)
32 CHAPTER 2. NONLINEARD PRICING WITHOUT A SINGLE-CROSSING TARIFF
where q
R
and q
B
result from Theorem 1 (i) and (ii), respectively. On the other hand q
C
results
from solving the equation:
v
q
(q, θ
d
) = v
q
(q, θ).
Notice that the customers with type θ
ˆ
θ
d
choose q [q(θ
d
), q(θ
d
+)] and their decision is
affected by the fact that for this q the marginal tariff is T
(q) = v
q
(q, θ
d
). The function q
C
captures this effect. Finally, we get
ˆ
θ
d
from solving q
B
(θ
d
) = q
B
(
ˆ
θ
d
).
The point θ
d
must be chosen optimally and is characterized by the following:
Theorem 2. The first order condition for the optimal θ
d
is given by:
f(q
B
(θ
d
), θ
d
) f(q
R
(θ
d
), θ
d
) =
θ
ˆ
θ
d
f
q
(q
C
(θ, θ
d
), θ)
q
C
θ
d
(θ, θ
d
). (2.13)
Notice that this vertical ironing fixes the monotonicity problem by keeping the type assign-
ment functions ψ
b
and ψ
s
continuous. This kind of solution was also proposed in Araujo and
Moreira [1]. It can also be obtained by using the demand profile approach of Wilson, but the
computations are more difficult than the one we presented here.
2.4.2 Non Single-Crossing Tariff
Now we propose an alternative for this vertical ironing where ψ
b
and ψ
s
may be discontinuous.
This is illustrated in Figure 2.4. More than that, our procedure will result in a non single-
crossing tariff.
We will impose the global incentive compatibility constraint relating θ
d
and θ customers.
We are asking that the θ-type customer does not envy θ
d
-type customer. In other words we
impose:
v(q(θ), θ) t(θ) v(q(θ
d
), θ) t(θ
d
). (2.14)
The following result will be useful to restate the condition above
8
:
Lemma 6. Consider an allocation rule (q, t) : Θ R
+
× R. If (q, t) is incentive compatible
then:
θ
ˆ
θ
q(
˜
θ)
q(
ˆ
θ)
v
qθ
(˜q,
˜
θ)d˜qd
˜
θ 0, θ,
ˆ
θ Θ. (2.15)
8
This condition is actually equivalent to incentive compatibility, as shown by Araujo and Moreira [1].
2.4. THE MONOPOLIST’S PROBLEM 33
θ
m
θ
d
θ
θ
q
1
q
2
q
θ
q
θ
m
θ
d
θ
q
2
q
q
θ
1
θ
2
θ
3
θ
4
q(θ)
θ
ψ
b
(q)
ψ
s
(q)
q(θ)
q
0
q
0
q
1
Figure 2.4: An alternative ironing procedure.
Notice that Lemma 6 relates incentive compatibility with an area condition represented by
a double integral.
The same procedure used in the proof of Lemma 6 allows us to write the inequality (2.14)
as:
θ
θ
d
q(
˜
θ)
q(θ
d
)
v
qθ
(˜q,
˜
θ)d˜qd
˜
θ 0. (2.16)
Notice that:
θ
θ
d
q(
˜
θ)
q(θ
d
)
v
qθ
(˜q,
˜
θ)d˜qd
˜
θ =
θ
θ
d
q
2
q
1
v
qθ
(˜q,
˜
θ)d˜qd
˜
θ +
θ
θ
d
q(
˜
θ)
q
2
v
qθ
(˜q,
˜
θ)d˜qd
˜
θ. (2.17)
Using Fubini’s theorem, we can write the second integral on the right hand side of equation
(2.17) as:
θ
θ
d
q(
˜
θ)
q
2
v
qθ
(˜q,
˜
θ)d˜qd
˜
θ =
q
q
2
ψ
s
(q)
ψ
b
(q)
v
qθ
(˜q,
˜
θ)d
˜
θd˜q
=
q
q
2
{v
q
(q, ψ
s
(q)) v
q
(q, ψ
b
(q))}dq.
However v
q
(q, ψ
s
(q)) = v
q
(q, ψ
b
(q)) for q (q
2
, q] which implies that this part is null.
Using Fubini’s theorem again we can write the first integral on the right hand side of equation
(2.17) as:
θ
θ
d
q
2
q
1
v
qθ
(˜q,
˜
θ)d˜qd
˜
θ =
q
2
q
1
{v
q
(q, ψ
s
(q)) v
q
(q, θ
d
)}dq. (2.18)
34 CHAPTER 2. NONLINEARD PRICING WITHOUT A SINGLE-CROSSING TARIFF
and the condition in equation (2.16) will be given by:
q
2
q
1
{v
q
(q, ψ
s
(q)) v
q
(q, θ
d
)}dq 0. (ISO)
In the interval [q
1
, q
2
], we will optimally choose ψ
s
(q) such that the condition (ISO) is fulfilled.
So we have the following isoperimetric problem:
max
{ψ
s
}
q
2
q
1
{F (q, ψ
s
(q)) F (q, θ
d
)}dq
s.t.(ISO).
ISO
)
Theorem 3. The solution of Π
ISO
is characterized by the following condition:
f
q
(q, ψ
s
(q)) + λv
qθ
(q, ψ
s
(q)) = 0, (2.19)
where λ is chosen to satisfy the condition (ISO) with equality.
Now we use conditions given by Theorem 1 and Theorem 3 to build a candidate for the
monopolist’s optimization problem. The cited theorems give the pointwise conditions for the
three pieces that constitute the candidate we are proposing. Looking again at Figure 2.4, we
see that the only change is for q [q
1
, q
2
], where we are doing this alternative ironing. The
values q
1
, q
2
and θ
d
are endogenously determined as a result of an optimization process. Let us
describe the type assignment functions ψ
b
and ψ
s
:
ψ
s
(q) =
ψ
sr
(q) , if q
q q
1
,
ψ
si
(q) , if q
1
q q
2
,
ψ
sc
(q) , if q
2
q q,
(2.20)
where we have that ψ
sr
= θ, ψ
si
(q) is given by equation (2.19) and ψ
sc
is given by equation
(2.10).
ψ
b
(q) =
ψ
br
(q) , if q q q
1
,
ψ
bi
(q) , if q
1
q q
2
,
ψ
bc
(q) , if q
2
q q,
(2.21)
where ψ
bi
= θ
d
, we define ψ
br
from equation (2.9) and ψ
bc
from equation (2.10).
Now the monopolist’s problem will depend on the variables q
1
, q
2
and θ
d
, and we can write
its expected profit as Π(q
1
, q
2
, θ
d
) where q
1
, q
2
and θ
d
satisfy the condition (ISO). Our last step
is to optimally choose these parameters:
2.5. AN EXAMPLE 35
Theorem 4. The optimal choices for the parameters q
1
, q
2
and θ
d
are characterized by:
(i)
F (q
1
, ψ
sr
(q
1
)) F (q
1
, ψ
br
(q
1
)) + F (q
1
, θ
d
) F (q
1
, ψ
si
(q
1
))
v
q
(q
1
, ψ
si
(q
1
)) v
q
(q
1
, θ
d
)
= λ,
(ii)
F (q
2
, ψ
si
(q
2
)) F (q
2
, θ
d
) + F (q
2
, ψ
bc
(q
2
)) F (q
2
, ψ
sc
(q
2
))
v
q
(q
2
, θ
d
) v
q
(q
2
, ψ
si
(q
2
))
= λ,
(iii)
q
2
q
1
{F
θ
(q, θ
d
) + λv
qθ
(q, θ
d
)}dq = 0,
where λ is the Lagrangian multiplier associated with the isoperimetric constraint.
Remark 2. Considering the isoperimetric condition, we have four equations and four param-
eters: q
1
, q
2
, θ
d
and λ. We get the optimal candidate by solving this system of equations.
2.5 An Example
This example illustrates the difference between the two ironing procedures used for fixing the
monotonicity problem. The first one is compatible with the demand profile approach because
the resulting tariff is single-crossing. The second one uses the isoperimetric condition and results
in a non single-crossing tariff.
Let us choose the following values for the parameters in our model: a = 2, b = 1 and c = 6.
With these parameters, we have that θ is uniformly distributed in [2, 3] and:
v(q, θ) = θq θ
2
q
2
2
,
C(q) = 3q
2
.
Using Theorem 1, we can derive the solution for Π
BS
:
ψ
b
(q) =
3q+1
9q
2
3q+1
3q
, if
1
6
q
1
102
15 +
21
,
13q
q
, if
1
102
15 +
21
q
1
66
9 +
15
,
3q
3
q
2
24q
4
6q
2
, if
1
66
9 +
15
q
1
2
6
.
ψ
s
(q) =
3, if
1
6
q
1
102
15 +
21
,
3, if
1
102
15 +
21
q
1
66
9 +
15
,
3q+
3
q
2
24q
4
6q
2
, if
1
66
9 +
15
q
1
2
6
.
As we can see in Figure 2.5 ψ
b
is nonmonotonic. We are going to derive the solutions using
the two ironing procedures developed before.
36 CHAPTER 2. NONLINEARD PRICING WITHOUT A SINGLE-CROSSING TARIFF
ψ
b
(q)
ψ
s
(q)
2
3
q
1
q
2
θ
1
θ
2
q
q
θ
Figure 2.5: The solutions ψ
b
and ψ
s
for Π
BS
.
a) Standard Ironing Procedure:
The first step is to write the solution depending on the parameter θ
d
, as we did in equation
(2.12):
q
θ
d
(θ) =
q
R
(θ) =
32θ
3θ
2
+6θ6
, if θ < θ
d
,
q
B
(θ) =
3θ+
3θ
2
12
2(3θ
2
+6)
, if θ
d
θ
ˆ
θ
d
,
q
C
(θ, θ
d
) =
1
θ+θ
d
, if
ˆ
θ
d
θ θ,
where
ˆ
θ
d
= 2θ
d
3
θ
2
d
4.
Using Theorem 2, we can find the optimal θ
d
and
ˆ
θ
d
:
θ
d
2.164282,
ˆ
θ
d
2.89596.
The decision fucntion resulting from this ironing procedure is denoted q
SC
(θ). We can find
the tariff T
SC
(q) that implements the decision by integrating the marginal tariff given by:
T
SC
(q) = v
q
(q, ψ
b
(q)),
where ψ
b
is the pseudoinverse of q
SC
(θ)|
[θ,
6]
. In Figure 2.6, we plot the decision function and
the marginal tariff. Notice that the marginal tariff is continuous so the tariff is continuously
differentiable.
The monopolist’s expected profit from q
SC
(θ) is:
Π(θ
d
) = 0.200272 (2.22)
2.5. AN EXAMPLE 37
q
CS
+
CS
q
0
θ
d
ˆ
θ
d
q(θ
d
+)
q(θ
d
)
6
1
2
6
1
6
2
3
θ
T
SC
(q)
q
q
q
q(θ
d
+)
q(θ
d
)
q
SC
(θ)
Figure 2.6: The decision function and the marginal tariff.
b) Isoperimetric Ironing Procedure:
Now we use the isoperimetric procedure. Let us describe the type assignment functions ψ
s
and ψ
b
according to equations (2.20) and (2.21):
ψ
s
(q) =
ψ
sr
(q) = 3 , if
1
6
q q
1
,
ψ
si
(q) =
1q(λ3)+
(λ
2
6λ9)q
2
+(λ3)q+1
3q
, if q
1
q q
2
,
ψ
sc
(q) =
3q+
3
q
2
24q
4
6q
2
, if q
2
q
1
2
6
,
ψ
b
(q) =
ψ
br
(q) =
3q+1
9q
2
3q+1
3q
, if
1
6
q q
1
,
ψ
bi
(q) = θ
d
, if q
1
q q
2
,
ψ
bc
(q) =
3q
3
q
2
24q
4
6q
2
, if q
2
q
1
2
6
.
Using Theorem 4 and the isoperimetric condition, we get the following values:
q
1
0.183112, q
2
0.202431, θ
d
2.201349, λ 0.067841.
When we invert the type assignment functions, we get the following decision function:
q
NSC
(θ) =
32θ
3θ
2
+6θ6
, if θ θ
1
,
32θ
1
3θ
2
1
+6θ
1
6
, if θ
1
θ θ
d
,
3θ
2
+
3θ
2
2
12
2
(
3θ
2
2
+6
)
, if θ
d
θ θ
2
or if θ
3
θ θ
4
,
3θ+
3θ
2
12
2(3θ
2
+6)
, if θ
2
θ θ
3
,
1q(λ3)+
(λ
2
6λ9)q
2
+(λ3)q+1
3q
, if θ
4
θ 3.
38 CHAPTER 2. NONLINEARD PRICING WITHOUT A SINGLE-CROSSING TARIFF
where:
θ
1
2.117953, θ
2
2.286691, θ
3
2.653259, θ
4
2.863469.
q
CS
+
CS
q
0
θ
d
6
1
2
6
1
6
2
3
θ
1
θ
2
θ
3
θ
4
q
1
q
2
θ
T
NSC
(q)
q
NSC
(θ)
q
1
q
2
q(3)
q
q
Figure 2.7: The decision function and the marginal tariff..
We can find the tariff T
NSC
(q) that implements the decision q
NSC
(θ) by integrating the
marginal tariff given by:
T
NSC
(q) =
v
q
(q, ψ
br
(q)), if
1
6
q q
1
,
v
q
(q, ψ
si
(q)), if q
1
q q
2
,
v
q
(q, ψ
bc
(q)), if q
2
q
1
2
6
.
We can see in Figure 2.7 the decision function q
NSC
(θ) and the marginal tariff T
NSC
(q). Notice
that jumps in the marginal tariff correspond to bunching in the decision function graphic.
The monopolist’s expected profit from q
NSC
(θ) is:
Π(q
1
, q
2
, θ
d
) = 0.200314 (2.23)
Comparing the equations (2.22) and (2.23), we see that the isoperimetric ironing procedure
results in a larger expected profit for the monopolist. We have an increase of approximately
0.021%. This shows the suboptimality the decision function q
NSC
(θ).
In Figure 2.8 we make a superposition of the decision function and the marginal tariff for
ironing procedures (a) and (b). Notice that the latter results in a smaller quality spectrum
than the former.
The fundamental difference between the two decision functions is that q
SC
(θ) is implemented
by the single-crossing tariff T
SC
(q) and q
NSC
(θ) is implemented by the non single-crossing tariff
2.6. CONCLUSION 39
q
q
q
T
SC
(q)
T
NSC
(q)
q
CS
+
CS
q
0
6
1
2
6
1
6
2
3
q
1
q
2
θ
q
SC
(θ)
q
NSC
(θ)
Figure 2.8: The decision an the marginal tariff for both procedures (a) and (b) .
T
NSC
(q). In fact, when the tariff is T
NSC
(q), the maximization problem for customer θ
d
is not
quasiconcave as it has two local maxima q
1
and q
2
so the decision q
NSC
(θ) is not convex valued.
In Figure 2.9 we plot the customer θ
d
utility depending on his choice of q under the non
single-crossing tariff T
NSC
(q).
q
1
q
2
q
V (θ
d
)
q(θ
)
q(θ
m)
v(q, θ
d
) T
NSC
(q)
Figure 2.9: The customer θ
d
’s utility under the non single-crossing tariff T
NSC
(q).
2.6 Conclusion
In our model of nonlinear pricing without the Spence and Mirrlees condition, we showed that
the basic assumption of the demand profile approach may not be valid and that the demand
profile approach can lead to a suboptimal solution for the monopolist’s optimization problem.
40 CHAPTER 2. NONLINEARD PRICING WITHOUT A SINGLE-CROSSING TARIFF
The reason is that the requirement of a single-crossing tariff is restrictive, as it imposes a convex
valued decision.
In a multidimensional setting we also have the same situation described here, since there is
not a natural ordering for the customer’s demand curves. Then one has to investigate whether
the restrictions imposed by the demand profile approach may affect or not the monopolist’s
welfare. Without a criterion based on the fundaments of the model that allows the monopolist to
anticipate whether his maximization problem results or not in a single-crossing tariff, we cannot
know if the contract resulting from the demand profile approach is a suboptimal contract. This
poses a serious restriction in knowing which problems are adequate for this kind of approach.
Appendix
We need the concept of cyclical monotonicity
9
:
Definition 8. A correspondence q : Θ Q is v-cyclic-monotone if and only if for all finite
cycles θ
0
, θ
1
, . . . , θ
n+1
= θ
0
Θ,
n
i=0
{v(q(θ
i
), θ
i+1
) v(q(θ
i
), θ
i
)} 0.
Theorem 5. (Rochet, 1987) A decision q : Θ Q is implementable if and only if q is v-cyclic-
monotone.
We also need some abstract convexity results related to incentive compatibility that we will
state here.
10
Definition 9. Let V : Θ R. The v-subdifferential of V ,
v
V : Θ Q, is defined by:
v
V (θ) =
q Q : V (θ
) V (θ) v(q, θ
) v(q, θ) θ
Θ
.
Definition 10. V is said to be v-subdifferentiable in Θ if and only if
v
V (θ) = ∅ ∀θ Θ.
Definition 11. Let V : Θ R. We define the v-conjugated of V by:
V
v
: Q R V
v
(q) = sup
θΘ
{v(q, θ) V (θ)};
and the v-biconjugate of V by:
V
vv
: Θ R V
vv
(θ) = sup
qQ
{v(q, θ) V
v
(q)}.
9
This can be found in Rochet [25].
10
These results can be found in Carlier [6] and Rachev and R¸schendorf [23].
2.6. CONCLUSION 41
Proposition 3. Let V : Θ R , then:
V is v-convex V = V
vv
.
Proposition 4. Let V : Θ R , then:
q
v
V (θ) V (θ) + V
v
(q) = v(q, θ).
Theorem 6. (Carlier, 2001) A decision q : Θ R
M
+
is implementable if and only if there
exists a v-convex and v-subdifferentiable function V : Θ R such that:
q(θ)
v
V (θ) θ .
Remark 1. So when the informational rent V is v-convex, the conjugate V
v
plays the role of
the nonlinear tariff T that implements the decision q and the correspondence
v
V (θ) is identified
with q(θ).
Proof. of Lemma 3 The v-conjugation result allows us to write:
V (θ) = max
qQ
{v(q, θ) T (q)},
and
T (q) = max
θΘ
{v(q, θ) V (θ)}. (2.24)
Let us prove first that V is Lipschitz continuous. By the incentive compatibility constraint
we have that:
v(q(θ), θ) t(θ) v(q(θ
), θ) t(θ
). (2.25)
Using the definition of V , we can rewrite equation (2.25) as:
V (θ) V (θ
) v(q(θ
), θ) v(q(θ
), θ
). (2.26)
Changing the roles of θ and θ
in equation (2.26), we have that:
V (θ
) V (θ) v(q(θ), θ
) v(q(θ), θ). (2.27)
42 CHAPTER 2. NONLINEARD PRICING WITHOUT A SINGLE-CROSSING TARIFF
Equations (2.26) and (2.27) can be combined into:
v(q(θ), θ) v(q(θ), θ
) V (θ) V (θ
) v(q(θ
), θ) v(q(θ
), θ
).
As q is bounded and v(q, θ) is C
3
, we conclude that there is M > 0 such that:
V (θ
) V (θ)
M
θ θ
.
Now let us prove that T is Lipschitz continuous. Supposing that q
1
q(θ
1
) and q
2
q(θ
2
),
by Proposition 4 and equation (2.24), we can write:
T (q
1
) = v(q
1
, θ
1
) V (θ
1
) v(q
1
, θ
2
) V (θ
2
), (2.28)
T (q
2
) = v(q
2
, θ
2
) V (θ
2
) v(q
2
, θ
1
) V (θ
1
). (2.29)
Equations (2.28) and (2.29) results in:
v(q
1
, θ
1
) v(q
2
, θ
1
) T (q
1
) T (q
2
) v(q
1
, θ
2
) v(q
2
, θ
2
).
As q is bounded and v(q, θ) is C
3
, we conclude that there is M > 0 such that:
|T (q
1
) T (q
2
)| M |q
1
q
2
|.
Proof. of Lemma 4(i ) We know that θ is an interior point of Θ, then by the differentiability
of V at θ, we have that:
V (θ + h) = V (θ) + V
(θ) · h + o(h). (2.30)
Using equation (2.26) we have that:
V (θ + h) V (θ) + v(q(θ), θ + h) v(q(θ), θ) = V (θ). (2.31)
Combining equations (2.30), (2.31) and using the differentiability of v(q, θ), we get:
V
(θ) · h
v
θ
(q(θ), θ) · h o(h). (2.32)
Taking the limit in equation (2.32) first when h 0 and then when h 0 we get that:
V
(θ) =
v
θ
(q(θ), θ).
2.6. CONCLUSION 43
Proof. of Lemma 4(ii ) We know that q is an interior point of Q, then by the differentiability
of T at q q(θ), we have that:
T (q + h) = T (q) + T
(q) · h + o(h). (2.33)
And equation (2.24) gives us that:
T (q + h) v(q + h, θ) V (θ) = v(q + h, θ) v(q, θ) + T (q), (2.34)
and so:
T (q + h) T (q) v(q + h, θ) v(q, θ). (2.35)
Combining equations (2.33), (2.35) and using the differentiability of v(q, θ), we have that:
T
(q) · h
v
q
(q, θ) · h o(h). (2.36)
Taking the limit in equation (2.36) first when h 0 and then when h 0 we get that:
T
(q) =
v
q
(q, θ).
Proof. of Lemma 5 We will only prove (i). For (ii), the proof is analogous. The sets CS
+
is
given by:
CS
+
= {(θ, q) Θ × R
+
: q(θ) < q
0
(θ)}.
If q is continuous at θ
0
and (θ
0
, q(θ
0
)) CS
+
, it is possible to build an interval I = [θ
0
δ, θ
0
+δ]
such that (θ, q(θ)) CS
+
for all θ I. Let us take θ
1
I and define:
∆(θ
0
, θ
1
) = [v(q(θ
0
), θ
1
) v(q(θ
0
), θ
0
)] + [v(q(θ
1
), θ
0
) v(q(θ
1
), θ
1
)].
By Theorem 5, we must have ∆(θ
0
, θ
1
) 0. Notice that we can write:
∆(θ
0
, θ
1
) =
θ
1
θ
0
q(θ
1
)
q(θ
0
)
v
qθ
(q, θ)dq.
The region of integration is a subset of I, so the integrand v
qθ
is always positive. This gives us
that:
∆(θ
0
, θ
1
) (q(θ
1
) q(θ
0
))(θ
1
θ
0
) 0.
So we conclude that q must be increasing in θ
0
.
44 CHAPTER 2. NONLINEARD PRICING WITHOUT A SINGLE-CROSSING TARIFF
Proof. of Lemma 6 We must have:
v(q(θ), θ) t(θ) v(q(
ˆ
θ), θ) t(
ˆ
θ).
Using the informational rent V , we can write the inequality above as:
V (θ) V (
ˆ
θ) v(q(
ˆ
θ), θ) v(q(
ˆ
θ),
ˆ
θ). (2.37)
By Lemma 4(i), we have that V
(θ) = v
θ
(q(θ), θ), and equation (2.37) becomes:
θ
ˆ
θ
v
θ
(q(
˜
θ),
˜
θ)d
˜
θ
θ
ˆ
θ
v
θ
(q(
ˆ
θ),
˜
θ)d
˜
θ.
And using the fundamental theorem of calculus, we get the following equation:
θ
ˆ
θ
q(
˜
θ)
q(
ˆ
θ)
v
qθ
(˜q,
˜
θ)d˜qd
˜
θ 0.
Proof. of Theorem 1
We have a variational problem with inequality constraint. In this case the extremum is
achieved on a composite curve of pieces of extremals of the unconstrained problem and pieces
of extremals with binding constraints.
11
(i) As the constraint (BS) is not binding, we have an unconstrained maximization problem
for ψ
b
. The Euler equation for problem Π
BS
implies that:
F
θ
(q, ψ
b
(q)) = 0,
and using the definition of F in equation (2.8) the result follows.
(ii) BS is binding and θ < ψ
b
(q) < ψ
s
(q) < θ. By introducing a Lagrangian multiplier λ for
the constraint, we get:
L(q, ψ
b
, ψ
s
) = F (q, ψ
s
(q)) F (q, ψ
b
(q)) + λ(q)(v
q
(q, ψ
b
(q)) v
q
(q, ψ
s
(q))).
The first order condition for the Lagrangian L results in :
λ(q) =
F
θ
(q, ψ
s
(q))
v
qθ
(q, ψ
s
(q))
=
F
θ
(q, ψ
b
(q))
v
qθ
(q, ψ
b
(q))
.
And the result follows from the definition of F in equation (2.8).
11
Petrov [22] derives the optimality conditions for this kind of problems.
2.6. CONCLUSION 45
(iii) BS is binding, but now we have a corner solution, as ψ
s
= θ. So the characterization
follows from solving the following constraint equation:
v
q
(q, ψ
b
(q)) = v
q
(q, θ).
Proof. of Theorem 2 The expected profit coming from the decision q(θ, s) is given by:
Π(s) =
s
θ
f(q
R
(θ), θ) +
A(s)
s
f(q
B
(θ), θ) +
θ
A(s)
f(q
C
(θ, s), θ), (2.38)
where A(s) solves:
v
q
(q
B
(s), s) = v
q
(q
B
(A(s)), A(s)).
Differentiating equation (2.38) with respect to s gives us the result.
Proof. of Proposition 2 Consider q
1
, q
2
in q(θ) with q
1
< q
2
. We have that:
q
2
q
1
v
q
(q, θ) T
(q)
dq = v(q
2
, θ) T (q
2
) (v(q
1
, θ) T (q
1
)) = 0. (2.39)
As T is single crossing, if v
q
(q
2
, θ) T
(q
2
) 0 then:
v
q
(q, θ) T
(q) 0 q [q
1
, q
2
] . (2.40)
Now, by equations (2.39) and (2.40) we conclude that
v
q
(q, θ) T
(q) = 0 q [q
1
, q
2
] a.s.
and remembering that for q [q
1
, q
2
] we have
q
q
1
v
q
(x, θ) T
(x)
dx = 0.
Then we have:
v(q, θ) T (q) = v(q
1
, θ) T (q
1
) q [q
1
, q
2
] ,
and so q is convex valued.
46 CHAPTER 2. NONLINEARD PRICING WITHOUT A SINGLE-CROSSING TARIFF
Proof. of Theorem 3 This problem is known as an Isoperimetric Problem. It is solved by
introducing a Lagrangian multiplier for the (ISO) condition, and appending the constraint with
the multiplier to the original problem. Then the multiplier λ should be adjusted to cope with
the isoperimetric constraint. The resulting problem is:
12
max
{ψ
s
}
q
q
{F (q, ψ
s
(q)) F (q, θ
d
)}dq + λ
q
1
q
2
{v
q
(q, ψ
s
(q)) v
q
(q, θ
d
)}dq.
The Euler equation for the problem above is exactly:
F
θ
(q, ψ
s
(q)) + λv
qθ
(q, ψ
s
(q)) = 0,
and remembering the definition of F in equation (2.8) we see that F
θ
(q, ψ
s
(q)) = f
q
(q, ψ
s
(q)).
Finally, we have to adjust λ in order that the condition (ISO) is satisfied.
Proof. of Theorem 4 The way we have built our optimal candidate allows us to write the
monopolist’s expected profit as:
Π(q
1
, q
2
, θ
d
) =
q
1
q
{F (q, ψ
sr
(q)) F (q, ψ
br
(q))}dq +
+
q
q
2
{F (q, ψ
sc
(q)) F (q, ψ
bc
(q))}dq +
+
q
2
q
2
{F (q, ψ
si
(q)) F (q, θ
d
) + λ[v
q
(q, ψ
si
(q)) v
q
(q, θ
d
)]}dq.
Differentiating Π(q
1
, q
2
, θ
d
) with respect to q
1
, q
2
and θ
d
results in conditions (i), (ii) and (iii),
respectively.
12
We refer the interested reader to the book by Petrov [22]. It covers all the material from calculus of variations
that we use here.
Chapter 3
Bidimensional Screening
3.1 Introduction
Most of the work available in the literature of hidden information is based on one-dimensional
screening models. In this case there is a condition on the fundamentals, the Spence and Mirrlees
condition (SMC), that allows an easy characterization of an incentive compatibility allocation
rules. The reason is that the SMC provides a natural ordering in the type space which implies
in an equivalence between monotonicity and implementability of the agent’s decision function.
Therefore the principal can restrict his attention to monotonic decision functions and then
derive the optimal contract.
However, in the case of multidimensional screening models there is not an analogous con-
dition
1
on the fundamentals. As a consequence, it is very difficult to deal with the incentive
compatibility constraints. Unlike the previous case, it is not possible to know a priori the
directions of the binding constraints. The result is that the principal may have too many con-
straints to take into account which makes the full characterization of the optimal contract a
rather difficult problem.
This chapter is a tentative to extend the techniques developed by Araujo and Moreira [1] to
a bidimensional screening context. We study a nonlinear pricing model where the monopolist
sells a single product and the customer has a bidimensional characteristic. We study two cases.
1
The generalized single-crossing property defined by McAfee and McMillan [17] is too restrictive.
47
48 CHAPTER 3. BIDIMENSIONAL SCREENING
In the first one, called discrete-continuous, one of the customer’s characteristic is discrete and
the other is continuous. In the second one, called bicontinuous, both customer’s characteristics
are continuous. In the latter case, this chapter is close to McAfee and McMillan [17] and Laffont,
Maskin and Rochet [14]. But we do not assume the generalized single-crossing property as in
[17], and we generalize the example solved by [14].
In both setups, we derive a new necessary condition for implementability, resulting from
the customer’s maximization problem. This condition states that if two customers choose the
same decision they must pay the same marginal tariff which implies that their marginal utility
must be the same. This condition will permit us to find the optimality conditions that we use
for solving the monopolist’s maximization problem.
The chapter is divided in two main sections, one treating the discrete-continuous setup, and
the other one treating the bicontinuous setup.
3.2 Model
We use the Principal-Agent framework to analyse the bidimensional monopolistic screening
problem. In this model, each customer has a quasi-linear preference:
V (q, t, a, b) = v(q, a, b) t,
where q R
+
is the customer’s decision, t is the monetary transfer and (a, b) Θ R
2
is the
customer’s characteristics or types which are private information. The distribution function
P (a, b) is common knowledge. We assume that the customer’s utility function v(q, a, b) is C
3
.
The firm is a profit-maximizing monopolist which can produce any quality q Q R
+
incurring in a cost C(q). The monopolist’s revenue is given by:
Π(q, t) = t C(q),
where C(q) is a C
2
, nonnegative, increasing and convex.
Using the ‘Revelation Principle’
2
the monopolist’s problem can be stated as choosing the
allocation rule (q, t) : Θ R
+
× R that solves:
max
{q(·),t(·)}
Θ
Π(q(a, b), t(a, b))dP (a, b), (Π)
2
The ‘Revelation Principle’ has been enunciated in Gibbard [7].
3.3. DISCRETE-CONTINUOUS TYPE 49
subject to the individual-rationality constraints:
v(q(a, b), a, b) t(a, b) 0 (a, b) Θ, (IR)
and the incentive compatibility constraints:
(a, b) arg max
(a
,b
)Θ
{v(q(a
, b
), a, b) t(a
, b
)}, (a, b) Θ. (IC)
Remark 3. An allocation rule (q, t) satisfying the IC constraints is called incentive compatible.
A decision q is implementable if there exists a monetary transfer t such that the pair (q, t) is
incentive compatible.
Remark 4. The ‘Taxation Principle’
3
states that any allocation (q, t) satisfying the IC con-
straints can be implemented by a nonlinear tariff T : Q = q(Θ) R where:
T (q(a, b)) = t(a, b), (a, b) Θ.
3.3 Discrete-Continuous Type
In this section we study a bidimensional monopolist’s screening model where the customer’s
characteristics are represented by two parameters. One is a discrete variable and the other one
is a continuous variable. This specification for the parameters can be understood as a limit
case when their values are b
1
and b
2
, as shown in Figure 3.1.
We have two distinct groups of customers, one with lower b and the other one with higher
b. We assume that for a fixed b, the Spence and Mirrlees condition (SMC) is valid. By this
assumption, an incentive compatible decision function must be monotonic in the variable a.
However, the monotonicity is no longer a sufficient condition for implementability. The reason
is that the ordering of the binding IC constraints among customers with lower and higher b is
endogenous. In particular, there may exist two types (lower and higher b) choosing the same q.
From the customer’s maximization problem, we derive a new necessary IC condition. If two
customers choose the same decision they must pay the same marginal tariff. Consequently their
marginal utility must be the same. We will refer to it as the U-condition (UC).
3
This principle can be found in Guesnerie [9], Hammond [11] and Rochet [24].
50 CHAPTER 3. BIDIMENSIONAL SCREENING
b
1
b
2
a
b
a
a
Figure 3.1: The parameter b may take the values b
1
and b
2
.
We have two optimization problems: the relaxed problem and the UC problem which takes
the U-condition into account. Consequently we have two kinds of optimal solutions, depending
on whether the U-condition is binding or not. The solution we propose is a composite curve of
pieces of the relaxed problem’s solution and the UC problem’s solution.
We assume that the variable a is distributed in [a, a] with a continuous and positive density
p(a) and distribution function given by P (a). The variable b is discrete, taking values in
{b
1
, b
2
}, with a probability function given by Pr(b = b
i
) = p
i
. These variables are independent
and their joint distribution is given by P (a, b
i
) = p
i
P (a). The type space is then given by
Θ = [a, a] × {b
1
, b
2
}.
We assume the following condition:
Definition 12. (The Spence and Mirrlees condition.) For a fixed b = b
i
the sign of the
cross derivative of v(q, a, b) with respect to the decision q and type a is positive:
v
qa
(q, a, b
i
) > 0 on R
+
× [a, a]. (SMC)
With the SMC one can show that an incentive compatible decision must be increasing
with a.
4
This condition, however, is no longer sufficient and we derive now another necessary
condition for implementability. By Remark 3 for all incentive compatible allocation rule (q, t),
4
The proof is exactly the same as the one used for the one-dimensional screening problem with the SMC.
See Rochet [25].
3.3. DISCRETE-CONTINUOUS TYPE 51
we can find a tariff T that implements the decision q. This results in the following maximization
problem for the customer (a, b
i
):
max
qq(Θ)
{v(q, a, b
i
) T (q)}.
The first-order condition for an interior solution of the problem above is:
v
q
(q, a, b
i
) = T
(q).
So we can state the following result as a direct consequence of the first-order condition.
Proposition 5. (U-condition.) Suppose that T is differentiable at an interior point of Q =
q(Θ), q q(a, b
1
) q(a
, b
2
). Then
v
q
(q, a, b
1
) = v
q
(q, a
, b
2
). (UC)
This marginal utility identity between the pooled customers (a, b
1
) and (a
, b
2
) is called the
U-condition (UC). It simply states that these customers must pay the same marginal tariff at
their same decision. We can solve this marginal identity for a
, which results in a relation be-
tween the higher and lower b customers that will be useful for deriving the optimality conditions
when the UC is binding.
3.3.1 Optimality Conditions
In this subsection we derive the pointwise optimality conditions for the monopolist’s problem.
There are two maximization problems, one when the UC constraint is not binding and the
other when it is binding. The former is the relaxed problem and the latter is the UC problem.
The pointwise conditions derived give the relaxed solution and the UC solution q
R
and q
UC
,
respectively.
Consider an incentive compatible allocation rule (q, t). Then we define the customer’s
informational rent by:
V (a, b
i
) = v(q(a, b
i
), a, b
i
) t(a, b
i
).
52 CHAPTER 3. BIDIMENSIONAL SCREENING
We can plug the equation above into the monopolist’s objective function in the problem (Π)
and the result is:
2
i=1
p
i
a
a
{v(q(a, b
i
), a, b
i
) C(q(a, b
i
)) V (a, b
i
)}p(a)da, (3.1)
Using the envelope theorem (see Milgrom and Segall [18]) and an integration by parts procedure
we can rewrite the monopolist’s objective function as:
2
i=1
p
i
a
a
g(q(a, b
i
), a, b
i
)da,
where g is defined as:
g(q, a, b
i
) = p
i
v(q, a, b
i
) C(q) +
P (a) 1
p(a)
v
a
(q, a, b
i
)
p(a). (3.2)
By dropping the global incentive compatibility constraints we can define a relaxed version of
problem (Π) which is called the monopolist’s relaxed problem:
max
q(·)
2
i=1
p
i
a
a
g(q(a, b
i
), a, b
i
)da.
R
)
We have the following imediate result for the problem (Π
R
):
Proposition 6. (The Relaxed Decision.) The interior solution of (Π
R
) must satisfy the
following first-order condition:
g
q
(q, a, b
i
) = 0. (3.3)
Notice that this gives pointwise conditions for a solution of problem (Π
R
). The relaxed
decision q
R
(a, b
i
) is exactly the solution of equation (3.3) for each q. The relaxed solution may
not satisfy the necessary UC condition. So we may have to incorporate the UC constraint into
the monopolist’s problem.
Suppose that we have an interval [r
1
, r
2
] of lower b customers such that the UC constraint
is binding for them. By using the UC identity and the implicit function theorem we can define
implicitly a function a(q, r) by:
v
q
(q, r, b
1
) = v
q
(q, a(q, r), b
2
).
3.3. DISCRETE-CONTINUOUS TYPE 53
Let φ(r) denote the decision function associated with the (r, b
1
) customer. Then we have:
v
q
(φ(r), r, b
1
) = v
q
(φ(r), a(φ(r), r), b
2
). (3.4)
Notice that for each r [r
1
, r
2
], the customers (r, b
1
) and (a(φ(r), r), b
2
) choose the same
decision φ(r).
Considering equation (3.4), we can write the monopolist’s objective function on this interval
as:
p
1
r
2
r
1
g(φ(r), r, b
1
)dr + p
2
s
2
s
1
g(ψ(s), s, b
2
)ds, (3.5)
where:
s = a(φ(r), r),
ψ(s) = φ(r),
s
1
= a(φ(r
1
), r
1
),
s
2
= a(φ(r
2
), r
2
).
(3.6)
Using the equations in (3.6) we can make a change of variables in expression (3.5), resulting in:
r
2
r
1
{p
1
g(φ(r), r, b
1
) + p
2
g(φ(r), a(φ(r), r), b
2
)[a
1
(φ(r), r)φ
(r) + a
r
(φ(r), r)]}dr.
Notice that the UC constraints are incorporated in the expression above. Let us define:
F (r, x, y) = p
1
g(x, r, b
1
) + p
2
g(x, a(x, r), b
2
)[a
1
(x, r)y + a
r
(x, r)].
Then we can define a less constrained version of the monopolist’s maximization problem taking
into account only the UC constraints:
max
φ(·)
r
2
r
1
F (r, φ(r), φ
(r))dr. (3.7)
We then establish the pointwise optimality conditions for (3.7):
Proposition 7. (UC Decision.) If φ
is the optimal decision for problem (3.7), then:
p
1
g
q
(q, r, b
1
)
v
qa
(q, r, b
1
)
= p
2
g
q
(q, a(q, r), b
2
)
v
qa
(q, a(q, r), b
2
)
, (3.8)
where q = φ
(r).
This condition is analogous to the U-shaped condition in Araujo and Moreira [1] and to the
Bell-shaped condition from Chapter 2.
54 CHAPTER 3. BIDIMENSIONAL SCREENING
Finally we suggest a method for determining the optimal decision. We construct a composite
decision combining pieces of the relaxed and the UC decisions. It is important to optimally
choose the point where you change from one to another. In what follows we solve an example
that illustrates this method.
3.3.2 An Example
In this example, a is uniformly distributed in [0, 1], b
1
= 0 and b
2
= 1, with p
1
= p
2
= 1/2. The
customer’s utility function is given by:
v(q, a, b
i
) = aq (1 + b
i
)
q
2
2
,
and for simplicity we assume that the monopolist’s production costs are zero.
Hence:
g(x, a, b
i
) =
1
2
(2a 1)q(a, b
i
) (b
i
+ 1)
q(a, b
i
)
2
2
.
Using Proposition 6, we can find the relaxed decision:
q
R
(a, 0) = {2a 1}
+
,
q
R
(a, 1) = {
2a1
2
}
+
.
The relaxed solution is not incentive compatible, because it does not satisfy the necessary UC
condition.
Using the U-condition (UC), we have that:
a(q, r) = r + q,
and, using Proposition 7, we can find the UC decision:
q
UC
(a, 0) = {4a 2}
+
,
q
UC
(a, 1) = {
4a2
5
}
+
.
In Figure 3.2 we plot the relaxed and the UC decision functions.
Our strategy now is to construct a decision function combining the relaxed and the UC
decision, depending on the parameter a
U
, which is the point where we change from one decision
3.3. DISCRETE-CONTINUOUS TYPE 55
0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
q
q
R
(a, 0)
q
UC
(a, 0)
q
R
(a, 1)
q
UC
(a, 1)
q
Figure 3.2: The relaxed and the UC decision functions.
to the other:
q(a, 0, a
U
) =
0 if 0 a
1
2
,
q
UC
(a, 0) if
1
2
a a
U
,
q
UC
(a
U
, 0) if a
U
a a
R
,
q
R
(a, 0) if a
R
a 1.
(3.9)
q(a, 1, a
U
) =
0 if 0 a
1
2
,
q
UC
(a
U
, 1) if
1
2
a ˆa
U
,
q
R
a
U
, 1) if ˆa
U
a 1,
(3.10)
where ˆa
U
= a(q
UC
(a
U
, 0), a
U
) and a
R
is such that q
UC
(a
U
, 0) = q
R
(a
R
, 0). In Figure 3.3 we plot
this decision function which combines the relaxed decision and the UC decision.
q
0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
Figure 3.3: The composite solution in thicker black.
From the objective function in (Π
R
), we can determine the monopolist profit as a function
56 CHAPTER 3. BIDIMENSIONAL SCREENING
of a
U
(see Figure 3.4):
Π(a
U
) =
28a
3
U
3
18a
2
U
+
23a
U
2
19
8
.
Now we have to optimally choose the parameter a
U
.
5
By solving the first-order condition
a
U
a
U
Π(a
U
)
0.586 0.588 0.59 0.592 0.594 0.596 0.598
0.06102
0.06104
0.06106
0.06108
Figure 3.4: The expected profit depending as a function of a
U
.
Π
(a
U
) = 0, we find the optimal choice for a
U
:
a
U
=
1
28
(18
2).
So the solution we propose results from equations (3.9) and (3.10), choosing the parameter
a
U
= a
U
. This solution is implemented by the following tariff:
T (q) =
1
8
q(4 3q), if 0 q
1
7
(4
2),
1
196
(9 + 4
2 + 98q 49q
2
), if
1
7
(4
2) q 1,
which is determined by integrating the marginal utility.
Comparing the relaxed decision q
R
(a, b) with q(a, b, a
U
), we have a decrease of approximately
2.3% in the expected profit.
3.4 Bicontinuous Type
In this section we show how to use the marginal utility condition to solve nonlinear pricing
model where the customer has two dimensions of private information. Unlike the case treated
5
The optimal a
U
can also be found through an ironing procedure. See Araujo and Moreira [1].
3.4. BICONTINUOUS TYPE 57
in the previous section, where we have a continuous and a discrete parameter for the type,
now we have that both dimensions are continuous, that is, the type space is the rectangle
Θ = (0, α) × (0, β), with α, β > 0.
As the decision q is a function defined from Θ R
2
into R
+
, we expect that its level
sets are one-dimensional curves with images contained in Θ. The level sets for q represents a
continuous pooling of types, and the marginal condition states that pooling types must have
identical marginal utility at the same chosen decision. The result is that both q(a, b) and
v
q
(q(a, b), a, b) should have common level sets. This principle may be expressed in a convenient
way by using partial differential equation (PDE), as we will see in what follows.
Analysing the customer’s maximization problem we derive a partial differential equation
(PDE) whose solution can be interpreted as resolving this relation among the level sets. This
is a quasilinear first-order partial differential equation and we use the method of characteristic
curves to solve it. This method is adequate for our problem because the characteristic curves
for this particular PDE is exactly the level sets of both q(a, b) and v
q
(q(a, b), a, b). In the end
it provides us a natural change of variables that reduces the problem from two dimensions to
only one dimension. Then we apply variational calculus techniques to find the solution of this
one-dimensional problem and finally we go back to the original variables.
The parameter representing the customer’s type (a, b) Θ has a positive and continuous
density p(a, b). For simplicity, we assume that the monopolist’s production costs are zero.
We also assume that the monetary transference t is positive. Consequently the tariff T is
positive for all units consumed q. This means that the monopolist ever has positive profits when
selling to any customer (a, b). Consider an incentive compatible allocation rule (q, t). From the
(IC) condition, each customer has the following maximization problem:
max
(a
,b
)Θ
{v(q(a
, b
), a, b) t(a
, b
)}.
The first-order conditions for the maximization problem above give us an analogous UC condi-
tion of the discrete-continuous problem
6
:
Proposition 8. (The Quasilinear Equation.) Suppose that (q, t) : Θ R
+
×R is incentive
6
Actually the UC condition is equivalent to the PDE (3.11). The PDE formulation is more convenient to
the bicontinuous model.
58 CHAPTER 3. BIDIMENSIONAL SCREENING
compatible and twice differentiable in an open set Θ. Then we have that:
v
qa
(q(a, b), a, b)q
b
(a, b) = v
qb
(q(a, b), a, b)q
a
(a, b). (3.11)
Equation (3.11) is classified as a first-order partial differential equation (PDE)
7
. We can
interpret it geometrically by observing that the gradients
a,b
v
q
and q have the same direction
and, consequently, both q and v
q
have the same level set.
Although Proposition 8 is a general result, we will work with a particular specification for
the customer’s utility function. This allow us to show how to use the PDE derived to solve the
monopolist’s problem. Hence we assume that the customer’s utility function is given by:
v(q, a, b) = aq (c + w(b))
q
γ
γ
t,
where a and b are distributed independently and uniformly on Θ; w(0) = 0 and w
(b) > 0;
γ > 1, q represents the consumption choice and t is the monetary transfer. The monopolist’s
production cost C(q) is assumed to be zero.
For an incentive compatible allocation rule (q, t), the customer’s informational rent is given
by V (a, b) = v(q(a, b), a, b) t(a, b). As the production costs are now zero, if we plug the
informational rent in equation (Π) we can rewrite the monopolist’s objective function as:
1
αβ
α
0
β
0
{v(q(a, b), a, b) V (a, b)}dadb.
Using the envelope theorem (see [18]), and an integration by parts procedure, we can derive
the following result about the monopolist’s expected profit:
Proposition 9. (The Monopolist’s Expected Profit.) Let q be an implementable decision.
Then the monopolist’s expected profit is given by:
1
αβ
α
0
β
0
{(2a α)q(a, b) (c + w(b))
q
γ
γ
}dadb. (3.12)
7
See Fritz John [12] for a complete analysis of this kind of PDE and the method of characteristic curves for
solving it.
3.4. BICONTINUOUS TYPE 59
Let us define G(q, a, b) = (2a α)q(a, b) (c + w(b))
q
γ
γ
.
From Proposition 8, we can establish the PDE (3.11) for our specific model:
w
(b)q
γ1
q
a
+ q
b
= 0. (3.13)
We now formulate the following Cauchy problem for this PDE:
w
(b)q
γ1
q
a
+ q
b
= 0,
q(r, 0) = φ(r),
(3.14)
where we assume that φ is a continuous and increasing function such that φ(0) = 0.
We now use the method of characteristic curves to find the solution of (3.14). The method
works in the following way: along the characteristic curves the PDE equation becomes an
ordinary differential equation (ODE) with initial condition given by q(r, 0) = φ(r). So, for each
fixed r, we have an ODE with initial value and we then invoke the existence and uniquiness
theorems to solve it. We choose the curve (r, 0) to give the initial value and it is important
that the characteristic curves and the initial value curve to be not tangent. The idea is that we
can find the characteristic curves and relate the value of q in Θ to the value of q in (r, 0). In
Figure 3.5, the projections of the characteristic curves are plotted. As we can see in the figure,
they are not tangent to the line (r, 0) and the value of q is constant along these curves.
a
b
α
β
t
I
Figure 3.5: Characteristic curves in Θ.
So using the method of characteristic curves, we can establish the following result:
60 CHAPTER 3. BIDIMENSIONAL SCREENING
Proposition 10. (The Cauchy Problem.) The solution for the Cauchy problem (3.14) is
given by:
q(a, b) = q(a(r, s), b(r, s)) = φ(r(a, b)),
where we get r by inverting the following equations:
a(r, s) = r + w(s)φ(r)
γ1
,
b(r, s) = s.
For each r we have characteristic curves parametrized as (a(r, s), b(r, s), φ(r)). With them
we have a natural change of variables that we will plug in equation (3.12). This results in the
following system of variables:
a = A(x, r, s) = r + w(s)x
γ1
,
b = B(r, s) = s,
where the Jacobian is simply A
1
φ
(r) + A
2
, such that A
1
=
A
x
and A
2
=
A
r
.
Using these new variables, we can rewrite the monopolist’s expected profit as
1
αβ
α
0
L(φ(r),r)
0
{G(φ(r), A(φ(r), r, s), s)
A
1
φ
(r) + A
2
}dsdr,
where, for each r, L is defined as the s coordinate of the intersection between the characteristic
curve and the boundary of Θ. Notice that there should exist an intermediate r
I
such that for
r < r
I
, L is constant with L = β and for r > r
I
, L solves A(x, r, L(x, r)) α. In Figure 3.5, L
is represented by dot points.
Then we can define a less constrained version of the monopolist’s maximization problem,
by dropping the IC constraints and considering only the constraints following from the EDP
given in Proposition 8:
max
φ(·)
1
αβ
α
0
L(φ(r),r)
0
{G(φ(r), A(φ(r), r, s), s)
A
1
φ
(r) + A
2
}dsdr. (3.15)
Now we can establish our main result:
Proposition 11. The Euler’s equation for the monopolist’s optimization problem (3.15) is
given by:
L(φ(r),r)
0
G
q
(φ(r), A(φ(r), r, s), s)ds = 0. (3.16)
3.4. BICONTINUOUS TYPE 61
3.4.1 Examples
Here we solve some examples of bidimensional contracts with one instrument.
Example 1. (Laffont, Maskin and Rochet, 1987.) This example was taken from [14]. We
set α = β = c = 1, γ = 2 and w(b) = b in our model.
We have that:
G(q, a, b) = (2a 1)q
1
2
(b + 1)q
2
,
A(x, r, s) = r + sx,
B(x, r, s) = s.
We can determine L as:
L(x, r) =
1 , if r < r
I
,
1r
x
, if r > r
I
.
By Proposition 11, the Euler equation is given by:
L(φ(r),r)
0
G
1
(φ(r), A(φ(r), r, s), s)A
1
(φ(r), r, s)ds = 0.
This gives us:
L
0
{(2(r + ) 1 (s + 1)φ)}ds = (2r 1 φ)L +
L
2
2
φ = 0.
Solving the equation above for φ results in:
φ(r) =
0 , if 0 r
1
2
,
4r 2 , if
1
2
r
3
5
,
3r1
2
, if
3
5
r 1.
Now we have to go back to the original variables. Solving the equation A(φ(r), r, s) = r + (r)
for r in terms of a and b, we get:
r(a, b) =
a , if a
1
2
,
a+2b
1+4b
, if
1
2
a+2b
1+4b
3
5
,
2a+b
2+3b
, if
3
5
2a+b
2+3b
1.
We have that q(a, b) = φ(r(a, b)). Making the substitution we can find the optimal decision
q(a, b):
q(a, b) =
0 , if a
1
2
,
4a2
1+4b
, if
1
2
a+2b
1+4b
3
5
,
3a1
2+3b
, if
3
5
2a+b
2+3b
1,
62 CHAPTER 3. BIDIMENSIONAL SCREENING
and also the nonlinear tariff
8
T that implements q:
T (q) =
q
2
3q
2
8
, if q
2
5
,
q
3
q
2
6
+
1
30
, if q
2
5
.
Example 2. This example is an slight variation of the previous one. The fundamental dif-
ference is that now the characteristic curves are not straight lines for r > 1/2. We set
α = β = c = 1, γ = 2 and w(b) = b
2
in our model.
We have that:
G(q, a, b) = (2a 1)q
1
2
(b
2
+ 1)q
2
,
A(x, r, s) = r + s
2
x,
B(x, r, s) = s.
We can determine L as:
L(x, r) =
1 , if r r
I
,
1r
x
, if r r
I
.
By Proposition 11, the Euler equation is given by:
L(φ(r),r)
0
G
1
(φ(r), A(φ(r), r, s), s)A
1
(φ(r), r, s)ds = 0.
This gives us:
L
0
(2(r + s
2
φ) 1 (s
2
+ 1)φ)
ds = (2r 1 φ)L +
L
3
3
φ = 0.
Solving the equation above for φ results in:
φ(r) =
0 , if 0 r
1
2
,
6r3
2
, if
1
2
r
5
8
,
5r2
3
, if
5
8
r 1.
Now we have to go back to the original variables. And solving the equation A(φ(r), r, s) =
r + s
2
φ(r) for r in terms of a and b, we get:
r(a, b) =
a , if a
1
2
,
2a+3b
2
2+6b
2
, if
1
2
2a+3b
2
2+6b
2
5
8
,
3a+2b
2
3+5b
2
, if
5
8
3a+2b
2
3+5b
2
1.
8
We find the nonlinear tariff T by integrating the marginal tariff given by v
q
(q, a, 0).
3.4. BICONTINUOUS TYPE 63
We have that q(a, b) = φ(r(a, b)). Making the substitution we can find the optimal decision
q(a, b):
q(a, b) =
0 , if a
1
2
,
6a3
2+6b
2
, if
1
2
2a+3b
2
2+6b
2
5
8
,
5a2
3+5b
2
, if
5
8
3a+2b
2
3+5b
2
1,
and also the nonlinear tariff T that implements q:
T (q) =
q
2
q
2
3
, if q
3
8
,
2q
5
q
2
5
+
3
160
, if q
3
8
.
Example 3. (Basov, 2005.) This is a generalization of the first one and was proposed by
Basov [4]. We set w(b) = b and β < 2c in our model.
We have that:
G(q, a, b) = (2a α)q
1
γ
(b + c)q
γ
,
A(x, r, s) = r + sx
γ1
,
B(x, r, s) = s.
We can determine L as:
L(x, r) =
β , if r r
I
,
αr
x
γ1
, if r r
I
.
By Proposition 11, the Euler equation is given by:
L(φ(r),r)
0
G
1
(φ(r), A(φ(r), r, s), s)A
1
(φ(r), r, s)ds = 0.
This gives us:
L
0
(2(r +
γ1
) α (s + c)φ
γ1
)
ds = (2r α
γ1
)L +
L
2
2
φ
γ1
= 0.
Solving the equation above for φ results in:
φ(r) =
0 , if 0 r
α
2
,
4r2α
2cβ
1
γ1
, if
α
2
r α
2c+β
2c+3β
,
3rα
2c
1
γ1
, if α
2c+β
2c+3β
r α.
64 CHAPTER 3. BIDIMENSIONAL SCREENING
Now we have to go back to the original variables. And solving the equation A(φ(r), r, s) =
r + s
2
φ(r) for r in terms of a and b, we get:
r(a, b) =
a , if a
α
2
,
a(2cβ)+2αb
2cβ+4b
, if
α
2
a(2cβ)+2αb
2cβ+4b
α
2c+β
2c+3β
,
2ac+αb
2c+3b
, if α
2c+β
2c+3β
2ac+αb
2c+3b
α.
We have that q(a, b) = φ(r(a, b)). Making the substitution we can find the optimal decision
q(a, b):
q(a, b) =
0 , if a
α
2
,
4a2α
2cβ+4b
1
γ1
, if
α
2
a(2cβ)+2αb
2cβ+4b
α
2c+β
2c+3β
,
3aα
2c+3b
1
γ1
, if α
2c+β
2c+3β
2ac+αb
2c+3b
α,
and also the nonlinear tariff T that implements q:
T (q) =
αq
2
(β + 2c)q
γ
4γ
, if q
2α
3β+2c
,
αq
3
cq
γ
3γ
+
2α
2
18β + 12c
3β + 2c
12γ
2α
3β + 2c
γ
, if q
2α
3β+2c
.
3.5 Conclusion
In this chapter we showed that the techniques by Araujo and Moreira [1] can be extended
to the bidimensional context at least for some particular specifications. The marginal utility
identity plays a fundamental role in our analysis. In a sense, it allows us to reduce the problem
to only one dimension. Then we could derive the optimality conditions for the monopolist’s
maximization problem.
In the discrete-continuous setup we derived the pointwise optimality conditions, and then
we gave an example illustrating how to use them to build a solution for the monopolist’s max-
imization problem in a way similar to Araujo and Moreira [1]. In the bidimensional setup, we
also derived optimality conditions and then we were able to solve examples from the litera-
ture, and to solve a new example that does not satisfy the generalized single-crossing property
assumed by [17].
3.5. CONCLUSION 65
Appendix
Proof. of Proposition 5 The customer (a, b
i
) has the following maximization problem:
max
qq(Θ)
{v(q, a, b
i
) T (q)}.
If q = q(a, b
1
) = q(a, b
2
) is an interior point of Q = q(Θ) and T is differentiable at q, deriving
the first-order condition for the maximization problem above results in:
v
q
(q, a, b
1
) = T
(q) = v
q
(q, a, b
2
).
Proof. of Proposition 6 The Euler’s equation
9
for problem (Π
R
) is exactly g
q
(q, a, b
i
) = 0.
Proof. of Proposition 7 Consider the following functional:
r
2
r
1
F (r, φ(r), φ
(r))dr.
The Euler’s equation for the functional above is:
F
x
(r, φ(r), φ
(r)) =
d
dr
F
y
(r, φ(r), φ
(r)).
If we expand the Euler’s equation, we get:
p1g
q
(φ(r), r, b
1
) + p2g
q
(φ(r), a(φ(r), r), b
2
)a
r
(φ(r), r) = 0.
But the function a(q, r) is implicitly defined as the solution of:
v
q
(q, r, b
1
) = v
q
(q, a(q, r), b
1
).
Differentiating the equation above with respect to q results in:
a
r
(q, r) =
v
qa
(q, r, b
1
)
v
qa
(q, a(q, r), b
2
)
,
and the result follows.
9
See Petrov [22].
66 CHAPTER 3. BIDIMENSIONAL SCREENING
Proof. of Proposition 8 For each customer (a, b), the first-order conditions from the (IC) give
that:
t
a
= v
q
(q(a, b), a, b)q
a
(a, b),
t
b
= v
q
(q(a, b), a, b)q
b
(a, b).
By taking the cross derivatives in both equations above, we get:
t
ab
= (v
qq
(q, a, b)q
b
+ v
qb
(q, a, b))q
a
+ v
q
(q, a, b)q
ab
,
t
ba
= (v
qq
(q, a, b)q
a
+ v
qa
(q, a, b))q
b
+ v
q
(q, a, b)q
ba
.
As t is twice differentiable at (a, b), using Schwarz’ theorem we have that the cross derivatives
are equal and the result follows.
Proof. of Proposition 9 Consider an incentive compatible (IC) allocation rule (q, t). For each
customer (a, b) we should have:
V (a, b) = v(q(a, b), a, b) t(a, b) v(q(a
, b
), a, b) t(a
, b
), (a, b), (a
, b
),
and using the envelope theorem (see Milgrom and Segall [18]), we have that:
V
a
(a, b) = v
a
(q(a, b), a, b) = q(a, b) and V
b
(a, b) = v
b
(q(a, b), a, b) = w
(b)
q(a, b)
γ
γ
.
The fundamental theorem of calculus allows us to write:
V (a, b) = V (0, b) +
a
0
q(θ, b),
and
V (0, b) = V (0, 0)
b
0
w
(θ)
q(0, θ)
γ
γ
.
We have that v(q, 0, b) 0 and, by assumption, t is always positive. As a consequence we must
have q(0, b) = 0. Otherwise, customer (0, b) would have a negative utility. This results in:
V (0, b) = 0 and V (a, b) =
a
0
q(θ, b).
Using the informational rent we can replace t(a, b) in the monopolist’s objective function in
the problem (Π):
1
αβ
α
0
β
0
{v(q(a, b), a, b) V (a, b)}dadb. (3.17)
3.5. CONCLUSION 67
Using an integration by parts procedure we have that:
β
0
α
0
V (a, b)dadb =
β
0
α
0
a
0
q(θ, b)dadb
=
β
0
a
a
0
q(θ, b)
α
0
α
0
aq(θ, b)da
=
β
0
α
0
(α a)q(a, b)dadb.
Plugging the equation above in equation (3.17) we get the result.
Proof. of Proposition 10 The characteristic curves for equation (3.11) emerge as the solution
of the following system of ordinary differential equations
10
:
da
ds
= v
qb
(z(r, s), a(r, s), b(r, s)) = w
(b)z
γ1
, with a(r, 0) = r;
db
ds
= v
qa
(z(r, s), a(r, s), b(r, s)) = 1, with b(r, 0) = 0;
dZ
ds
= 0, with z(r, 0) = φ(r),
and the solution for the system of ordinary differential equations above is given by:
a(r, s) = r + w(s)φ(r)
γ1
;
b(r, s) = s;
z(r, s) = φ(r).
We have that q(a, b) = z(r(a, b), s(a, b) = φ(r(a, b)) and we only have to invert the variables to
find the solution.
Proof. of Proposition 11 Define the function:
J() =
α
0
L(φ(r)+h(r),r)
0
{G(φ(r) + h(r), A(φ(r) + h(r), r, s), s)
[A
1
(φ(r) + h(r), r, s), s)(φ
(r) + h
(r)) + A
2
(φ(r) + h(r), r, s), s)]}dsdr,
10
See Fritz John [12].
68 CHAPTER 3. BIDIMENSIONAL SCREENING
where h(r) is an increasing function such that h(0) = h(α) = 0. Differentiating J with respect
to , and evaluating at = 0, we get:
α
0
L(φ(r),r)
0
[G
1
+ G
2
A
1
][A
1
φ
+ A
2
] + G[A
11
φ
+ A
21
]
ds
+ G(φ, A(φ, r, L), L)[A
1
(φ, r, L)φ
+ A
2
(φ, r, L)]
h(r)dr +
α
0
L(φ(r),r)
0
GA
1
ds
h
(r)dr.
Rewriting the expression above and imposing that J
(0) = 0 results in:
α
0
I
1
(r)h(r) + I
2
(r)h
(r)
dr = 0.
Using a classical result from calculus
11
, we conclude from equation above that:
I
1
(r) = I
2
(r). (3.18)
Using equation (3.18), we get:
L(φ(r),r)
0
G
1
A
2
ds + G(A
2
L
1
A
1
L
2
) = 0, (3.19)
where
G = G(φ, A(φ, r, L), L),
A
1
= A
1
(φ, r, L),
A
2
= A
2
(φ, r, L).
Now, we observe that if r < r
I
, then L(x, r) = β and so L
1
= L
2
= 0; if r > r
I
, L solves
A(x, r, L(x, r)) 1 and deriving this equation with respect to x and r, we get:
A
1
+ A
3
L
1
= 0, A
2
+ A
3
L
2
= 0,
(3.20)
and this gives us:
L
1
= A
1
/A
3
,
L
2
= A
2
/A
3
.
(3.21)
Finally, we conclude that A
2
L
1
A
1
L
2
= 0 and we can simplify equation (3.19):
L(φ(t),r)
0
G
1
A
2
ds = 0, (3.22)
and recalling that A(x, r, s) = r + w(s)x
γ1
, we have that A
2
= 1, and the result follows.
11
See Troutman [28], pg. 98.
Bibliography
[1] A. Araujo and H. Moreira. Adverse selection problem without the spence-mirrlees condi-
tion. 2007.
[2] M. Armstrong. Multiproduct nonlinear pricing. Econometrica, 64:51–75, 1996.
[3] S. Basov. Hamiltonian approach to multi-dimensional screening. Journal of Mathematical
Economics, 36:77–94, 2001.
[4] S. Basov. Multidimensional Screening. Springer., 2005.
[5] S. Brown and D. Sibley. The theory of public utility pricing. Cambridge University Press.,
1986.
[6] G. Carlier. A general existence result for the principal-agent problem with adverse selection.
Journal of Mathematical Economics, 35:129–150, 2001.
[7] A. Gibbard. Manipulation for voting schemes. Econometrica, 41:587–601, 1973.
[8] M. Goldman, H. Leland, and D. Sibley. Optimal nonuniform pricing. Review of Economic
Studies, 51:305–320, 1984.
[9] R. Guesnerie. On taxation and incentives: further reflections on the limit of redistribution.
Mimeo., 1981.
[10] R. Guesnerie and J.-J. Laffont. A complete solution to a class of principal-agent problems
with an application to the control of a self-managed firm. Journal of Public Economics,
25:329–369, 1984.
69
70 BIBLIOGRAPHY
[11] J.P. Hammond. Straightforward individual incentive compatibility in large economies.
Review of Economic Studies, 46:263–282, 1979.
[12] F. John. Partial Differential Equations. Springer Verlag, 1981.
[13] B. Jullien. Participation constraints in adverse selection models. Journal of Economic
Theory, 93:1–47, 2000.
[14] J.J. Laffont, E. Maskin, and J.C. Rochet. Optimal nonlinear pricing with two dimensional
characteristics. University of Minnesota Press, 1987.
[15] E. Maskin and J. Riley. Monopoly with incomplete information. Rand Journal of Eco-
nomics, 15(2):171–196, 1984.
[16] S. Matthews and J. Moore. Monopoly provision of quality and warranties: An exploration
in the theory of multidimensional screening. Econometrica, 55(2):441–468, 1987.
[17] R.P. McAfee and J. McMillan. Multidimensional incentive compatibility and mechanism
design. Journal of Economic Theory, 46:335–354, 1988.
[18] P. Milgrom and I. Segal. Envelope theorems for arbitrary choice sets. Econometrica,
70(2):583–601, 2002.
[19] P.K. Monteiro and F.H. Page Jr. Optimal selling mechanisms for multiproduct monopolists:
Incentive compatibility in the presence of budget constraints. Journal of Mathematical
Economics, 30, 1998.
[20] M. Mussa and S. Rosen. Monopoly and product quality. Journal of Economic Theory,
18:301–307, 1978.
[21] G. Nˆldeke and L. Samuelson. Optimal bunching without optimal control. Journal of
Economic Theory, 134:405–420, 2007.
[22] Iu. P. Petrov. Variational Methods in Optimum Control Theory. Academic Press, 1968.
[23] S.T. Rachev and L. R¸schendorf. Mass Transportation Problems.Volume I. Springer, 1988.
BIBLIOGRAPHY 71
[24] J.C. Rochet. The taxation principle and multitime hamilton-jacobi equations. Journal of
Mathematical Economics, 14:113–128, 1985.
[25] J.C. Rochet. A necessary and sufficient conditions for rationalizability in a quasi-linear
context. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 16:191–200, 1987.
[26] J.C. Rochet and P. Chon
`
E. Ironing, sweeping, and multidimensional screening. Econo-
metrica, 66(4):783–826, 1998.
[27] J.C. Rochet and L. Stole. The economics of multidimensional screening, in M. Dewa-
tripont, L.P. Hansen, and S.J. Turnovsky, eds. Advances in Economics and Econometrics,
Cambridge. The Press Syndicate of the University of Cambridge, UK, 2003.
[28] J. L. Troutman. Variational Calculus and Optimal Control: Optimization with Elementary
Convexity. Springer Verlag, 1995.
[29] R.B. Wilson. Nonlinear Pricing. Oxford University Press, 1993.
Livros Grátis
( http://www.livrosgratis.com.br )
Milhares de Livros para Download:
Baixar livros de Administração
Baixar livros de Agronomia
Baixar livros de Arquitetura
Baixar livros de Artes
Baixar livros de Astronomia
Baixar livros de Biologia Geral
Baixar livros de Ciência da Computação
Baixar livros de Ciência da Informação
Baixar livros de Ciência Política
Baixar livros de Ciências da Saúde
Baixar livros de Comunicação
Baixar livros do Conselho Nacional de Educação - CNE
Baixar livros de Defesa civil
Baixar livros de Direito
Baixar livros de Direitos humanos
Baixar livros de Economia
Baixar livros de Economia Doméstica
Baixar livros de Educação
Baixar livros de Educação - Trânsito
Baixar livros de Educação Física
Baixar livros de Engenharia Aeroespacial
Baixar livros de Farmácia
Baixar livros de Filosofia
Baixar livros de Física
Baixar livros de Geociências
Baixar livros de Geografia
Baixar livros de História
Baixar livros de Línguas
Baixar livros de Literatura
Baixar livros de Literatura de Cordel
Baixar livros de Literatura Infantil
Baixar livros de Matemática
Baixar livros de Medicina
Baixar livros de Medicina Veterinária
Baixar livros de Meio Ambiente
Baixar livros de Meteorologia
Baixar Monografias e TCC
Baixar livros Multidisciplinar
Baixar livros de Música
Baixar livros de Psicologia
Baixar livros de Química
Baixar livros de Saúde Coletiva
Baixar livros de Serviço Social
Baixar livros de Sociologia
Baixar livros de Teologia
Baixar livros de Trabalho
Baixar livros de Turismo